Skip to content
Publicly Available Published by De Gruyter December 8, 2015

Estimating Sourcing Premia Using Italian Regional Data

  • Valeria Gattai ORCID logo EMAIL logo and Valentina Trovato

Abstract

This paper explores the link between sourcing and performance for a representative sample of manufacturing firms located in Lombardy, which is the leading region of the Italian economy. The survey estimation methods that we applied to our original database reveal certain performance premia for firms that engage in foreign rather than domestic sourcing and in- rather than outsourcing. This result is robust to different specifications, samples, performance measures, and definitions of sourcing strategies.

JEL: D23; F23; L23

1 Introduction

The present paper aims to estimate sourcing premia using Italian regional data.

Our interest in this topic is motivated by two main facts. First, firms that are committed to global markets make crucial decisions about sourcing, i.e., they choose the tasks that should be performed intra- or extra-firm in the domestic or foreign markets. Second, firms that are involved in international business exhibit certain internationalization premia, i.e., they are larger, more productive, or more capital intensive than purely domestic firms are.

Estimating sourcing premia means detecting any systematic performance difference among firms that are characterized by different sourcing behavior. [1]

We believe that this is an interesting research question that has been only partially addressed in previous papers. Indeed, there is literature on global sourcing under contractual incompleteness that provides a basic taxonomy of sourcing strategies (for a survey, see: Spencer 2005; Gattai 2006; Antras and Rossi-Hansberg 2009; Antras 2014) and literature on internationalization and performance that investigates internationalization premia (for a survey, see: Lopez 2005; Wagner 2007, 2012; Greenaway and Kneller 2007; Singh 2010; Hayakawa, Kimura, and Machikita 2012). However, from our point of view, these strands do not convincingly address sourcing premia because they are concerned with either defining sourcing strategies or estimating trade premia.

To fill this gap, we integrate the two strands mentioned above, deriving the basic taxonomy of sourcing strategies from the former and the entire array of performance measures from the latter.

In the end, we pursue an open search for sourcing premia by using original survey data on a representative sample of manufacturing enterprises located in Lombardy, which is the leading region of the Italian economy. Lombardy accounts for 28% of Italy’s total exports and 31% of imports; it involves 49% of inward and 35% of outward FDI, and it contributes to 21% of value added, 21% of GDP, and 29% of patent applications (ASR 2013). Moreover, the region exhibits a mature and highly heterogeneous industrial system, which makes it a suitable locus for investigating sourcing premia in a context of heterogeneity (Garofoli 1983; Corò and Grandinetti 1999; Garofoli 2002; Cusmano and Malerba 2005).

Our empirical analysis unveils certain performance differences among firms that make different sourcing decisions. Survey estimation methods reveal that foreign rather than domestic sourcing and in- rather than outsourcing [2] entail significant sales, value added, capital, productivity, profit, and skill intensity premia for Lombardy’s enterprises, and this result is robust to different specifications, samples, performance measures, and definitions of sourcing strategies.

We believe our approach entails a few novelties compared with the existing literature. They concern the research question, data, and methodology. For the first issue, our attempt at integrating the two strands allows us to broaden the scope for research. Instead of studying the correlation between productivity and sourcing, as in the global sourcing under contractual incompleteness literature, or the correlation between performance and internationalization, as in the internationalization and performance literature, we analyze the link between sourcing and performance and thus provide a wider framework [3] that encompasses previous empirical models. For the second issue, there is something unique to our data. On the one hand, they cover a different sample of firms for which it is interesting to replicate previous empirical exercises. On the other hand, and more importantly, we have information regarding firms’ organizational choices for every task performed in the production process. This leads to our main contribution, which is on methodological grounds. Notably, we introduce an unprecedentedly rich taxonomy of sourcing strategies that distinguishes between mutually inclusive versus mutually exclusive and conservative versus liberal definitions. This results in a deeper characterization of firms’ sourcing behaviors and eventually challenges previous findings by Kohler and Smolka (2011, 2012), and Federico (2010) based on a more elementary taxonomy.

For all of these reasons, we believe the present paper should be regarded as highly complementary to the previous ones on related topics.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 conducts a brief literature review and explains how this contribution concretely fits into the existing literature; Section 3 provides the data description; Section 4 defines sourcing strategies and comments on their descriptive statistics; Section 5 is completely devoted to the econometric analysis; and Section 6 concludes and sets forth future lines of research.

2 Literature Review

In this section, we briefly review the two strands of the literature that inspired the present research.

2.1 Global Sourcing under Contractual Incompleteness

For the sake of simplicity, consider a very stylized framework in which a firm is willing to produce a final good; the final-good production requires two tasks – input manufacturing and final-good processing – and the enterprise itself is responsible for processing. Under these assumptions, the firm can either manufacture components within its boundaries or purchase them from an independent supplier; moreover, inputs can be made or bought in either the home or the host country. Depending on whether the input supplier is a domestic or a foreign enterprise and whether it belongs to the firm or it does not, four sourcing strategies may emerge, namely, domestic integration (DI), domestic outsourcing (DO), foreign integration (FI), and foreign outsourcing (FO) [4] (Antras and Helpman 2004).

From a theoretical point of view, one candidate explanation of global sourcing stems from the wish to mitigate hold-up concerns in a context of contractual incompleteness.

The original intuitions of Grout (1984), Grossman and Hart (1986), and Hart and Moore (1990) are extended to the international context in McLaren (2000), Grossman and Helpman (2002, 2003, 2005), Antras (2003), Ottaviano and Turrini (2007), and Antras and Helpman (2004, 2008).

The framework maintained across these models is that a firm located in the north is the final-good producer and that final-good production requires relationship-specific investments to manufacture components. The difference is, instead, in the number of sourcing strategies that are analyzed. In particular, McLaren (2000), and Grossman and Helpman (2002) focus on DI as opposed to DO; Grossman and Helpman (2005) on DO rather than FO; and Grossman and Helpman (2003), Antras (2003), and Ottaviano and Turrini (2007) on FI rather than FO. Antras and Helpman (2004, 2008) [5] are the only contributions that offer the full characterization of all sourcing modes in a unitary framework.

Despite the subset of strategies that are considered in the different papers, a common message emerges from this theoretical literature. In choosing between in- and outsourcing, firms trade off the benefits of ownership under the former with the benefits of better incentives for the manufacturer under the latter. In choosing between domestic and foreign sourcing, final-good producers trade off the benefits of lower variable costs in the south with the benefits of lower fixed organizational costs in the north. By combining these effects, one obtains a clear understanding of the main factors that affect firm sourcing behavior.

An additional interesting question regards which firms are more likely to choose a specific sourcing strategy rather than the others. Clearly, this issue can be addressed only in a heterogeneous firm framework, as in Antras and Helpman (2004, 2008). Building on Melitz (2003), those authors assume that upon paying fixed entry costs, final-good producers draw a productivity level from a known distribution; after observing that level, each of them decides whether to exit the market or to start producing. In the end, the two papers demonstrate that in low-tech sectors, integration never occurs: Lower-productivity players choose DO, and higher-productivity players select FO. On the contrary, in high-tech sectors, all sourcing strategies may be undertaken: Lower-productivity firms buy inputs in the domestic market, and higher productivity firms buy inputs in the foreign market; among firms that source in the same country, the more productive ones vertically integrate, and the less productive outsource. These results provide unambiguous predictions about firm sorting into different sourcing modes. Put another way, firms are expected to self-select into one of the four mutually exclusive alternatives – DO, DI, FO, and FI – depending on their productivity levels.

In the last few years, a burgeoning empirical literature has grown rapidly that brings the intuition of Antras and Helpman (2004, 2008) to the data. The availability of large longitudinal datasets at the micro-level has recently helped obtain interesting findings about productivity and sourcing behavior and have offered a preliminary test of certain theoretical results and adding to previous industry-level evidence (Antras 2003; Nunn and Trefler 2008; Yeaple 2006; Federico 2012; Bernard et al. 2010).

Empirical papers of this sort differ in terms of their sourcing modes and geographical coverage. For the former issue, the majority of studies consider only a subset of strategies depending on the data availability. For instance, Tomiura (2005, 2009) and Ito, Tomiura, and Wakasugi (2011) focus on FO as opposed to DO, and Tomiura (2007a), Defever and Toubal (2013), and Corcos et al. (2013) study FO instead of FI, whereas Tomiura (2007b), Federico (2010), and Kohler and Smolka (2011, 2012) are the only papers to consider all strategies in the same econometric model, capturing the original spirit of Antras and Helpman (2004, 2008). For the geographical coverage, the existing studies provide evidence only for Japan (Tomiura 2005, 2007a, 2007b, 2009; Ito, Tomiura and Wakasugi 2011), France (Defever and Toubal 2013; Corcos et al. 2013), Italy (Federico 2010), and Spain (Kohler and Smolka 2011, 2012).

Despite these differences, important regularities also emerge throughout the empirical literature. First, heterogeneity is measured quite consistently in terms of labor and total factor productivity; second, the results are quite similar: Firms that source abroad are, on average, better than firms that source domestically; moreover, vertically integrated enterprises are, on average, better than outsourcers. By and large, these findings are consistent with the theoretical framework of Antras and Helpman (2004, 2008) in that the most productive firms choose FI and the least productive opt for DO. However, no definite ranking emerges that encompasses all sourcing strategies because firms with intermediate levels of productivity self-select into either DI or FO (see, for instance, Federico 2010; Kohler and Smolka 2011). Hence, the theoretical sorting of firms into sourcing modes is preserved only at the extremes.

