Skip to main content
Advertisement
Browse Subject Areas
?

Click through the PLOS taxonomy to find articles in your field.

For more information about PLOS Subject Areas, click here.

  • Loading metrics

Entangling Credit and Funding Shocks in Interbank Markets

Abstract

Credit and liquidity shocks represent main channels of financial contagion for interbank lending markets. On one hand, banks face potential losses whenever their counterparties are under distress and thus unable to fulfill their obligations. On the other hand, solvency constraints may force banks to recover lost fundings by selling their illiquid assets, resulting in effective losses in the presence of fire sales—that is, when funding shortcomings are widespread over the market. Because of the complex structure of the network of interbank exposures, these losses reverberate among banks and eventually get amplified, with potentially catastrophic consequences for the whole financial system. Inspired by the recently proposed Debt Rank, in this work we define a systemic risk metric that estimates the potential amplification of losses in interbank markets accounting for both credit and liquidity contagion channels: the Debt-Solvency Rank. We implement this framework on a dataset of 183 European banks that were publicly traded between 2004 and 2013, showing indeed that liquidity spillovers substantially increase systemic risk, and thus cannot be neglected in stress-test scenarios. We also provide additional evidence that the interbank market was extremely fragile up to the global financial crisis, becoming slightly more robust only afterwards.

Introduction

The recent financial crises have highlighted the importance to properly assess systemic risk in capital markets. In particular, both researchers and regulators realized that the financial system is actually more fragile than previously thought, because of the complexity of interconnections between financial institutions [15], resulting both from direct exposures to bilateral contracts and from indirect exposures to common assets [611]. Indeed, while interconnectedness means diversification and thus reduces individual risk, it can however increase systemic risk: financial distress can spread between institutions through such exposures and propagate over the market, leading to amplification effects like default cascades [1214]. Thus, much attention is being devoted nowadays to characterize the emerging network structure of financial markets from the viewpoint of systemic risk [1518]—especially in terms of counterparty and rollover risks caused by loans between institutions [19, 20]. Remarkably, the network-based approach allows to track the reverberation of a credit event or liquidity squeeze throughout the financial system, with important outputs like measures for potential capital losses and domino effect, and the identification of systemic and vulnerable institutions [1]. The shortcoming of requiring data on individual exposures, which are often privacy-protected and thus unaccessible, can be overcome by using either stylized banking systems (see, e.g., [18, 21]) or effective methods to reconstruct the network structure from the available data [22] (usually, the balance sheet composition of financial institution) [2333].

Here we focus on the interbank lending market, where banks temporarily short on liquidity borrow money for a specified term (mostly overnight) from other banks having excess liquidity, that in turn receive an interest on the loan. This market plays crucial role in the financial system, by allowing banks to cope with liquidity fluctuations and meet reserve requirements at the end of the trading day [3436]. Because of its structure, the interbank market can be properly represented as a directed weighted network, where interbank loans constitute the direct exposures between banks and allow for the propagation of financial distress in the system through two main mechanisms [1, 18, 21]: credit shocks and funding shocks. Credit losses are related to counterparty risk, and are faced by lender banks when their borrower banks default and fail to fulfill their obligations. These losses can then lead to the default of lenders, resulting in another wave of credit shocks. In a seminal paper, Eisenberg and Noe [37] developed an analytical framework to determine the set of payments that clear the network given an initial shock, assessing in this way how losses propagate through the system (see also [17, 38]). The Furfine algorithm [39] instead quantifies losses due to financial contagion by iteratively propagating distress from a defaulted bank to its creditors. In contrast, in the Debt Rank algorithm [40] credit shocks propagate also in the absence of defaults, provided that balance sheets are deteriorated: potential losses in the equity of a borrower translate into the devaluation of interbank assets of the corresponding lender [41, 42]. In this way Debt Rank accounts for the incremental build-up of distress in the system even before the occurrence of defaults, and thus seems appropriate for stress-test scenarios [43].

Funding shocks are instead related to rollover risk, and concern financial institutions subject to regulatory solvency constraints marking their assets to market in order to replace lost fundings [1, 4446]. If the interbank market is under distress and shrinks, banks short on liquidity may be unable to borrow all the money they need from the market, and be forced to sell their illiquid assets [47]. In the presence of fire sales, the market demand for illiquid assets becomes inelastic, depressing the market prices of these assets and resulting in effective losses for banks [48, 49]. These fire sales spillovers create the incentive to hoard liquidity [50, 51], which can in turn induce another wave of sales, activating a liquidity spiral that can lead the interbank market to freeze completely [5254]. Note that beyond a direct channel (funding losses combined with cash-flow constraints), fire sales may also originate indirectly through common assets holdings, or the leverage targeting policy adopted by banks [10, 43, 55]. In any event, liquidity spillovers were shown to represent an important dimension of overall systemic risk, comparable to counterparty domino effects [38].

