Skip to main content
Log in

Governance in Seaport Clusters

  • Policy Perspective (Non Peer-Reviewed)
  • Published:
Maritime Economics & Logistics Aims and scope

Abstract

Seaports can be meaningfully analysed with a cluster perspective. In this perspective, seaports are regarded as concentrations of economic activity related to the arrival and service of ships and cargoes at ports. This perspective has two main advantages: first, it draws attention to forces of agglomeration and disagglomeration in seaports. Some seaports are able to become concentrations of logistics activities, commercial centres, ‘information hubs’ and ‘shipping hubs’, while others do not attract such activities. The cluster perspective allows for an analysis of such processes of agglomeration. Second, the cluster perspective enriches existing theories on governance in seaports. The analysis of governance in seaports has mostly been limited to the role of the port authority. Notwithstanding the central role of port authorities in ports (port clusters), we argue that a port authority is one ‘arrangement’ to improve the governance in clusters, but not the only ‘arrangement’. Other arrangements include the formation of associations, the development of public-private partnerships and the use of networks. The literature on governance in clusters provides a broad analytical framework. This framework has implications for analysing the important and complex issue of the role of port authorities in seaports. In this paper, we deal in depth with the issue of cluster governance in seaports and illustrate our approach to cluster governance with an analysis of the port of Rotterdam.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For these reasons, we claim that the performance of a port cannot be understood when a port is analysed as a transport node, or an element of a logistics chain. Such a perspective neglects the interdependence of various economic activities that cluster together in seaports.

  2. Given the presence of regulations that prevent collusion.

  3. The presence of intermediaries in a cluster offers advantages because the costs of using a local intermediary are lower than the costs of using an intermediary outside the cluster. Furthermore, intermediaries are likely to have a dense local network and client base.

  4. The above-mentioned reasons are the ‘raison d’être’ of many intermediaries. However, their presence in an industry is a different issue than their presence in a (regional) cluster.

  5. For each specific cluster, different issues are relevant, issues such as an education regime and an innovation regime are widely regarded as relevant for the performance of clusters.

  6. Campbell et al (1991) argue that ‘When actors have already established associations (…) and thus the capacity for selecting far sighted cooperative strategies, they can more easily devise new multilateral governance mechanisms than actors from a sector, where short sighted bilateral mechanisms dominate the governance regime (Campbell et al, 1991, p. 331). This shows the path-dependence of regimes.

  7. Instead of investing in the quality of regimes firms can also leave the cluster when regimes are not efficient or ‘free-ride’ on the investments of others.

  8. The coordination mechanisms markets, hierarchies and interfirm alliances are used in clusters, but are used for transactions within a firm or between a limited number of firms. These coordination mechanisms are not suited for solving CAPs. Other kinds of institutions, such as discussion platforms and informal are not truly elements of an infrastructure for solving CAPs.

  9. Public–private organisations and public organisations can be regarded as elements of the infrastructure for collective action (of a cluster) if they are established to generate cluster-specific collective benefits.

  10. Hirschman (1970) discusses three possible reactions when confronted with an unsatisfactory situation (in his case working conditions): exit, voice and as a third possibility, ‘silence’. The first two are sources of pressure, the third is not. When applied to association members, exit means that firms do not use services of associations. Exit does not directly contribute to the quality of a regime.

  11. Campbell and Lingberg write with regard to changing a regime that ‘actors eventually select a new governance regime as streams of action intermingle in complex ways. Trial and error learning as the result of spontaneous interaction may predominate in some instances (…). In this sense, selection is very much a process of muddling through. In other cases, deliberate coordinations among organisations will take the place of, or supplement, trial and error’ (Campbell and Lingberg, 1991, p. 331). This illustrates that adaptation of regimes is far from spontaneous.

  12. Four of these five issues are relevant for clusters in general, hinterland accessibility is a port-specific governance issue. These five issues are important but not the only five issues. Other relevant issues include the relation between port and city and port expansion.

  13. Cooke (1998) uses the term ‘regional system of innovation’, Brackzyk et al (1998) the term ‘regional innovation systems’.