How does our contribution fit into the literature on global sourcing under contractual incompleteness? Estimating sourcing premia, in the global sourcing jargon, means analyzing the matching between heterogeneous enterprises and organizational modes. Our contribution then lays in the measure of heterogeneity, which is not restricted to productivity, and the characterization of organizational modes, which includes all sourcing strategies dissected by production tasks. Addressing the whole set of organizational modes, heterogeneity dimensions and definitions of sourcing strategies, we develop a wide research framework that encompasses previous results as a special case.

2.2 Internationalization and Performance

Starting from the seminal contribution of Bernard and Jensen (1995), a large number of scholars have investigated the relationship between internationalization and performance at the micro-level.

They document that globally engaged enterprises tend to be a minority compared with purely domestic players, but they perform better on a number of economic variables, including sales, wage, value added, and productivity.

Those authors also suggest two alternative but not mutually exclusive explanations for why firms that are involved in international business are better than domestic enterprises. Under the so-called self-selection argument, there are ex-ante performance differences between firms that will become international and firms that will keep serving the domestic market. The intuition is that operating abroad involves additional costs related to transportation, marketing, human capital and production that provide a natural entry barrier to less successful firms.

Under the so-called learning-by-internationalization argument, ex post performance differences emerge, instead, as a result of firm exposure to international markets. This is because in interacting with foreign competitors and customers, firms derive information about reducing costs and quality rising processes; moreover, to keep pace with their rivals, they are strongly encouraged to innovate, increase their scales, and become more efficient.

Since the publication of the research of Bernard and Jensen (1995), a rapidly growing body of empirical literature has comprehensively investigated these issues, identifying typical internationalization premia, defined as the average percentage differences in performance between international and domestic players.

In the following, we focus more specifically on the papers that address the internationalization and performance of Italian enterprises to allow for comparing the results in Sections 4 and 5, in which we present original evidence from the same country. [6] For expositional convenience, we review the related literature according to the following issues. First, we portray the global involvement of Italian firms considering the relative prevalence of different internationalization strategies; second, we discuss the main internationalization premia as highlighted in the existing studies.

With regard to the first issue, evidence provides unambiguous results. Italian firms are active in a number of internationalization strategies, which range from importing to exporting, from FDI to international outsourcing, and from international partnerships to subcontracting. If one considers these strategies together, global firms prove to be the majority compared with purely domestic players (Basile, Giunta, and Nugent 2003; Benfratello and Razzolini 2009; Castellani and Zanfei 2007). If one instead considers one strategy at a time, different patterns emerge. In particular, exporters and importers tend to be quite numerous, representing more than 50% of the entire population (see, among others, Crinò and Epifani 2012; ISGEP 2008; Razzolini and Vannoni 2011; Serti and Tomasi 2008b, 2012; Serti, Tomasi, and Zanfei 2010). On the contrary, firms that engage in FDI represent a minority, accounting for less than 10% of the overall sample (Barba Navaretti et al. 2011; Casaburi, Gattai, and Minerva 2007; Castellani and Giovannetti 2010; Giovannetti, Ricciuti, and Vilucchi 2009), and the same is the case for international outsourcing (Barba Navaretti et al. 2011; Casaburi, Gattai, and Minerva 2007).

With regard to the second issue, the majority of the literature emphasizes the existence of some internationalization premia related to the foreign exposure of Italian enterprises. [7] Notably, each category of foreign involvement entails certain performance advantages compared with the purely domestic operations (see, among others, Basile 2001; Bratti and Felice 2012; Castellani 2007; Mayer and Ottaviano 2007). Furthermore, a systematic performance ranking emerges for players characterized by different degrees of internationalization or that pursue more than a single strategy, with FDI makers at the top and exporters at the bottom (see, for instance, Benfratello and Razzolini 2009; Casaburi, Gattai, and Minerva 2007; Castellani and Zanfei 2007; Serti and Tomasi 2008b, 2012; Castellani, Serti, and Tomasi 2010; Mayer and Ottaviano 2007; Castellani and Giovannetti 2010). Finally, there is evidence in favor of both self-selection and learning-by-internationalization (see, for instance, Basile 2001; Bratti and Felice 2012; Castellani and Giovannetti 2010; Ferragina and Quintieri 2001; ISGEP 2008; Serti and Tomasi 2008a, 2012).

How does our contribution fit into the literature on internationalization and performance? Estimating sourcing premia in the internationalization and performance jargon can be rephrased as searching for systematic performance differences between firms that choose foreign sourcing, our “international” players, and firms that choose domestic sourcing, our “domestic” players. Because domestic and foreign sourcing can be further dissected by firms’ ownership decisions, we end up with a wider framework in which different types of domestic and international enterprises can be considered at the same time. Therefore, we expect to obtain more general results to be compared with the FDI and international outsourcing premia that were detected before.

3 Data

The present study draws on an original survey that we conducted between 2010 and 2011 of a representative sample of manufacturing firms located in Lombardy.

Our target sample of 300 firms is drawn from the national firm Census (ISTAT 2001) and stratified according to geographical location, manufacturing activity, and firm size. Geographical location stratification is based on four macro areas that group neighboring provinces according to their productive specialization; they are designated as follows: northwest (including Como, Lecco, and Varese), northeast (including Bergamo, Brescia, and Sondrio), southwest (including Lodi, Milano, Monza Brianza, and Pavia), and southeast (including Cremona and Mantova). The manufacturing activity stratification follows the taxonomy of Bell and Pavitt (1993), which groups industries into four macro categories according to the source of technology and technical change; they are designated as supplier-dominated, specialized-supplier-dominated, science-based and scale-intensive. Firm size stratification reflects the number of employees, and it is based on three main cells: firms with fewer than 50 employees, firms with 50–249 employees, and firms with more than 249 employees.

The number of firms in each stratum of the target sample was obtained to ensure proportionality to the total number of firms in the same stratum of the population.

All firms were contacted by phone, and a multiple-choice questionnaire was submitted by email (70%) or fax (30%) to senior managers and CEOs.

The questionnaire consists of two sections: First, we ask about the background information of the local firms, including balance sheet details and intangible assets for the period 2005–2009; second, we investigate their sourcing behavior and international experience in 2007. This approach to the data collection reflects our attempt to exclude any effects of the financial crises on sourcing behavior and international experience, as self-reported by firms, while benefiting from a longer time span for the performance variables.

With a response rate of 76%, this study provides a detailed outline of 228 enterprises.

As displayed in Table 1, our sample is highly representative of the entire population.

Table 1:

Sample versus population of Lombardy enterprises, by geographical location, manufacturing activity, and firm size.

SamplePopulation
No. firms%No. firms%
Geographical location
Northwest6126.7517,40020.54
Northeast6930.2624,69529.15
Southwest8336.4036,06442.57
Southeast156.586,5537.74
Manufacturing activity
Supplier-dominated7432.4626,60731.41
Specialized-supplier-dominated3716.2316,00618.89
Science-based114.824,6645.51
Scale-intensive10646.4937,43544.19
Firm size
<5021794.9081,66796.41
50–24994.142,6673.15
>24920.963780.45
Tot. manufacturing228100.0084,712100.00

Concerning the geographical location, the majority of firms are from the southwest of the region (36.4%), followed by the northeast (30.26%), the northwest (26.75%), and the southeast (6.58%). This suggests that the manufacturing core of Lombardy is centered in Lodi, Milano, Monza Brianza, and Pavia, whereas Cremona and Mantova account for a limited share of the local business.

For the manufacturing activity, scale-intensive operations prove to be the main economic activity, involving 46.49% of the sampled firms. They are followed closely by the supplier-dominated (32.46%) industry, and the specialized-supplier-dominated (16.23%) and science-based (4.82%) industries represent the smallest segments. These data confirm that the industrial texture of the region is highly diversified, with multiple specializations leading to a balanced mixture of traditional and high-tech activities.

Finally, with respect to firm size, our sample is characterized by the sharp prevalence of small enterprises (94.9%) with fewer than 50 employees. On the contrary, medium and large firms account for a limited 4.14% and 0.96% of the total, respectively. Given the well-documented relevance of Lombardy for the Italian economy (ASR 2013), this suggests that a mass of small and medium enterprises, rather than a handful of huge conglomerates, is responsible for remarkable shares of the national value added, GDP, export, import, and FDI.

4 Definition of Sourcing Strategies and Descriptive Statistics

In this section, we provide a detailed definition of sourcing strategies and comment on the descriptive statistics to portray Lombardy firms’ global sourcing.

4.1 Definition of Sourcing Strategies

Defining sourcing strategies correctly is crucial to the present study. The main challenge of our survey is to obtain all of the relevant information to translate the theoretical definition into a convenient empirical proxy.

According to the theory, firms are uniquely mapped into four mutually exclusive sourcing strategies depending on their ownership and location responses to input procurement concerns. As mentioned in Section 2, this is the result of two simplifying assumptions: First, the production process involves only two tasks; and second, ownership and location decisions apply only to one task.