In this work we aim at combining these two channels of financial contagion into a systemic risk metric for the spreading of potential losses in interbank markets. By doing so, we define the Debt-Solvency Rank, an extension of the Debt Rank framework to such a credit-funding shock scenario [1]. We build on the assumption that equity losses experienced by a bank do imply not only a decreasing value of its obligations, but also a decreasing ability to lend money to the market—even if no default has occurred. Such financial distress then reverberates throughout the market, turning into equity losses for other banks. We show that accounting for fire sales spillovers directly within the distress propagation dynamics leads to a more refined assessment of systemic risk for interbank markets, where liquidity issues represent a first-order correction to counterparty risk. We apply our method on a dataset of 183 European banks from 2004 to 2013, quantifying individual impact and vulnerability of these financial institutions over time. Our analysis confirms that liquidity issues are important for a correct systemic risk assessment, their effect being particularly relevant when credit risk peaks. We also provide additional evidence that the interbank market was extremely fragile up to the 2007–2008 crisis, and that afterwards microprudential policies and quick adoption of new regulations by banks actually increased the robustness of the system.

Data & Methods

Balance sheets basics and the interbank network

In order to characterize the interbank market, we use the Bureau van Dijk Bankscope database that contains yearly-aggregated balance sheets information of N = 183 large European banks, from 2004 to 2013. Raw data are available from Bureau van Dijk: https://bankscope.bvdinfo.com. Refer to [43] for all the details about the handling of missing data.

For each bank i and for each year T (we omit the year label for convenience), the balance sheet composition summarizes the financial position of the bank, and consists of assets with a positive economic value (loans, derivatives, stocks, bonds, real estate, and so on) and of liabilities with a negative economic value (such as customer deposits, and debits). To disentangle the interbank market from the overall financial system, we distinguish between interbank assets Ai (corresponding to the total loans to other banks) and external (non-interbank) assets , and between interbank liabilities Li (the total debts to other banks) and external (non-interbank) liabilities . The balance sheet identity for bank i defines its equity Ei (or tier capital) as the difference between its total assets and liabilities: (1) A bank is solvent as long as its equity is positive. In fact, negative equity means insolvency, as the bank cannot pay back its debs even by selling all of its assets. Here, following the literature on financial contagion [18, 19, 24], we take insolvency as a proxy for default. In the following, we denote the overall equity of the interbank market as E = ∑i Ei, and its total volume as C = ∑i Ai ≡ ∑i Li (see Table 1).

thumbnail
Table 1. Aggregate equity and volume of the interbank market (expressed in million USD) for the various years considered.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0161642.t001

For each bank i, its interbank assets and liabilities are aggregates of the individual loans to and borrowings from other banks: Ai = ∑j Aij and Li = ∑j Lij, where Aij is the amount of the loan extended by bank i to bank j, which represents an asset for bank i and a liability for bank j: thus LjiAiji, j. Hence, the interbank market can be represented as a directed weighted network, in which links correspond to exposures between banks [56, 57]. However, because of privacy issues, we do not have information on the individual loans and obligations. Yet, we can reconstruct the interbank network of exposures from aggregated interbank assets and liabilities by resorting to the two-step inference procedure described in [32], which was shown to be particularly effective in assessing the presence and extent of overnight interbank loans. In a nutshell, the method estimates individual exposures as: (2) where z is a parameter that controls for the density of the network and aij denotes the presence of the link. Here we set a network density of 10% and generate an ensemble of 1000 interbank networks. Results presented in this paper are averaged over this ensemble (we remand the reader to [32, 33] for a detailed network analysis of reconstructed interbank markets, and to [14, 41] for a spectral analysis of their connectivity matrices). Note that the probabilistic nature of the connections is particularly fit to represent overnight positions: we assume that contracts are continuously placed and immediately resolved and rolled over, a scenario in which credit and liquidity shocks can be assumed to hit the system and spread on the same temporal scale.

Credit & funding shocks

Having built the network of interbank exposures, we now describe the credit-funding shock dynamics on the interbank market [1, 21] that will be at the basis of the Debt-Solvency Rank. Suppose a generic bank u is hit by an exogenous shock (such as the sudden devaluation of its external assets) that causes u to become insolvent. This event triggers a cascade of losses in the network, through two distinct processes.

  1. Credit shock: bank u fails to meet its obligations, resulting in effective losses for its creditors. In particular, each other bank j suffers a loss equal to λAju, where 0 ≤ λ ≤ 1 indicates the amount of loss given default. Here we consider only uncollateralized markets (i.e., without a central counterparty that guarantees for interbank loans), and thus set λ = 1 always.
  2. Funding shock: banks are unable to replace all the liquidity previously granted by u; this, in turn, triggers a fire sale of assets. In particular, each other bank j can use its cash reserves to replenish only a fraction (1 − ρ) of the lost funding from u, and its illiquid assets trade at a discount (their market value is less that their book value), so that j must sell assets worth (1 + γ)ρAuj in book value terms—corresponding to an overall loss of γρAuj, where the parameter γ set the change in asset prices. In the following we will focus on two cases: ρ = 1, meaning that banks actually cannot replace the lost funding from u and are thus forced to entirely replenish the corresponding liquidity by assets sales; and ρ = 0, for which there are no funding shocks as banks always have enough liquid assets to cope with these losses.