  14. Since labour is mobile, all firms in a cluster benefit indirectly from investments in training and education.

  15. Albertini (1999) argues that internationalisation is indeed to some extent a ‘collective process’: ‘the main transformation process can be identified in the evolution of the district from closed contextual ‘community networks’ to ‘semantic’ and ‘market’ networks –that are open and integrated with the global economy’ (Albertini, 1999, p. 113).

  16. Public authorities are generally deeply involved in safeguarding the quality of accessibility, through investing in infrastructure, infrastructure utilisation, and spatial planning.

  17. These experts are selected on the basis of three criteria: job position, years experience in the port industry and involvement in cluster governance. A first selection of about 38 was made in cooperation with Professor Welters, former director of the port association. This list with experts was supplemented based on the suggestions of the port experts. Overall, 43 of the 49 experts on the list were interviewed and filled out a questionnaire.

References

  • Albertini, S . 1999: Networking and division of labour – the case of industrial districts in the north-east of Italy. Human Systems Management 18: 107–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashar, A . 2001: Strategic pricing in newly privatised ports. International Journal of Maritime Economics 3: 52–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belussi, F, and Gottardi, G . 2000. Evolutionary patterns of local industrial systems: Towards a cognitive approach to the industrial district. Ashgate: Aldershot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bennett, RJ, 1998: Explaining the membership of voluntary local business associations: The example of British Chambers of Commerce. Regional Studies 32: 503–514.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Best, MH . 1990: The new competition: institutions of industrial restructuring. Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blackburn, R, Curran, J and Storey, D (eds). (1993: In Search of Spatial Differences: Evidence from a Study of Small Service Sector Enterprises. Routledge: London and New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braczyk, HJ, Cooke, P and Heidenreich, M . 1998: Regional innovation systems: The role of governances in a globalized world. UCL Press: London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, JL, Hollingsworth, JR and Lindberg, LN. (1991: Governance of the American Economy. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge [etc.].

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cooke, P . 1998: Regional systems of innovation: An evolutionary perspective. Environment and Planning A 30: 1563–1584.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edquist (ed) . 1997: Systems of innovation: Technologies, institutions, and organizations. Pinter: London [etc].

  • Haezendonck, E . 2001: Essays on strategy analysis for seaports. Garant: Leuven.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschmann, AO . 1970: Exit, voice, and loyalty: Responses to decline in firms, organizations, and states. Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hollingsworth, JS and Boyer, R (eds). 1997: Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge [etc].

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hollingsworth, JR, Schmitter, PC and Streeck, W . 1994: Governing capitalist economies: performance and control of economic sectors. Oxford University Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klink, HA van . 1995: Towards the Borderless Mainport Rotterdam – an analysis of functional, spatial and administrative dynamics in port systems. Thesis publishers: Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Langen, PW de . 2002: Clustering and performance; The case of maritime clustering in the Netherlands. Maritime Policy and Management 29; 209–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langen, PW de . 2004: The performance of seaport clusters, a framework to analyze cluster performance and an application to the seaport clusters of Durban, Rotterdam, and the lower Mississippi. ERIM PhD series, Rotterdam.

  • Lorenzoni, G and Baden-Fuller, C . 1995: Creating a Strategic center to manage a web of partners. California Management Review 37: 146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McEvily, B and Zaheer A . 1999: Bridging ties: A source of firm heterogeneity in competitive capabilities. Strategic Management Journal 20: 1133–1156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M . 1971:The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA [etc].

    Google Scholar 

  • Panniccia, I . 1999: The performance of industrial districts; some insights from the italian case. Human Systems Management 18: 141–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, ME . 1990: The competitive advantage of nations. MacMillan: London.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pouder, R and CH ST. John . 1996: Hot spot and blind spots: Geographical cluster of firms and innovation. Academy of Management Review 21: 1192–1225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nooteboom, B . 2000: Institutions and forms of co-ordination in innovation systems. Organization Studies 21: 915–932.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • RMPM. 2002: Annual Report. RMPM: Rotterdam.

  • Westlund, H . 1999: An interaction – cost perspective on networks and territory. The Annals of Regional Science 33: 93–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, OE . 1985: The economic institutions of capitalism: firms, markets, relational contracting. The Free Press; etc: New York.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Langen, P. Governance in Seaport Clusters. Marit Econ Logist 6, 141–156 (2004). https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.mel.9100100

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.mel.9100100

Keywords

Navigation