In designing the questionnaire, we relaxed these assumptions in a way that provided a richer taxonomy of sourcing strategies while preserving the stylized theoretical framework as a special case. More precisely, we disaggregate the production process into four tasks, rather than two: input manufacturing, final-good processing, research & development (R&D), and other services (e.g., informative, logistics). Moreover, we allow firms to engage in the ownership and location decisions for every task performed in their production process, not solely for input manufacturing. In this way, we are able to collect very detailed information on which tasks are performed within the boundaries of the firm, a foreign affiliate, an independent Italian firm, and an independent foreign firm. Unlike the stylized theoretical framework delineated in Section 2, these are not intended as mutually exclusive categories, which means that the same task may be performed both intra- and extra-firm and both domestically and abroad.

Drawing on our survey data, we give four definitions of DO, DI, FO, and FI.

First, we distinguish between the so-called conservative and liberal definitions of sourcing strategies (Table 2). Consistent with the theory, the former focuses only on input manufacturing, whereas the latter considers all production tasks except for final-good processing. [8] The main advantage of the conservative definition is that the results are likely to be neat and not difficult to confront with the theoretical priors; however, the definition exploits only part of the information that was collected from the survey interviews, thus offering a somewhat standard treatment of sourcing strategies. The liberal definition creates, instead, a more general overview of firms’ organizational solutions. Taking advantage of the rich dataset might disclose new facts about global sourcing; however, evaluating its results according to the theory is not clear.

Table 2:

Conservative versus liberal definitions of sourcing strategies.

Sourcing strategyConservative definitionLiberal definition
Firms are said to engage in:
DOWhen they perform a positive fraction of input manufacturing within the boundaries of an independent Italian firm.When they perform a positive fraction of input manufacturing or R&D or other services within the boundaries of an independent Italian firm.
DIWhen they perform a positive fraction of input manufacturing within their boundaries.When they perform a positive fraction of input manufacturing or R&D or other services within their boundaries.
FOWhen they perform a positive fraction of input manufacturing within the boundaries of an independent foreign firm.When they perform a positive fraction of input manufacturing or R&D or other services within the boundaries of an independent foreign firm.
FIWhen they perform a positive fraction of input manufacturing within the boundaries of a foreign affiliate.When they perform a positive fraction of input manufacturing or R&D or other services within the boundaries of a foreign affiliate.

Second, we distinguish between the so-called mutually inclusive and mutually exclusive definitions of sourcing strategies (Table 3). In the former case, we assign to each firm any sourcing strategy that results from the interviews, whereas in the latter case, we assign each firm only one sourcing strategy. Following Kohler and Smolka (2011), when a firm is active in two or more sourcing modes simultaneously, it is assigned the least prevalent category in the overall sample, according to the ranking of the most frequent choice, that is, DI-DO-FO-FI. [9] The main advantage of the mutually inclusive definition is that it preserves all information from the data; however, the results might be difficult to interpret in light of the theoretical models. The mutually exclusive definition is, in contrast, more arbitrary in that we make a choice, out of a set, regarding the strategy that should be assigned to each firm; however, the results are likely to be clear and not difficult to confront with the theoretical predictions.

Table 3:

Mutually inclusive versus mutually exclusive definitions of sourcing strategies.

Sourcing strategyMutually inclusive definitionMutually exclusive definition
Firms are said to engage in:
DOWhen they perform any of the following combinations of sourcing strategies: DO, DIDO, DOFI, DOFO, DIDOFI, DIDOFO, DOFIFO, DIDOFIFOWhen they perform any of the following combinations of sourcing strategies: DO, DIDO
DIWhen they perform any of the following combinations of sourcing strategies: DI, DIDO, DIFI, DIFO, DIDOFI, DIDOFO, DIFIFO, DIDOFIFOWhen they perform any of the following combinations of sourcing strategies: DI
FOWhen they perform any of the following combinations of sourcing strategies: FO, DIFO, DOFO, FIFO, DIDOFO, DIFIFO, DOFIFO, DIDOFIFOWhen they perform any of the following combinations of sourcing strategies: FO, DIFO, DOFO, DIDOFO
FIWhen they perform any of the following combinations of sourcing strategies: FI, DIFI, DOFI, FIFO, DIDOFI, DIFIFO, DOFIFO, DIDOFIFOWhen they perform any of the following combinations of sourcing strategies: FI, FIFO, DIFI, DOFI, DIDOFI, DIFIFO, DOFIFO, DIDOFIFO

In light of the above discussion, because each definition entails certain pros compared with the others, we prefer retaining all of them for empirical purposes. This eventually enables us to make comparisons and reach a better understanding of global sourcing.

4.2 Descriptive Statistics

Table 4 disaggregates the sampled firms into all possible combinations of DO, DI, FO, and FI – in italics – to provide a first observation of the data.

According to the conservative (liberal) definition, no-sourcing firms (NS) [10] represent only 25% (11%) of the overall sample, whereas sourcing firms are the majority.

Table 4:

Sampled firms’ sourcing strategies, conservative versus liberal definitions.

Sourcing strategyConservative definitionLiberal definition
DI6978
DO81
FI11
FO10
DIDO7298
DIFI13
DIFO52
DOFI00
DOFO30
FIFO00
DIDOFI37
DIDOFO819
DIFIFO00
DOFIFO00
DIDOFIFO16
Total number of sourcing firms172215
Average number of sourcing strategies1.621.8
No sourcing firms5613
Total number of firms in the sample228228

If we observe the pure strategies, [11]DI is the most frequent choice, followed by DO, FO, and FI. Notice also that FO and FI are quite marginal in our data, accounting for a negligible number of observations. This result is strongly consistent with the Japanese firms portrayed by Tomiura (2007b), for which the same ranking emerges; on the contrary, Kohler and Smolka (2011, 2012) report that Spanish enterprises are primarily active in DO, followed by FO, DI, and FI, and the same is true for the sample of Italian firms that were analyzed in Federico (2010). If we instead observe the mixed strategies, the most frequent combination is DIDO. Interestingly, DI occurs quite often both alone and together with DO, FO, and FI, whereas the other strategies tend to be chosen only as part of a mixed design.

For the ownership and location decisions that underlie firm sourcing behavior, Table 4 reveals that in choosing between home and foreign, Lombard respondents tend to prefer home, and in choosing between make and buy, they tend to select make, consistent with the theoretical case of Antras and Helpman (2004, 2008).

Interestingly, our sampled firms’ sourcing strategies appear to be complementary rather than substitutes for each other. This becomes evident after observing the average number of modes per firm, which is 1.62 below the conservative definition and 1.8 below the liberal definition. These results are aligned with the previous evidence reported by Kohler and Smolka (2011, 2012) and indicate the benefit of maintaining both mutually inclusive and mutually exclusive proxies for empirical purposes.

For the sake of completeness, Figures 1 and 2 extract mutually inclusive and mutually exclusive sourcing strategies from the data reported in Table 4; this may help the reader focus on a few facts.

Figure 1: Sampled firms’ mutually inclusive sourcing strategies, conservative versus liberal definitions.
Figure 1:

Sampled firms’ mutually inclusive sourcing strategies, conservative versus liberal definitions.

Figure 2: Sampled firms’ mutually exclusive sourcing strategies, conservative versus liberal definitions.
Figure 2:

Sampled firms’ mutually exclusive sourcing strategies, conservative versus liberal definitions.

First, mutually inclusive and mutually exclusive definitions produce only a partially overlapping ranking of the most preferred sourcing strategies, that is, DI-DO-FO-FI in the former case and DO-DI-FO-FI in the latter case. Second, these rankings are robust to the conservative versus liberal perspective.

Taking advantage of our data, this evidence can be further dissected by province, industry, and type of firm. [12] In particular, we ask the following: How do sourcing behaviors differ for firms that are headquartered in the regional capital? Are “true-headquarters firms” more or less likely to engage in a certain sourcing mode? Does any sectoral pattern reflect the relative prevalence of DI, DO, FO, and FI?

Figure 3 answers these questions and displays mutually inclusive sourcing strategies.

Figure 3: Sampled firms’ mutually inclusive sourcing strategies, by province, type, and industry, conservative versus liberal definitions.
Figure 3:

Sampled firms’ mutually inclusive sourcing strategies, by province, type, and industry, conservative versus liberal definitions.

Concerning the province, we distinguish between Milan – the regional capital – and the rest of Lombardy. Our descriptive statistics reveal that firms headquartered in Milan are the most likely to retain strategic high-value functions, such as R&D and other services, within the boundaries of a foreign affiliate. On the contrary, there seems to be no “metropolitan hub-effect”, given that the percentages of DI are very similar throughout the sample and do not display any sizeable differences based on the conservative versus liberal definitions.

For type of firm, we introduce the notion of “true-headquarters” to denote those companies that have less than 50% external participation in their joint capital (Kohler and Smolka 2011, 2012). Identifying true-headquarters firms is important for controlling for firms’ discretion over their input procurement choice. [13] Interestingly, companies that have more than 50% of external participation rely more on internationalization than do true-headquarters firms. Moreover, the former tend to perform strategic high-value functions abroad more often than the latter.

Finally, Figure 3 dissects the Lombard firms’ sourcing behavior according to the Bell and Pavitt (1993) industries. All sectors produce a ranking of the most preferred sourcing strategies that is consistent with the sample average displayed in Figure 1. However, some specific patterns emerge as well. To mention just a few, specialized supplier-dominated firms are those that rely the most on domestic sourcing; scale-intensive firms have the smallest percentage of foreign integration; and, not surprisingly, science-based firms seem quite reluctant to engage in outsourcing, especially that of R&D and other services.