Overall, the generic bank j faces a loss of λAju + γρAuj (the first term appears if j is a lender of u, and the second one if j is a borrower of u). Then, bank j also defaults if this loss exceeds Ej, and a new credit-funding shock propagates through the market, resulting in a wave of failures.

Before moving further, we discuss how to compute the coefficient γ that determines the losses due to funding shocks. Following a common approach [10, 18, 58, 59], here we assume that assets fire sales generate a linear impact on prices: given that Q = ρj Auj is the aggregate amount of assets that need to be liquidated, we set the price impact coefficient such that when Q = 0 the relative assets price change is Δp/p = 0 (i.e., no devaluation), and when Q = C it is Δp/p = −1 (assets value vanishes). This results in a price impact Δp/p = −Q/C. The coefficient C−1 in our case is of order 10−13 (see Table 1), meaning that 10bn euros of trading imbalances lead to a price change of order ten basis points—in line with [10]. Finally, to obtain the corresponding value of γ, it is sufficient to equate the relative loss γρ to the relative amount sold (1 + γ)ρ times the relative assets price change (−Δp/p), obtaining γ = [C/Q − 1]−1.

The Debt-Solvency (DS) Rank

We are now equipped to apply the credit-funding shock scenario described above to the Debt Rank framework. Before starting, we recall again the basic idea outlined [40]: the probabilities of banks default can be obtained by iteratively spreading the individual banks distress levels weighted by the potential wealth affected. In its original formulation, Debt Rank considers counterparty risk in a network of long-term interbank loans (in physics terminology, the network is said to be quenched). In this situation, liabilities stay at their face value, while assets are marked to market. The microscopic dynamics of distress propagation then works as follows [41]. If a bank u is hit by a shock and its equity decreases, also if u is still solvent the market value of its obligations decreases, because u is now “closer” to default and thus less likely to meet its obligation at maturity. This results in a loss on equity for the banks that have u’s obligations in their balance sheet, which in turn decrease the market value of these banks obligations, and so forth. Now, the Debt Rank assumes that relative changes of equity translate linearly into relative changes of asset values, resulting in an impact of bank u on bank j equal to λΛju = λAju/Ej, where Λ is the interbank leverage matrix [41, 43] (the same approach can be extended to non-linear impact functions [42]). Then, by iterating the described credit shocks dynamics, Debt Rank allows to compute the final level of financial distress in the network.

In contrast, in the interbank market the majority of contracts have overnight duration, meaning that they are placed and shortly after resolved and rolled-over: the network is said to be annealed, as links change continuously. In this situation, liabilities also change and may lead to funding shocks. In line with the original approach, we can assume that the ability of bank u to lend money to the market decreases proportionally to its equity, and that the liabilities (borrowings) of other banks towards u change in the same way. As funding shocks results in effective equity losses only in the presence of fire sales (i.e., when γ > 0), the impact of bank u on bank j in this case can be assessed as ργϒju = ργAuj/Ej. Overall, the impact of bank u on bank j due to both counterparty creditworthiness and liquidity shortage issues is λΛju + ργϒju. Importantly, we assume that these shocks happen on the same temporal scale. In this way, we can extend the Debt Rank formulation to a dynamics where the equity decrease of bank u causes an equity decrease both for the lenders of u because of credit shocks, and at the same time for the borrowers of u because of funding shocks.

We can formalize the above discussion as follows. The dynamics of shock propagation consists of several rounds {t}, and we are interested in quantifying the level of financial distress of each bank i and at each time step t, given by the relative change of equity: hi(t) = 1 − Ei(t)/Ei(0). By definition, hi = 0 when no equity losses occurred for bank i, hi = 1 when that bank defaults, and 0 < hi < 1 for intermediate distress levels. At step t = 0, there is no distress in the system, and thus hi(0) = 0 ∀i. At step t = 1, an exogenous shock hits the market causing a decrease of equity for some banks; hence, the set {hi(1)}i = 1, …, N represents the initial condition of the dynamics. Subsequent values of h are obtained by spreading this shock on the system, and writing up the equation for the evolution of banks equity [41]. By defining as the set of banks that have not defaulted up to time t − 1 (and thus can still spread their financial distress at t), we assume that a generic bank j propagates shocks as long as it keeps receiving them, i.e., provided that hj(t) > hj(t − 1). However, such a propagation is damped with a function D[(ttj)/τ], where tj denotes the time step when bank j first becomes distressed, tj: hj(tj) > 0 and hj(tj − 1) = 0, and τ is the damping scale. Overall, we get: (3) In this expression, according to the discussion in the previous paragraphs, the individual impact of bank j on bank i at step t is λΛij + ργ(t)ϒij, where the fire sale devaluation factor depends on time as γ(t) = {C/[ρQ(t)] − 1}−1. The aggregate amount of interbank assets potentially to be liquidated at t is in turn given by . Concerning the damping function, note that for generic bank j it plays a role only when ttj, as otherwise hj(t) = hj(t − 1) = 0. Importantly, it must have the properties D(0) = 1 and : the spreading is damped more and more with the propagation step, and eventually vanishes. An exponential shape D[(ttj)/τ] = exp[−(ttj)/τ] satisfies these properties, but alternative forms can be used as well. The damping scale τ sets the mean lifetime of the spreading. In the limit τ → 0, we have exp[−(ttj)/τ] → δ(ttj): banks spread their distress only once, as in [40]. In the opposite limit τ → ∞, exp[−(ttj)/τ] → 1: banks always propagate received shocks until they default, as in [41].

The above described dynamics stops at t* when no more banks can propagate their distress, i.e., hi(t*) = hi(t* − 1) ∀i. The overall Debt-Solvency (DS) Rank of the network is then obtained as: (4) where νi = Ei(0)/∑j Ej(0) = Ei(0)/E(0) is the relative importance of bank i in the system, and E(t) = ∑i Ei(t) is the total equity of the system at time t. DS(t*) thus represents the amount of equity that is potentially at risk in the system, given an initial shock {hi(1)}. Note that the original Debt Rank accounting only for credit shocks is recovered for λ = 1 and ρ = 0.

Results

Group DS Rank

We first consider the simplest case of an initial shock to the system corresponding to a fixed percentage (1 − ψ) of equity loss for each bank: Ei(1) = (1 − ψ)Ei(0) ∀i. Thus, hi(1) ≡ ψi and DS(t*) = 1 − ψE(t*)/E(0). Concerning the dynamics of shock propagation, we can easily study two limiting cases.

  • When ψ ≃ 0, we can safely assume that no bank has failed after the first propagation step: hi(2) < 1∀i. We thus have hi(2) = ψ{1 + ∑j[λΛij + ργ(1)ϒij]} ∀i and, after some algebra, , where γ(1) = ρψ/(1 − ρψ). For τ → 0, the dynamics stops at this stage as banks have already spread their distress once. For τ > 0, instead, the dynamics goes on and eventually banks start to default.
  • When ψ ≃ 1, all banks will ultimately fail after some rounds of distress propagation. In general, if at t = t* each bank has failed, we get hi(t*) = 1 ∀i and E(t*) = 0, so that .

Fig 1 shows the results of the group DS dynamics for two temporal snapshots of our dataset: 2008 (the year of the global financial crisis) and 2013 (the most recent year at our disposal). Panels (a) summarize the stationary profile of DS as a function of the initial shock ψ. Let us first consider the case τ = 0 of banks spreading their distress only once. As expected, for ψ ≃ 0 the system is close to the configuration of with no bank defaults. Then, as ψ increases, the overall equity loss grows, and after reaching its maximum value DS(t*) converges to the configuration with all bank defaults. The clear effect of liquidity shocks is that of increasing equity losses (especially in correspondence of the peak), and making the dynamics converge to for smaller initial shocks. Equity losses are however much heavier when subsequent rounds of shock propagation are allowed. In the extreme case τ → ∞, strikingly for year 2008 the dynamics converge to even if the initial distress is very small. By contrast, for year 2013 some banks survive, indicating a higher resilience of the system to financial distress. In any case, the dynamics needs more rounds to converge for small values of ψ, as shown in panels (b), and the fire sale devaluation factor γ eventually assumes values close to 1, as shown in panels (c): large fire sales are triggered at least once during the evolution of the system. By denoting the stationary value of DS Rank for a given value of ρ as DS[ρ](t*), we see from panels (d) that the progressive effect of liquidity shocks, given by the difference Δ[ρ] DS(t*) = DS[ρ](t*) − DS[0](t*) is almost linear in ρ, and can reach values up to 0.3 for ρ = 1. Finally, in order to gain insights on the reason why the resilience of the interbank market changed so significantly between the two considered years, we study the interbank leverage matrix, whose spectral properties determine the stability of the shock propagation dynamics [41]. By definition, the interbank leverage ratio of a bank i is given by Λi = ∑j Λij. Such value determines the bank resilience to credit shocks in the interbank market [41], with Λi < 1 representing the “safety” condition for which that bank has enough capital to cover the losses due to the simultaneous defaults of all its debtor banks. Here, in order to account also for liquidity shocks, we introduced an extended interbank leverage ratio λΛi + ρϒi, where ϒi = ∑jϒij and γ = 1 according to the analysis of panels (c). The shape of the probability distributions of original and extended leverage ratios in the banking system, shown in panels (e), reveals how these values were much higher in 2008 than in 2013, resulting in a more fragile system in the previous case. Indeed, since the breakdown of the interbank market at the global financial crisis, some banks started to adopt a precautionary hoarding policy (due to concerns about future liquidity needs), and other banks in turn responded to the liquidity hoarding of others by adopting the same behavior [50, 52]. While precautionary motives still affect the interbank market nowadays (its total volume being steadily decreasing since 2007, see Table 1), the resulting reduced leverage ratios resulted in a more stable system.

thumbnail
Fig 1. Detailed results of group DS Rank for years 2008 (upper panels) and 2013 (lower panels).