For the sake of completeness, Figure 4 displays mutually exclusive sourcing strategies by province, industry, and type of firms. The results are broadly consistent with those described above for the mutually inclusive case.

Figure 4: Sampled firms’ mutually exclusive sourcing strategies, by province, type, and industry, conservative versus liberal definitions.
Figure 4:

Sampled firms’ mutually exclusive sourcing strategies, by province, type, and industry, conservative versus liberal definitions.

5 Econometric Analysis

In this section, we explore the relationship between sourcing and performance by using econometric techniques.

5.1 Variables and Specification

Following the methodology of Bernard and Jensen (1995, 1999), we define sourcing premia as the average percentage difference of performance between firms engaged in a particular strategy compared with the others. To compute these premia, we regress firm performance on sourcing dummies, controlling for a number of additional variables that may also affect performance.

Our econometric model is set accordingly. For every performance measure, three equations are estimated, designated [1], [2], and [3].

Equation [1] has a very parsimonious specification because performance (performancei) is regressed only on sourcing strategies (sourcing strategyi) for the unrestricted sample of respondents, called Ω_unrestr:

[1]performancei=αsourcingstrategyi+εiforiΩ_unrestr

This basic equation is then completed by firm controls (firmctrli), together with industry (industryctrli) and province (provincectrli) controls, as in eq. [2].

[2]performancei=αsourcingstrategyi+βfirmctrli+γindustryctrli+σprovincectrli+εiforiΩ_unrestr

Equation [3] is the same as eq. [2], with the only difference being that it is estimated in the restricted sample of true-headquarters firms, called Ω_restr, to account for the potential effect of foreign ownership on performance. [14]

[3]performancei=αsourcingstrategyi+βfirmctrli+γindustryctrli+σprovincectrli+εifor  iΩ_restr

A number of variables are considered in eqs [1], [2], and [3] as a proxy for firm performancei. They range from sales to value added and from profit to productivity (TFP) and skill intensity to investigate many potential premia related to sourcing strategies. With regard to productivity, we follow the estimation method of Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) to address the simultaneity and selection bias. [15] In particular, we assume the production function of firm i, at a given point in time to be Cobb-Douglas:

[4]Yi=δ+ωLLi+ωKKi+ωMMi+ωi+εi

where Yi is the logarithm of firm output, measured by value added; Li and Mi are the logarithms of the freely variable inputs labor and intermediate input, approximated by the number of employees and the cost of raw materials, respectively; and Ki denotes the logarithm of the state variable capital, proxied by total assets. All variables in eq. [4] are deflated by the Producer Price Index for the appropriate two-digit NACE industry.

The independent variables can be distinguished into two main groups: the “core” and “control” regressors. Core regressors denote the main variables of interest, namely, sourcing strategyi. A number of dummies are available (DO_con_incl, DI_con_incl, FO_con_incl, FI_con_incl, DO_con_excl, DI_con_excl, FO_con_excl, FI_con_excl, DO_lib_incl, DI_lib_incl, FO_lib_incl, FI_lib_incl, DO_lib_excl, DI_lib_excl, FO_lib_excl, and FI_lib_excl), depending on the conservative versus liberal and mutually inclusive versus mutually exclusive definitions of sourcing strategies. In addition to the core regressors, eqs [2] and [3] consider a number of “controls” to verify the robustness of the sourcing dummies to the inclusion of firm, industry, and province variables. In particular, firm-level controls include firm size, age, group affiliation, and export experience; industry effects are measured through sector dummies following Bell and Pavitt (1993), and a dummy for Milan, the regional capital, captures the province effect.

OLS estimations are retained throughout the empirical analysis, with the only exception being the skill intensity equation, which follows a probit model. Under the OLS estimation, sourcing premia can be directly discerned from the α coefficient, which captures the percentage change in performance due to a given sourcing solution [16]; under the probit estimation, the same is true for marginal effects.

At this stage, it is worth mentioning that survey estimation methods are employed throughout the empirical analysis to control for the potential bias originating from the response rate. Each combination of a single geographical location (out of four) and a single manufacturing activity (out of four) denotes a stratum (16 in total). In the econometric analysis, we use sampling information to obtain consistent and efficient estimates and to draw conclusions about Lombardy as a whole. Specifically, we weight each observation by the inverse of the probability of being sampled using, for every stratum, location- and industry-specific information on the total number of firms in the population and in the sample.

To avoid simultaneity, all dependent variables refer to 2009, whereas the regressors date back to 2007. Unfortunately, the cross-sectional design of our data does not allow us to implement rigorous econometric methods, apart from lagged variables, to account for endogeneity. [17] Therefore, one should not interpret regressions as indicating the exact direction of causality but as a convenient way of summarizing the statistical regularities among variables.

A detailed variables description is available in Table 9, in the Appendix, while Tables 10 and 11 provide some summary statistics and correlations between firm-level regressors.

5.2 Results

In this section, we comment on the main estimation results.

Tables 5 and 6 report the empirical evidence about sourcing premia when the conservative definition is applied to mutually inclusive (Table 5) and mutually exclusive (Table 6) sourcing strategies. According to eqs [1], [2], and [3], for every dependent variable, three specifications are displayed.

Table 5:

Estimation results under the conservative definition of mutually inclusive sourcing strategies.

SalesValue addedProfit
OLS estimatesOLS estimatesOLS estimates
(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)
DO_con_incl–1,893.374–1,337.905–621.088–641.910–435.7369–352.80134.29979.04234.073
(0.353)(0.465)(0.728)(0.414)(0.536)(0.618)(0.841)(0.651)(0.847)
DI_con_incl138.774–463.213–1,243.597597.270332.4621249.422–7.331–60.419–12.801
(0.947)(0.785)(0.447)(0.434)(0.560)(0.658)(0.973)(0.746)(0.944)
FO_con_incl7,383.8927,101.2816,266.5672,463.1722,383.0952,326.433885.081724.517800.481
(0.014)**(0.050)**(0.068)*(0.020)**(0.058)*(0.061)*(0.051)*(0.059)*(0.061)*
FI_con_incl355,855.2323,003275,222.3171,683.9156,607.6153,229.237,328.1333,324.9635,765.16
(0.023)**(0.031)**(0.032)**(0.040)**(0.049)**(0.051)*(0.039)**(0.047)**(0.046)**
Size19.10153.9869.35011.8872.9731.187
(0.074)*(0.003)***(0.000)***(0.095)*(0.004)***(0.054)*
Age153.311146.05653.40651.5215.2795.240
(0.087)*(0.098)*(0.099)*(0.143)(0.297)(0.307)
Export–108.825–622.733–283.343–331.417198.266225.138
(0.963)(0.790)(0.755)(0.716)(0.272)(0.213)
Group6,722.3744,472.6551,644.7491,337.111–412.840–309.043
(0.013)**(0.054)**(0.036)**(0.070)**(0.263)(0.406)
Provinceyesyesyesyesyesyes
Industryyesyesyesyesyesyes
Obs197197191197197191197197191
R20.2450.3700.4590.3220.4640.4820.2460.4080.418
CapitalTFPSkill intensity
OLS estimatesOLS estimatesProbit estimates
(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)
DO_con_incl–957,591.7–832,533.2–765,832.3–0.0220.090–0.079–0.0560.014–0.016
(0.185)(0.169)(0.207)(0.867)(0.573)(0.623)(0.528)(0.884)(0.868)
DI_con_incl931,113.9767,813.6715,3240.1110.1490.144–0.083–0.101–0.097
(0.182)(0.167)(0.187)(0.357)(0.210)(0.228)(0.371)(0.280)(0.302)
FO_con_incl1,618,8671,640,5801,711,9700.1810.2360.2000.007–0.078–0.075
(0.143)(0.159)(0.139)(0.554)(0.400)0.472(0.965)(0.610)(0.626)
FI_con_incl4.79e+073.85e+074.17e+071.4621.1890.3840.6260.6280.250
(0.001)***(0.004)***(0.006)***(0.000)***(0.000)***(0.026)**(0.000)***(0.002)***(0.005)***
Size5,407.0923,295.8650.0010.0020.0010.001
(0.000)***(0.075)*(0.439)(0.217)(0.053)*(0.093)*
Age52,478.8846,685.17–0.004–0.0040.0040.004
(0.044)**(0.069)*(0.274)(0.266)(0.098)*(0.104)
Export–275,810.5–277,517.9–0.017–0.0310.1140.111
(0.717)(0.716)(0.920)(0.854)(0.246)(0.252)
Group1,638,2121,217,429–0.090–0.1330.1430.146
(0.056)*(0.097)*(0.423)(0.275)(0.316)(0.323)
Provinceyesyesyesyesyesyes
Industryyesyesyesyesyesyes
Obs197197191171171162223223214
R20.0760.2400.2970.0560.1130.1200.0240.0810.090
Table 6:

Estimation results under the conservative definition of mutually exclusive sourcing strategies.