(a) Stationary value DS(t*) as a function of the initial shock ψ, in the cases of maximal or vanishing strength of liquidity shocks (ρ = 1 or ρ = 0, respectively) and of instantaneous or vanishing damping of shocks (τ = 0 and τ = ∞, respectively). (b,c) Temporal dynamics of the system: DS and fire sale devaluation factor γ as a function of ψ for various iteration steps t, in the setting with liquidity shocks ρ = 1 and multiple shocks propagation τ = ∞. (d) Progressive effect of liquidity shocks: difference Δ[ρ] DS(t*) between DS[ρ](t*) (when banks must sell illiquid assets for a fraction ρ of the lost funding) and DS[0](t*) (when no liquidity shocks occur), for ψ maximizing the overall equity loss. (e) Probability distributions of banks leverages Λ (black diamonds) and Λ + ϒ (blue circles), with relative median given by a dashed vertical line.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0161642.g001

While detailed results for other years can be found in S1 File, we can grasp the general systemic risk properties of the interbank market over the time span considered (2004–2013) from Fig 2, which shows color maps of the stationary group DS values for the various years and as a function of the initial shock ψ. For τ = 0, DS(t*) keeps its “inverse U” shape for all years. Yet, while in the absence of liquidity shocks systemic risk substantially decreases after 2008, these shocks do lead to an increase in equity losses that shows up especially in late years. A similar behavior is observed even more clearly for τ → ∞, as in this case the distance from the full-fail scenario after 2008 is dramatically reduced by the presence of liquidity shocks. Overall, these results point to the importance of considering liquidity shocks when assessing potential equity losses in the financial system. Notably, after 2008 liquidity risk has become more prominent for higher values of the initial shock: in complex network terminology, the system has become more robust for low ψ, yet more fragile for high ψ.

thumbnail
Fig 2. Heat maps of group DS(t*) as a function of ψ and of the year.

Upper plots refer to the case of no damping (τ = ∞) and lower plots to the case of instantaneous damping (τ = 0). Then, from left to right, plots show DS(t*) with liquidity shocks and ρ = 1, no liquidity shocks ρ = 0, and the difference between these values.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0161642.g002

Individual DS Rank

We now move to the case in which the initial shock to the market corresponds to the failure of an individual bank u: Eu(1) = 0 ⇒ hu(1) = 1 and Ei(1) = Ei(0)⇒hi(1) = 0 ∀iu. To make this initial condition explicit, we use the notation X(t|u) for the value of a generic quantity X at step t an when u is the initially shocked bank. We thus have DS(t*|u) = 1 − E(t*|u)/E(0) − νu. Using this framework, we can compute two bank-specific risk indicators:

  • Impact I, given by the relative equity loss experienced by the market after the initial default of that bank:
  • Vulnerability V, namely the relative equity loss for that bank averaged over the initial defaults of all other banks:

Fig 3 shows scatter plots of impact and vulnerability of individual banks again for years 2008 and 2013 (plots corresponding to other years can be found in S2 File). First note that, as expected, vulnerability clearly increases with the leverage ratio of the bank, whereas, impact is more related to the bank size (as measured by its initial equity). According to our data, interestingly the banks with the highest leverage have relatively small size, and despite being very vulnerable they lack the potential to affect the market significantly. Concerning the different shock propagation scenarios, in general we observe that the systemic impact of banks drops significantly from 2008 to 2013, while the decrease of systemic vulnerability is less evident but for multiple shock propagation τ → ∞. The effect of liquidity shocks is in turn that of increasing both measures. In particular, in year 2013 these shocks cause an increase of 100% (for τ = 0) and of 50% (for τ → ∞) for the impact of the largest banks, again underlying the importance of fire sale spillovers for a more robust assessment of systemic risk.

thumbnail
Fig 3. Scatter plot of impact and vulnerability values for each bank in years 2008 (upper panels) and 2013 (lower panels).

Here we show the cases of maximal or vanishing strength of liquidity shocks (ρ = 1 or ρ = 0, respectively) and of instantaneous or vanishing damping of shocks (τ = 0 and τ = ∞, respectively). The size of the bubble is non-linearly proportional to the initial equity of the corresponding bank: . The color of the contour is instead given by the value of the generalized leverage λΛi + ρϒi.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0161642.g003

We conclude by remarking that, according to our analysis, impact indeed correlates with size but is not a monotonic function of it: some banks can be more impactful on the system than others with larger equity or leverage. Thus, network features are important when determining the extent of financial contagion: with respect to banking systems regulation, relying on balance sheet constraints may be insufficient, and should be supplemented by considerations on the structure of the network [21].

Discussion

In this work we have focused on the interbank lending market, the network of financial interlinkages resulting from overnight loans between banks. This network represent an important sector of the whole financial system in terms of traded volumes [60], and is crucial for banks to cope with liquidity fluctuations and meet reserve requirements [36]. In spite of its role, the interbank market is quite fragile, as intrasystem cash fluctuations alone have the potential to lead to systemic defaults [60], and exceptional external shocks can lead the market to a complete drought [2]. In order to quantify potential equity losses in interbank markets resulting from exogenous shocks, building on [40], here we have defined a systemic risk metric that combines the dynamics of credit and liquidity shocks propagation [1]: the Debt-Solvency Rank. By applying this framework to a dataset of 183 European banks from 2004 to 2013, we have showed that fire sale spillovers do increase the overall equity loss by a factor up to 50%, and almost double the individual systemic impact of banks—especially in years after 2008. All these evidences point to the importance of considering liquidity risk in network-based stress tests. We also document that the interbank market was extremely fragile also before 2008, as in those years even the smallest initial shock would have caused all banks to default (provided no taming of shocks propagation). By contrast, after the crisis the market became able to absorb an increasing amount of financial distress.

We remark that the proposed dynamics of shocks propagation measures potential losses for banks, and thus do not include the possibility of rearranging balance sheet positions. In principle this means that contracts can be indeed rolled over, but for lesser amounts, and banks cannot establish new credit lines with other banks as they cannot provide additional liquidity to the market. But we do model exogenous effects: a loss given default λ < 1 corresponds to banks being able to recover part of their loans to distressed institutions from clearing houses, whereas, a lost funding recovery (1 − ρ) > 0 allows banks to replace a fraction of lost liquidity with own cash reserves or from central banks before liquidating assets. Note that in our framework fire sales happen simultaneously with the propagation of credit and funding shocks, and because banks are in need to recover lost fundings. In this respect, our approach is different from [43], where fire sales occur only after the distress propagation process and because of the target leverage policy adopted by banks. Also note that in our model we consider assets sales solely by banks, but these spillovers are likely to trigger additional sales by other financial institutions, which would depress prices even more. In this respect, in principle the DS Rank could be combined with the aggregated vulnerability framework of [10, 55] in order to consider liquidity contagion through both direct exposures and common asset holdings. Additionally, we have not considered in our model any liquidity hoarding behavior for banks. Overall, the effect of funding shocks might be much more relevant than what can be assessed through the DS Rank alone. Still, our approach can provide a useful lower bound for the potential impact of these shocks on the financial system, and indirectly on the real economy [61] (as banks suffering from liquidity shortages end up reducing their investments and affecting the economic growth). In any event, our analysis supports the thesis that liquidity requirements on financial institutions may be as effective as capital requirements in hindering contagious failures [18, 44].

Supporting Information

S1 Fig. Probability distributions for the average number of outgoing and incoming connections of banks, for years from 2004 to 2013.

For each bank i, the number of outgoing links is the number of debtors of i, namely its out-degree, and is defined as . Analogously, the number of incoming links is the number of creditors of i, namely its in-degree, defined as . Using Eq (2) we get and .

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0161642.s001

(PDF)

S1 File. Slideshow with results of group DS Rank for years from 2004 to 2013.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0161642.s002

(PDF)

S2 File. Slideshow with scatter plots of impact and vulnerability of individual banks for years from 2004 to 2013.

https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0161642.s003

(PDF)

Acknowledgments

We thank Marco Bardoscia, Paolo Barucca, Guido Caldarelli and Marco D’Errico for useful discussions. G.C. acknowledges support from the EU projects GROWTHCOM (FP7-ICT, n. 611272), MULTIPLEX (FP7-ICT, n. 317532), SIMPOL (FP7-ICT, n. 610704) and DOLFINS (H2020-EU.1.2.2., n. 640772). The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.

Author Contributions

  1. Conceptualization: GC MS
  2. Formal analysis: GC MS
  3. Investigation: GC MS
  4. Methodology: GC MS
  5. Resources: GC MS
  6. Software: GC
  7. Validation: GC MS
  8. Visualization: GC
  9. Writing original draft: GC MS
  10. Writing review & editing: GC