SalesValue addedProfit
OLS estimatesOLS estimatesOLS estimates
(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)
DO_con_excl–1,264.622876.096–1,038.42956.398145.745131.91092.11387.42396.525
(0.303)(0.574)(0.482)(0.860)(0.748)(0.765)(0.579)(0.583)(0.544)
DI_con_excl1,997.4672,153.7181,047.4811,278.091,206.7261,080.06297.87260.618317.659
(0.469)(0.351)(0.640)(0.213)(0.143)(0.189)(0.197)(0.196)(0.110)
FO_con_excl5,599.4245,916.385,157.5741,985.9862,052.8651,994.282888.703760.231828.626
(0.064)*(0.108)(0.155)(0.027)**(0.056)*(0.064)*(0.069)*(0.089)*(0.098)*
FI_con_excl359,052.5325,790.9277,470.4173,282.3158,015.3154,635.437,920.9233,760.9136,286.79
(0.024)**(0.031)**(0.033)**(0.040)**(0.049)**(0.051)*(0.039)**(0.047)**(0.046)**
Size19.16753.9189.36211.8582.9781.169
(0.071)*(0.003)***(0.000)***(0.199)(0.004)***(0.550)
Age144.520136.61451.72449.8494.0874.163
(0.099)*(0.096)*(0.133)(0.148)(0.429)(0.425)
Export205.961314.884–161.603–209.976251.273277.249
(0.928)(0.890)(0.855)(0.813)(0.161)(0.124)
Group7,087.6044,767.5521,778.1841,464.361–365.635–254.618
(0.009)***(0.041)**(0.024)**(0.050)**(0.302)(0.475)
ProvinceyesyesyesyesyesYes
IndustryyesyesyesyesyesYes
Obs197197191197197191197197191
R20.2440.3690.4570.3220.4640.4130.2460.4070.317
CapitalTFPSkill intensity
OLS estimatesOLS estimatesProbit estimates
(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)
DO_con_excl1,148,8791,220,4551,094,9700.0830.0660.069–0.156–0.125–0.123
(0.196)(0.101)(0.130)(0.562)(0.690)(0.677)(0.125)(0.236)(0.241)
DI_con_excl73,013.06204,914.7194,544.40.1570.2350.226–0.102–0.108–0.103
(0.874)(0.705)(0.715)(0.283)(0.169)(0.191)(0.355)(0.339)(0.362)
FO_con_excl1,503,6041,661,1701,700,3820.2450.2850.254–0.104–0.151–0.146
(0.181)(0.161)(0.148)(0.419)(0.291)(0.348)(0.525)(0.332)(0.345)
FI_con_excl4.90e+073.96e+074.29e+071.4871.202–0.2830.6170.62220.096
(0.001)***(0.004)***(0.006)***(0.000)***(0.000)***(0.013)**(0.000)***(0.006)***(0.008)*
Size5,411.0393,291.7440.0010.0010.0010.001
(0.001)***(0.379)(0.457)(0.258)(0.452)(0.697)
Age53,216.6147,586.09–0.004–0.0040.0030.003
(0.038)**(0.059)*(0.291)(0.283)(0.136)(0.135)
Export–283,304.8–288,527.4–0.007–0.0190.1130.111
(0.706)(0.703)(0.968)(0.906)(0.246)(0.252)
Group1,753,1311,314,465–0.056–0.0970.1310.134
(0.048)**(0.083)*(0.633)(0.445)(0.361)(0.367)
ProvinceYesyesyesyesyesyes
IndustryYesyesyesyesyesyes
Obs197197191171171162223223214
R20.0750.2420.2980.0570.1180.1210.0280.0930.098

A first look at Tables 5 and 6 suggests some interesting facts.

With regard to core variables, FI_con_incl is found to be statistically significant, with a positive sign, in every specification. This means that FDI makers enjoy superior performance in terms of sales, value added, profit, capital, TFP, and skill intensity. FO_con_incl is found to be positive and statistically significant as well, but its explanatory power is limited to the sales, value added, and profit equations. These results are robust to firm, industry, and province controls, and they hold for both the unrestricted and restricted samples of true-headquarters firms. Our evidence thus unveils that foreign sourcing is key to Lombardy’s performance, regardless of whether it is pursued intra- or extra-firm. On the contrary, we find no effect for domestic sourcing because DO_con_incl and DI_con_incl are not significant. Consistent with Kohler and Smolka (2011, 2012) and Federico (2010), the magnitude of the FI effect is the largest, which means not only that FI discloses precious premia for Lombard enterprises but also that these sourcing premia are the highest possible.

Concerning control variables, size, age, and group affiliation seem to play a role in shaping firm performance. Indeed, they are positive drivers of many dependent variables such as sales, value added, profit, capital, and skill intensity, thus confirming the previous evidence on Italian enterprises reported by Barba Navaretti et al. (2008), Bugamelli, Cipollone, and Infante (2000), Conti, Lo Turco, and Maggioni (2010), and Bugamelli and Infante (2003). On the contrary, we find no significant effect of international experience on economic performance, which is quite surprising in light of the empirical literature reviewed in Section 2. [18]

Interestingly, moving from the mutually inclusive to the mutually exclusive definition does not alter the abovementioned results that can be considered typical of the conservative case.

To complete the picture, Tables 7 and 8 display our estimation results when the liberal definition is applied to mutually inclusive (Table 7) and mutually exclusive (Table 8) sourcing strategies.

Table 7:

Estimation results under the liberal definition of mutually inclusive sourcing strategies.

SalesValue addedProfit
OLS estimatesOLS estimatesOLS estimates
(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)
DO_lib_incl–17.677–1,735.942,848.9545,143.13,881.3122,479.7–815.393–448.092–464.665
(0.998)(0.736)(0.539)(0.229)(0.165)(0.308)(0.451)(0.563)(0.528)
DI_lib_incl2,274.25513,216.527,903.1521,814.9524,782.6934,102.4461,496.4122,021.6812,082.65
(0.778)(0.363)(0.553)(0.409)(0.236)(0.321)(0.191)(0.216)(0.232)
FO_lib_incl29,753.1235,047.2923,221.034,517.85311,053.1411,763.381,901.5452,674.6123,380.242
(0.182)(0.102)(0.139)(0.687)(0.341)(0.242)(0.420)(0.242)(0.117)
FI_lib_incl58,396.2421,758.939,479.9155,951.7331,110.340,068.6710,024.165,502.7566,197.986
(0.065)*(0.068)*(0.093)*(0.075)*(0.96)*(0.158)(0.083)*(0.084)*(0.086)*
Size12.67160.6726.97216.2612.9242.784
(0.265)(0.058)*(0.018)**(0.314)(0.001)***(0.482)
Age114.898164.699–5.527–1.2111.6840.654
(0.718)(0.475)(0.970)(0.992)(0.961)(0.983)
Export4,653.1252,183.4531,995.4521,716.49–94.242–96.230
(0.410)(0.644)(0.473)(0.516)(0.879)(0.875)
Group58,146.3442,811.5917,705.2815,759.56472.8301,176.851
(0.000)***(0.003)***(0.009)***(0.010)***(0.832)(0.620)
Provinceyesyesyesyesyesyes
Industryyesyesyesyesyesyes
Obs202202196199199193202202196
R20.0960.3390.4980.1950.3750.3800.1270.3280.228
CapitalTFPSkill intensity
OLS estimatesOLS estimatesProbit estimates
(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)
DO_lib_incl–752,785.4723,438.1128,133.4–0.075–0.142–0.130–0.0100.009
(0.699)(0.595)(0.918)(0.571)(0.323)(0.371)(0.910)(0.927)
DI_lib_incl89,4475.91,733,5631,766,628–0.0340.1450.172–0.140–0.121
(0.799)(0.648)(0.631)(0.874)(0.572)(0.518)(0.278)(0.383)
FO_lib_incl6,263,2497,365,5363,994,851–0.033–0.004–0.008–0.039–0.106
(0.262)(0.123)(0.107)(0.395)(0.987)(0.971)(0.796)(0.454)
FI_lib_incl1.52e+075,997,6211.04e+070.5790.5770.4230.5850.565
(0.063)*(0.051)*(0.027)**(0.010)***(0.000)***(0.001)***(0.000)***(0.001)***
Size3,633.1323,011.6440.0010.0020.0010.001
(0.012)**(0.529)(0.502)(0.244)(0.486)(0.563)
Age1,18,680.976,150.82–0.004–0.0040.0030.003
(0.035)**(0.040)**(0.280)(0.288)(0.165)(0.159)
Export56,388.14667,491.8–0.0080.0300.1290.125
(0.965)(0.574)(0.960)(0.851)(0.180)(0.189)
Group1.26e+071.05e+07–0.108–0.1740.1150.119
(0.004)***(0.003)***(0.357)(0.201)(0.419)(0.417)
Provinceyesyesyesyesyesyes
Industryyesyesyesyesyesyes
Obs202202196173173164225225216
R20.1040.3890.3010.0360.1140.0890.0320.920.084
Table 8:

Estimation results under the liberal definition of mutually exclusive sourcing strategies.

SalesValue addedProfit
OLS estimatesOLS estimatesOLS estimates
(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)
DO_lib_excl4,419.08916,888.6612,945.986,105.6497,377.5546,168.9111,273.9832,053.9672,111.91
(0.624)(0.321)(0.398)(0.037)**(0.172)(0.253)(0.338)(0.304)(0.308)
DI_lib_excl3,687.4621,019.5911,073.653,288.3156,938.3055,335.041,419.8722,599.5172,728.337
(0.652)(0.201)(0.426)(0.001)***(0.099)*(0.183)(0.182)(0.152)(0.133)
FO_lib_excl10,080.7231,469.5416,255.252,728.1278,694.4637,423.8821,287.4822,379.1892,777.888
(0.467)(0.188)(0.243)(0.017)**(0.071)*(0.083)*(0.236)(0.194)(0.146)
FI_lib_excl72,617.7254,571.5360,038.5761,496.3643,208.150,47911,843.068,654.0989,587.295
(0.040)**(0.090)*(0.096)*(0.075)*(0.072)*(0.073)*(0.057)*(0.064)*(0.056)*
Size11.72561.5006.54216.6322.8892.886
(0.313)(0.064)*(0.027)**(0.321)(0.001)***(0.485)
Age88.066152.198–10.719–2.847–2.743–1.600
(0.795)(0.527)(0.946)(0.982)(0.940)(9.959)
Export5,455.1242,851.7752,118.2471,764.778–19.647–11.017
(0.348)(0.538)(0.450)(0.483)(0.975)(0.985)
Group58,971.7641,549.2816,997.7314,608.44473.1681,051.381
(0.001)***(0.003)***(0.009)***(0.015)**(0.832)(0.657)
Provinceyesyesyesyesyesyes
Industryyesyesyesyesyesyes
Obs202202196199199193202202196
R20.0760.3130.4850.1870.3580.3640.1210.3190.179
CapitalTFPSkill intensity
OLS estimatesOLS estimatesProbit estimates
(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)(1)(2)(3)
DO_lib_excl663,050.72,539,3302,133,009–0.087–0.013–0.038–0.114–0.070–0.070
(0.862)(0.549)(0.604)(0.698)(0.961)(0.891)(0.359)(0.610)(0.612)
DI_lib_excl68,445.151,937,6131,880,158–0.0250.1190.079–0.082–0.054–0.056
(0.985)(0.640)(0.633)(0.910)(0.664)(0.779)(0.523)(0.694)(0.689)
FO_lib_excl4,543,0407,584,0971,804,686–0.0970.013–0.030–0.110–0.135–0.133
(0.512)(0.277)(0.649)(0.762)(0.970)(0.930)(0.530)(0.435)(0.435)
FI_lib_excl1.80e+071.16e+071.38e+070.5240.6080.4350.5570.5330.468
(0.040)**(0.085)*(0.041)**(0.091)*(0.031)**(0.135)(0.001)***(0.009)***(0.061)*
Size3,440.6753,189.7090.0010.0020.0010.001
(0.017)**(0.521)(0.644)(0.215)(0.580)(0.522)
Age1,13,832.174,887.65–0.004–0.0040.0030.003
(0.038)**(0.046)**(0.276)(0.264)(0.169)(0.158)
Export131,739.3856,372.40.0130.0330.1260.123
(0.924)(0.496)(0.936)(0.835)(0.190)(0.199)
Group1.29e+071.01e+07–0.114–0.1860.1340.136
(0.006)***(0.004)***(0.338)(0.154)(0.344)(0.355)
ProvinceYesyesyesyesyesyes
IndustryYesyesyesyesyesyes
Obs202202196173173164225225216
R20.0940.3730.2890.0340.1120.1230.0280.0780.070

Compared with the conservative case, the liberal definition makes a more restrictive argument. In terms of core regressors, sourcing premia seem to accrue only to FDI makers because FI_lib_incl is positive and statistically significant in every column of Tables 7 and 8, whereas FO_lib_incl is not significant, regardless of the parsimonious versus rich specification and the unrestricted versus restricted sample. With regard to control regressors, we find significant effects only of size on sales, value added, and capital and a significant effect of age on capital, but these effects vanish if we restrict attention to true-headquarters firms. On the contrary, group affiliation is found to be positive and statistically significant in the sales, value added, and capital equations.

These results are robust to the mutually inclusive versus mutually exclusive definitions; therefore, we retain them as typical of the liberal – as opposed to conservative – case.

As a further robustness check, one might run the same estimation exercise as in Tables 58 on the restricted sample of sourcing enterprises. The underlying idea is to restrict attention to firms that are actually making sourcing decisions, according to both the conservative and liberal views, and dispensing with those that do not perform the related tasks. Although we believe this is a proper way of estimating sourcing premia, it comes at the expense of a lower number of observations. Because the (unreported) results are fully consistent with those discussed above, we stick to Tables 58. [19]

6 Conclusion

In this paper, we estimate sourcing premia using Italian regional data.

Drawing on original information about Lombard enterprises, we find certain performance differences among firms that make different sourcing decisions. Survey estimation methods reveal foreign rather than domestic sourcing and in- rather than outsourcing entail significant sales, value added, capital, productivity, profit, and skill-intensity premia. This result is robust to different specifications, samples, performance measures, and definitions of sourcing strategies.

In the Introduction, we claimed that our approach entails a few novelties in terms of the research question, data and methodology compared with previous studies on related topics.

To see the benefits of asking a relatively new research question, note that our findings are broadly consistent with previous results on global sourcing under contractual incompleteness and internationalization and performance. Indeed, we document the existence of robust correlations among integration, foreign exposure, and performance. Nonetheless, viewing ownership and location decisions within a unitary framework, we are able to show that firm performance is not only a matter of integration (as postulated by the first strand) or internationalization (as implied by the second one) but is the joint effect of in- and foreign sourcing. This is something that the previous studies could not assert because of data limitations, whereas our survey design is sufficiently broad to embrace all factors in a coherent setting in which the previous results still hold, but new findings stand out as well.

To see the benefits of using Italian regional data, our results could be confronted with previous evidence about Lombard enterprises on related issues. Similar to Cusmano, Mancusi, and Morrison (2009, 2010), we observe that outsourcing is a very common phenomenon but that international outsourcing involves only a handful of players. However, by adding ownership to firms’ locational choice, we are able to revisit the positive correlation among international outsourcing, skill intensity, and innovation put forth by Cusmano, Mancusi, and Morrison (2009, 2010) and demonstrate that internationalization plus vertical integration – rather than outsourcing – is key to the superior performance of Lombard firms in terms of sales, value added, profit, capital, TFP and skill intensity. This was not apparent from previous studies because they could not control for in- versus outsourcing below the FO strategy.

Finally, to evaluate our methodological contribution, one should compare the results implied by the four definitions of sourcing strategies to see whether it was worth introducing our new taxonomy of organizational modes. Our econometric analysis delivers results that hold: (a) across all definitions, (b) only for the conservative case, and (c) only for the liberal case. [20] Therefore, moving from the mutually inclusive to the mutually exclusive definition makes no sizeable difference, whereas moving from the conservative to the liberal definition does. Put another way, what matters is not that firms are assigned one or more sourcing modes but rather the number of tasks for which the sourcing modes are computed. This is something that the previous studies could not address because they exclusively followed the conservative view. On the contrary, after disaggregating the firm production processes by task, we have the opportunity to add the liberal perspective and gain certain insights into this issue.

Although we believe that these are quite interesting findings, we are aware of some data limitations that plague the present analysis and constrain its scope.

First, although our sample proves to be representative of the entire population of Lombard enterprises, it is small in size. This might be a problem when selecting the set of regressors for econometric purposes because we cannot include too many variables. Relying on a larger database would allow us, for instance, to build sourcing dummies for every task instead of grouping input manufacturing, R&D, and other services under the same liberal definition. Based on this information, one could compare sourcing premia not only between different organizational modes but also within the same mode and thus observe the different tasks within the firm production process.

In addition to size, another major concern is the cross-sectional nature of the data. Although we collect performance measures for a five-year period, the sourcing strategies and international experience refer only to 2007. This prevents us from performing a proper causality test that the panel data would instead allow for. Put another way, although the present study finds robust correlations between sourcing and performance, it cannot offer insight into the direction of the causality, i.e., from the former to the latter, in the spirit of the learning-by-internationalization argument, or vice versa, according to the self-selection mechanism. Addressing causality correctly is important not only for academic purposes but also to derive policy implications. For instance, if the evidence supports the self-selection hypothesis, more successful enterprises self-select into foreign integration. In this case, the policy maker could attempt to promote local growth to foster internationalization. In fact, by helping firms to reach a certain threshold in terms of, e.g., sales, profit, value added, and productivity, one would also make them sufficiently strong to afford the additional cost of operating abroad. On the contrary, if the evidence supports the learning-by-internationalization hypothesis, firms become more successful as a result of their foreign exposure. In this case, the policy maker could instead promote internationalization to enhance local growth because international experience per se would act as a springboard for economic performance. In short, our data cannot offer conclusive evidence in this regard. In this sense, our study should be considered a first step toward the investigation of sourcing premia.

Hopefully, our preliminary evidence will encourage further research on the same topic. From an empirical point of view, our suggestion is to build on the drawbacks identified above and construct a larger dataset with panel information. This would help assess the direction of causality correctly and provide more rigorous econometric estimates. From a theoretical point of view, our suggestion is instead to relax the standard assumptions behind the taxonomy of Antras and Helpman (2004, 2008) and derive testable predictions for what we designated the liberal case. This would result in a more realistic treatment of firm boundaries, encompassing the multiple tasks performed in the complex production processes of the real world.

We believe that both extensions to the analysis are worth making to provide a deeper investigation of global sourcing and a better understanding of its relationship with firm performance in a context of heterogeneity.

Acknowledgements

Data have been gathered with the help of Maria Luisa Mancusi, to whom we are indebted. We thank the Editor, two anonymous Referees, Gregory Corcos, Charles Dhanaraj, Piergiovanna Natale, Gianmarco Ottaviano and participants in seminars at Università di Milano-Bicocca and Università Bocconi for helpful comments and insightful discussions. Valeria Gattai gratefully acknowledges financial support from Università di Milano-Bicocca and MIUR (Italian Ministry of Education, University and Research). All remaining errors are ours.