References

  1. 1. Chan-Lau JA, Espinosa M, Giesecke K, Solé JA. Assessing the Systemic Implications of Financial Linkages. IMF Global Financial Stability Report; 2009.
  2. 2. Brunnermeier MK. Deciphering the Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007–2008. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 2009;23(1):77–100.
  3. 3. Fouque JP, Langsam JA, editors. Handbook on Systemic Risk. Cambridge University Press; 2013.
  4. 4. Battiston S, Caldarelli G, May R, Roukny T, Stiglitz JE. The Price of Complexity in Financial Networks. SSRN:2594028. 2015;.
  5. 5. Battiston S, Farmer JD, Flache A, Garlaschelli D, Haldane AG, Heesterbeek H, et al. Complexity Theory and Financial Regulation. Science. 2016;351(6275):818–819. pmid:26912882
  6. 6. Allen F, Gale D. Financial Contagion. Journal of Political Economy. 2000;108(1):1–33.
  7. 7. Gai P, Haldane A, Kapadia S. Complexity, Concentration and Contagion. Journal of Monetary Economics. 2011;58(5):453–470.
  8. 8. Bluhm M, Krahnen JP. Default Risk in an Interconnected Banking System with Endogeneous Asset Markets. Center for Financial Studies; 2011. 2011/19.
  9. 9. Acemoglu D, Ozdaglar A, Tahbaz-Salehi A. Systemic Risk and Stability in Financial Networks. American Economic Review. 2015;105(2):564–608.
  10. 10. Greenwood R, Landier A, Thesmar D. Vulnerable Banks. Journal of Financial Economics. 2015;115(3):471–485.
  11. 11. Gualdi S, Cimini G, Primicerio K, Clemente RD, Challet D. Statistically Similar Portfolios and Systemic Risk. arXiv:160305914. 2016;.
  12. 12. Corsi F, Marmi S, Lillo F. When Micro Prudence Increases Macro Risk: The Destabilizing Effects of Financial Innovation, Leverage, and Diversification. SSRN:2278298. 2013;.
  13. 13. Caccioli F, Shrestha M, Moore C, Farmer JD. Stability Analysis of Financial Contagion due to Overlapping Portfolios. Journal of Banking & Finance. 2014;46:233–245.
  14. 14. Bardoscia M, Battiston S, Caccioli F, Caldarelli G. Pathways Towards Instability in Financial Networks. arXiv:160205883. 2016;.
  15. 15. Boss M, Elsinger H, Summer M, Thurner S. Network Topology of the Interbank Market. Quantitative Finance. 2004;4(6):677–684.
  16. 16. Iori G, Jafarey S, Padilla FG. Systemic Risk on the Interbank Market. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 2006;61(4):525–542.
  17. 17. Elsinger H, Lehar A, Summer M. Risk Assessment for Banking Systems. Management Science. 2006;52(9):1301–1314.
  18. 18. Nier EW, Yang J, Yorulmazer T, Alentorn A. Network Models and Financial Stability; 2008. 346.
  19. 19. Gai P, Kapadia S. Contagion in Financial Networks. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London A: Mathematical, Physical and Engineering Sciences. 2010;466(2120):2401–2423.
  20. 20. Haldane AG, May RM. Systemic Risk in Banking Ecosystems. Nature. 2011;469:351–355. pmid:21248842
  21. 21. Krause A, Giansante S. Interbank Lending and the Spread of Bank Failures: A Network Model of Systemic Risk. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 2012;83(3):583–608.
  22. 22. Caldarelli G, Chessa A, Pammolli F, Gabrielli A, Puliga M. Reconstructing a Credit Network. Nature Physics. 2013;9:125–126.
  23. 23. Wells SJ. Financial Interlinkages in the United Kingdom’s Interbank Market and the Risk of Contagion. Bank of England; 2004. 230.
  24. 24. Upper C. Simulation Methods to Assess the Danger of Contagion in Interbank Markets. Journal of Financial Stability. 2011;7(3):111–125.
  25. 25. Mastromatteo I, Zarinelli E, Marsili M. Reconstruction of Financial Networks for Robust Estimation of Systemic Risk. Journal of Statistical Mechanics: Theory and Experiment. 2012;2012(03):P03011.
  26. 26. Baral P, Fique JP. Estimation of Bilateral Exposures—A Copula Approach; 2012.
  27. 27. Drehmann M, Tarashev N. Measuring the Systemic Importance of Interconnected Banks. Journal of Financial Intermediation. 2013;22(4):586–607.
  28. 28. Hałaj G, Kok C. Assessing Interbank Contagion Using Simulated Networks. Computational Management Science. 2013;10(2):157–186.
  29. 29. Anand K, Craig B, von Peter G. Filling in the Blanks: Network Structure and Interbank Contagion. Deutsche Bundesbank Research Centre; 2014. 02/2014.
  30. 30. Montagna M, Lux T. Contagion Risk in the Interbank Market: A Probabilistic Approach to Cope with Incomplete Structural Information. Kiel Institute for the World Economy; 2014.
  31. 31. Peltonen TA, Rancan M, Sarlin P. Interconnectedness of the Banking Sector as a Vulnerability to Crises. European Central Bank; 2015. 1866.