Appendix

This Appendix provides the variables description (Table 9) together with some summary statistics (Table 10) and correlations (Table 11) between firm-level regressors.

Table 9:

Variables description.

VariableDescription
SalesFirm’s sales (thousands of units).
Value addedFirm’s value added (thousands of units).
ProfitFirm’s profit (thousands of units).
CapitalFirm’s tangible fixed assets.
TFPNatural logarithm of firm’s total factor productivity (Levinsohn-Petrin estimate).
Skill intensityDummy variable, 1 if the firm’s share of graduates is larger than 10%, 0 otherwise.
SizeFirm’s number of employees.
AgeFirm’s age, defined as the difference between 2009 and the year of firm’s establishment.
ExportDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in export operations, 0 otherwise.
GroupDummy variable, 1 if the firm belongs to a group, 0 otherwise.
DO_con_inclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in DO, according to the conservative definition of mutually inclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
DI_con_inclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in DI, according to the conservative definition of mutually inclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
FO_con_inclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in FO, according to the conservative definition of mutually inclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
FI_con_inclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in FI, according to the conservative definition of mutually inclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
DO_con_exclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in DO, according to the conservative definition of mutually exclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
DI_con_exclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in DI, according to the conservative definition of mutually exclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
FO_con_exclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in FO, according to the conservative definition of mutually exclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
FI_con_exclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in FI, according to the conservative definition of mutually exclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
DO_lib_inclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in DO, according to the liberal definition of mutually inclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
DI_lib_inclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in DI, according to the liberal definition of mutually inclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
FO_lib_inclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in FO, according to the liberal definition of mutually inclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
FI_lib_inclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in FI, according to the liberal definition of mutually inclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
DO_lib_exclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in DO, according to the liberal definition of mutually exclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
DI_lib_exclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in DI, according to the liberal definition of mutually exclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
FO_lib_exclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in FO, according to the liberal definition of mutually exclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
FI_lib_exclDummy variable, 1 if the firm engages in FI, according to the liberal definition of mutually exclusive sourcing strategies, 0 otherwise.
Table 10:

Summary statistics of firm-level regressors.

VariableObsMeanStd. dev.minmax
DO_con_incl2280.4220.49501
DI_con_incl2280.7040.45801
FO_con_incl2280.0800.27201
FI_con_incl2280.0270.16101
DO_con_excl2280.3540.47901
DI_con_excl2280.2960.45801
FO_con_excl2280.0760.26601
FI_con_excl2280.0270.16201
DO_lib_incl2280.5750.49501
DI_lib_incl2280.9340.24801
FO_lib_incl2280.1180.32401
FI_lib_incl2280.0750.26301
DO_lib_excl2280.4340.49701
DI_lib_excl2280.3420.47501
FO_lib_excl2280.0920.29001
FI_lib_excl2280.0750.26301
Size228171.276920.667112000
Age22839.83326.0692159
Export2280.8030.80301
Group2280.2320.42301
Table 11:

Correlations between firm-level regressors.

DO_con_inclDI_con_inclFO_con_inclFI_con_inclDO_con_exclDI_con_exclFO_con_exclFI_con_exclDO_lib_inclDI_lib_inclFO_lib_inclFI_lib_inclDO_lib_exclDI_lib_exclFO_lib_exclFI_lib_exclsizeAgeexportgroup
DO_con_incl1.00
DI_con_incl0.3611.00
FO_con_incl0.1460.0511.00
FI_con_incl0.0830.0470.0531.00
DO_con_excl0.8680.342–0.220–0.1231.00
DI_con_excl–0.5540.425–0.192–0.108–0.4801.00
FO_con_excl0.1310.0410.970–0.048–0.213–0.1861.00
FI_con_excl0.0830.0490.0531.00–0.123–0.108–0.0481.00
DO_lib_incl0.7440.3380.1910.0880.650–0.4220.1840.0901.00
DI_lib_incl0.2290.4110.079–0.0670.1990.1740.077–0.0660.2731.00
FO_lib_incl0.1710.1200.8530.109–0.136–0.1940.8270.1210.2610.0971.00
FI_lib_incl0.0090.0170.1100.619–0.114–0.1270.0650.6430.1090.0080.2061.00
DO_lib_excl0.5840.241–0.261–0.1460.735–0.283–0.257–0.1490.7540.197–0.321–0.2491.00
DI_lib_excl–0.623–0.120–0.215–0.120–0.5430.534–0.211–0.122–0.838.191–0.264–0.205–0.6321.00
FO_lib_excl0.1940.0740.794–0.053–0.125–0.1630.820–0.0510.2130.0850.869–0.090–0.279–0.2301.00
FI_lib_excl0.0090.0170.1100.619–0.114–0.1270.0650.6430.1090.0080.2061.00–0.249–0.205–0.0901.00
size–0.062–0.0470.0110.086–0.0810.007–0.0300.086–0.0920.0400.0080.256–0.098–0.002–0.0320.2561.00
age–0.0700.1310.016–0.029–0.1360.1760.041–0.029–0.0930.0760.0500.008–0.1490.1220.1110.0080.2351.00
export0.0720.0400.1020.0820.006–0.0570.0980.0810.0410.1350.0790.057–0.0100.0090.0820.0570.0750.2381.00
group0.0340.039–0.0480.2330.027–0.062–0.0810.2330.012–0.063–0.0090.2000.000–0.069–0.1040.2000.2380.0180.0901.00

References

Amiti, Mary, and Shang J. Wei. 2006. “Service Offshoring and Productivity: Evidence from the United States”, Working Papers No. 11926, National Bureau of Economic Research.10.3386/w11926Search in Google Scholar

Antras, Pol. 2003. “Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (4):1375–418.10.3386/w9740Search in Google Scholar

Antras, Pol, and Elhanan Helpman. 2004. “Global Sourcing.” Journal of Political Economy 112 (3):552–80.10.3386/w10082Search in Google Scholar

Antras, Pol, and Elhanan Helpman. 2008. “Contractual Frictions and Global Sourcing.” In The Organization of Firms in a Global Economy, edited by E. Helpman, D. Marin, and T. Verdier, 9–54. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Antras, Pol, and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg. 2009. “Organizations and Trade.” Annual Review of Economics 1 (1):43–64.10.3386/w14262Search in Google Scholar

Antras, Pol. 2014. “Grossman–Hart (1986) Goes Global: Incomplete Contracts, Property Rights, and the International Organization of Production.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization doi:10.1093/jleo/ews023. in press.Search in Google Scholar

ASR. 2013. Annuario Statistico Regionale Lombardia. Milan: Arti Grafiche Colombo.Search in Google Scholar

Barba Navaretti, Giorgio, Roberto Basile, Luigi Benfratello, Davide Castellani, Silvia Cerisola, and Angelica Salvi. 2008. “Le Imprese E Il Mercato Internazionale: Quali Prospettive per Il Mezzogiorno Italiano?” In Luca D’agliano Policy Report. Milan: Centro Studi Luca D’Agliano.Search in Google Scholar

Barba Navaretti, Giorgio, Matteo Bugamelli, Fabiano Schivardi, Carlo Altomonte, Daniel Horgos, and Daniela Maggioni. 2011. “The Global Operations of European Firms.” In Second EFIFE Policy Report, Bruegel, No. 12.Search in Google Scholar

Basile, Roberto. 2001. “Export Behaviour of Italian Manufacturing Firms Over the Nineties: The Role of Innovation.” Research Policy 30 (8):1185–201.10.1016/S0048-7333(00)00141-4Search in Google Scholar

Basile, Roberto, Anna Giunta, and Jeffrey B. Nugent. 2003. “Foreign Expansion by Italian Manufacturing Firms in the Nineties: an Ordered Probit Analysis.” Review of Industrial Organization 23 (1):1–24.10.1023/B:REIO.0000005561.07176.30Search in Google Scholar

Bell, Martin, and Keith Pavitt. 1993. “Accumulating Technological Capability in Developing Countries.” World Bank Economic Review 6 (1):257–81.10.1093/wber/6.suppl_1.257Search in Google Scholar

Benfratello, Luigi, and Tiziano Razzolini. 2009. “Firms’ Productivity and Internationalisation Choices: Evidence from a Large Sample of Italian Firms.” In Multinationals and Local Competitiveness, edited by L. Piscitello and G. Santangelo, Milano: Franco Angeli.10.2139/ssrn.1313707Search in Google Scholar

Bernard, Andrew B., and Bradford J. Jensen. 1995. “Exporters, Jobs and Wages in US Manufacturing: 1976–1987.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Microeconomics 1:67–119.10.2307/2534772Search in Google Scholar

Bernard, Andrew B., and Bradford J. Jensen. 1999. “Exceptional Exporter Performance: Cause, Effect, or Both?” Journal of International Economics 47 (1):1–25.10.3386/w6272Search in Google Scholar

Bernard, Andrew B., Bradford J. Jensen, Stephen J. Redding, and Peter K. Schott. 2010. “Intrafirm Trade and Product Contractibility.” American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings) 100 (2):444–8.10.1257/aer.100.2.444Search in Google Scholar