  32. 32. Cimini G, Squartini T, Garlaschelli D, Gabrielli A. Systemic Risk Analysis on Reconstructed Economic and Financial Networks. Scientific Reports. 2015;5:15758. pmid:26507849
  33. 33. Cimini G, Squartini T, Gabrielli A, Garlaschelli D. Estimating Topological Properties of Weighted Networks from Limited Information. Physical Review E. 2015;92:040802.
  34. 34. Wiemers J, Neyer U. Why Do We Have an Interbank Money Market? Halle Institute for Economic Research; 2003. 182.
  35. 35. Angelini P, Nobili A, Picillo C. The Interbank Market after August 2007: What Has Changed, and Why? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 2011;43(5):923–958.
  36. 36. Allen F, Hryckiewicz A, Kowalewski O, Tümer-Alkan G. Transmission of Financial Shocks in Loan and Deposit Markets: Role of Interbank Borrowing and Market Monitoring. Journal of Financial Stability. 2014;15:112–126.
  37. 37. Eisenberg L, Noe TH. Systemic Risk in Financial Systems. Management Science. 2001;47(2):236–249.
  38. 38. Glasserman P, Young HP. How Likely is Contagion in Financial Networks? Journal of Banking & Finance. 2015;50:383–399.
  39. 39. Furfine CH. Interbank Exposures: Quantifying the Risk of Contagion. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 2003;35(1):111–128.
  40. 40. Battiston S, Puliga M, Kaushik R, Tasca P, Caldarelli G. DebtRank: Too Central to Fail? Financial Networks, the FED and Systemic Risk. Scientific Reports. 2012;2:541. pmid:22870377
  41. 41. Bardoscia M, Battiston S, Caccioli F, Caldarelli G. DebtRank: A Microscopic Foundation for Shock Propagation. PLoS ONE. 2015;10(6):e0130406. pmid:26091013
  42. 42. Bardoscia M, Caccioli F, Perotti JI, Vivaldo G, Caldarelli G. Distress Propagation in Complex Networks: The Case of Non-linear DebtRank. arXiv:151204460. 2015;.
  43. 43. Battiston S, Caldarelli G, D’Errico M, Gurciullo S. Leveraging the Network: A Stress-test Framework Based on DebtRank. arXiv:150300621. 2015;.
  44. 44. Cifuentes R, Ferrucci G, Shin HS. Liquidity Risk and Contagion. Journal of the European Economic Association. 2005;3(2/3):556–566.
  45. 45. Kapadia S, Drehmann M, Elliott J, Sterne G. In: Liquidity Risk, Cash Flow Constraints, and Systemic Feedbacks. University of Chicago Press; 2012. p. 29–61.
  46. 46. Anand K, Gai P, Marsili M. Rollover Risk, Network Structure and Systemic Financial Crises. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. 2012;36(8):1088–1100.
  47. 47. Brunnermeier MK, Pedersen LH. Market Liquidity and Funding Liquidity. Review of Financial Studies. 2009;22(6):2201–2238.
  48. 48. Adrian T, Shin HS. Liquidity and Leverage. Journal of Financial Intermediation. 2010;19(3):418–437.
  49. 49. Diamond DW, Rajan RG. Fear of Fire Sales and the Credit Freeze. National Bureau of Economic Research; 2009. 14925.
  50. 50. Berrospide JM. Bank Liquidity Hoarding and the Financial Crisis: An Empirical Evaluation. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.); 2013. 03.
  51. 51. Gale D, Yorulmazer T. Liquidity Hoarding. Theoretical Economics. 2013;8(2):291–324.
  52. 52. Acharya VV, Skeie D. A Model of Liquidity Hoarding and Term Premia in Inter-bank Markets. Journal of Monetary Economics. 2011;58(5):436–447.
  53. 53. Acharya VV, Merrouche O. Precautionary Hoarding of Liquidity and Interbank Markets: Evidence from the Subprime Crisis. Review of Finance. 2013;17(1):107–160.
  54. 54. Silvia G, Georg CP. A Network View on Interbank Market Freezes. Banque de France; 2014. 531.
  55. 55. Duarte FM, Eisenbach TM. Fire-Sale Spillovers and Systemic Risk. Federal Reserve Bank of New York; 2015. 645.
  56. 56. Iori G, Masi GD, Precup OV, Gabbi G, Caldarelli G. A Network Analysis of the Italian Overnight Money Market. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control. 2008;32(1):259–278.
  57. 57. Barucca P, Lillo F. Disentangling Bipartite and Core-Periphery Structure in Financial Networks. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals. 2016;
  58. 58. Ellul A, Jotikasthira C, Lundblad CT. Regulatory Pressure and Fire Sales in the Corporate Bond Market. Journal of Financial Economics. 2011;101(3):596–620.
  59. 59. Feldhütter P. The Same Bond at Different Prices: Identifying Search Frictions and Selling Pressures. Review of Financial Studies. 2012;25(4):1155–1206.
  60. 60. Smaga P, Wiliński M, Ochnicki P, Arendarski P, Gubiec T. Can Banks Default Overnight? Modeling Endogenous Contagion on O/N Interbank Market. arXiv:160305142. 2016;.
  61. 61. Gabbi G, Iori G, Jafarey S, Porter J. Financial Regulations and Bank Credit to the Real Economy. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control. 2015;50:117–143.