Bratti, Massimiliano, and Giulia Felice. 2012. “Are Exporters More Likely to Introduce Product Innovation?” The World Economy 35 (11):1559–98.10.1111/j.1467-9701.2012.01453.xSearch in Google Scholar

Bugamelli, Matteo, Piero Cipollone, and Luigi Infante. 2000. “L’internazionalizzazione Delle Imprese Italiane Negli Anni Novanta.” Rivista Italiana Degli Economisti 3 (1):349–86.Search in Google Scholar

Bugamelli, Matteo, and Luigi Infante. 2003. “Sunk Costs to Exports”, Bank of Italy Research Papers No. 469, Bank of Italy.Search in Google Scholar

Casaburi, Lorenzo, Valeria Gattai, and Gaetano A. Minerva. 2007. “Firms’ International Status and Heterogeneity in Performance: Evidence From Italy.” Rivista Di Politica Economica (Special issue May–June):151–87.10.1057/9780230274334_8Search in Google Scholar

Castellani, Davide. 2007. “L’internazionalizzazione Della Produzione in Italia: Caratteristiche Delle Imprese Ed Effetti Sul Sistema Economico.” L’industria 28 (3):467–93.Search in Google Scholar

Castellani, Davide, and Antonello Zanfei. 2007. “Internationalisation, Innovation and Productivity: How Do Firms Differ in Italy?” The World Economy 30 (1):156–76.10.1111/j.1467-9701.2007.00875.xSearch in Google Scholar

Castellani, Davide, and Giorgia Giovannetti. 2010. “Productivity and the International Firm: Dissecting Heterogeneity.” Journal of Economic Policy Reform 13 (1):25–42.10.1080/17487870903546226Search in Google Scholar

Castellani, Davide, Francesco Serti, and Chiara Tomasi. 2010. “Firms in International Trade: Importers and Exporters Heterogeneity in the Italian Manufacturing Industry.” The World Economy 33 (3):424–57.10.1111/j.1467-9701.2010.01262.xSearch in Google Scholar

Conti, Giuliano, Alessia Lo Turco, and Daniela Maggioni. 2010. “Exporters in Services: New Evidence From Italian Firms.” Applied Economic Quarterly 56 (1):73–98.10.3790/aeq.56.1.73Search in Google Scholar

Corcos, Gregory, Delphine M. Irac, Giordano Mion, and Thierry Verdier. 2013. “The Determinants of Intrafirm Trade: Evidence From French Firms.” Review of Economics and Statistics 95 (3):825–38.10.1162/REST_a_00293Search in Google Scholar

Corò, Giancarlo, and Roberto Grandinetti. 1999. “Strategie Di Delocalizzazione E Processi Evolutivi Nei Distretti Industriali Italiani.” L’industria 4 (4):897–924.Search in Google Scholar

Crinò, Rosario, and Paolo Epifani. 2012. “Productivity, Quality and Export Behaviour.” The Economic Journal 122 (565):1206–43.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2012.02529.xSearch in Google Scholar

Cusmano, Lucia, and Franco Malerba. 2005. “Le Sfide Strategiche per L’innovazione in Lombardia.” In Società, Governo E Sviluppo Del Sistema Lombardo: Dieci Anni Di Esperienze, edited by Irer, 151–4. Milan: Guerini e Associati. IRER (Istituto Regionale di Ricerca).Search in Google Scholar

Cusmano, Lucia, Maria L. Mancusi, and Andrea Morrison. 2009. “Innovation and the Geographical Organisational Dimension of Outsourcing: Evidence From Italian Firm-Level Data.” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 20 (3):183–95.10.1016/j.strueco.2009.02.001Search in Google Scholar

Cusmano, Lucia, Maria L. Mancusi, and Andrea Morrison. 2010. “Globalization of Production and Innovation: How Outsourcing Is Reshaping an Advanced Manufacturing Area.” Regional Studies 44 (3):235–52.10.1080/00343400802360451Search in Google Scholar

Defever, Fabrice, and Farid Toubal. 2013. “Productivity, Relationship-Specific Inputs and the Sourcing Modes of Multinationals.” Journal of Economic Behaviour & Organization 94 (C):245–357.10.1016/j.jebo.2012.11.006Search in Google Scholar

Federico, Stefano. 2010. “Outsourcing Versus Integration at Home or Abroad and Firm Heterogeneity.” Empirica 37 (1):47–63.10.1007/s10663-009-9118-3Search in Google Scholar

Federico, Stefano. 2012. “Headquarter Intensity and the Choice Between Outsourcing Versus Integration at Home or Abroad.” Industrial and Corporate Change 21 (6):1337–58.10.1093/icc/dts006Search in Google Scholar

Ferragina, Anna M., and Beniamino Quintieri. 2001. “Caratteristiche Delle Imprese Esportatrici Italiane.” In Le Imprese Esportatrici Italiane: Caratteristiche, Performance E Internazionalizzazione, edited by B. Quintieri, Bologna: Il Mulino.Search in Google Scholar

Garofoli, Gioacchino. 1983. “Industrializzazione Diffusa in Lombardia.” Milan: Franco Angeli.Search in Google Scholar

Garofoli, Gioacchino. 2002. “Local Development in Europe: Theoretical Models and International Comparisons.” European Urban and Regional Studies 9 (3):225–39.10.1177/096977640200900303Search in Google Scholar

Gattai, Valeria. 2006. “From the Theory of the Firm to FDI and Internalisation: a Survey.” Il GiornaledegliEconomisti e Annali di Economia 65 (2):225–62.10.2139/ssrn.702763Search in Google Scholar

Gattai, Valeria. 2015. “Internationalisation and performance: What we learn from Italy.” Journal of Industrial and Business Economics 42 (4):475–509.10.1007/s40812-015-0019-0Search in Google Scholar

Giovannetti, Giorgia, Giorgio Ricciuti, and Margherita Vilucchi. 2009. “Size, Innovation and Internationalization: A Survival Analysis of Italian Firms.” Applied Economics 1 (1):1–10.10.1080/00036840802600566Search in Google Scholar

Greenaway, Davide, and Richard A. Kneller. 2007. “Firm Heterogeneity, Exporting and Foreign Direct Investment: A Survey.” Economic Journal 117 (February):F134–F161.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02018.xSearch in Google Scholar

Grossman, Sanford J., and Oliver D. Hart. 1986. “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration.” Journal of Political Economy 94 (4):691–719.10.1086/261404Search in Google Scholar

Grossman, Sanford J., and Elhanan Helpman. 2002. “Integration Versus Outsourcing in Industry Equilibrium.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (1):85–120.10.1162/003355302753399454Search in Google Scholar

Grossman, Sanford J., and Elhanan Helpman. 2003. “Outsourcing Vs FDI in Industry Equilibrium.” Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (1):317–27.10.1162/154247603322390955Search in Google Scholar

Grossman, Sanford J., and Elhanan Helpman. 2005. “Outsourcing in a Global Economy.” Review of Economic Studies 72 (1):135–59.10.3386/w8728Search in Google Scholar

Grout, Paul A. 1984. “Investment and Wages in the Absence of Binding Contracts: A Nash Bargaining Approach.” Econometrica 52 (2):449–60.10.2307/1911498Search in Google Scholar

Hart, Oliver D., and John Moore. 1990. “Property Rights & the Nature of the Firms.” Journal of Political Economy 98 (6):1119–58.10.1086/261729Search in Google Scholar

Hayakawa, Kazunobu, Fukunari Kimura, and Tomohiro Machikita. 2012. “Globalization and Productivity: A Survey of Firm-Level Analysis.” Journal of Economic Surveys 26 (2):332–50.10.1111/j.1467-6419.2010.00653.xSearch in Google Scholar

ISGEP. 2008. “Understanding Cross-Country Differences in Exporter Premia: Comparable Evidence Fro 14 Countries.” Review of World Economics 144 (4):596–635.10.1007/s10290-008-0163-ySearch in Google Scholar

ISTAT. 2001. Ottavo Censimento Generale Dell’industria E Dei Servizi. Rome: ISTAT (Italian National Institute of Statistics), Rome.Search in Google Scholar

Ito, Banri, Eiichi Tomiura, and Ryuhei Wakasugi. 2011. “Offshore Outsourcing and Productivity: Evidence From Japanese Firm-Level Data Disaggregated by Task.” Review of International Economics 19 (3):555–67.10.1111/j.1467-9396.2011.00965.xSearch in Google Scholar

Kohler, Wilhelm K., and Marcel Smolka. 2011. “Sourcing Premia with Incomplete Contracts: Theory and Evidence.” The B.E. Journal of Economics Analysis and Policy 11 (1):1–39.10.2202/1935-1682.2498Search in Google Scholar

Kohler, Wilhelm K., and Marcel Smolka. 2012. “Global Sourcing Decisions and Firm Productivity: Evidence From Spain.” In Quantitative Analysis of Newly Evolving Patterns of International Trade: Fragmentation; Offshoring of Activities; and Vertical Intra-Industry Trade, edited by R. M. Stern, 139–90. Singapore: World Scientific Studies in International Economics 18, World Scientific Publishing.10.1142/9789814383486_0004Search in Google Scholar

Levinsohn, James, and Amin Petrin. 2003. “Estimating Production Functions Using Inputs to Control for Unobservables.” Review of Economic Studies 70 (2):317–42.10.3386/w7819Search in Google Scholar

Lopez, Ricardo A. 2005. “Trade and Growth: Reconciling the Macroeconomic and Microeconomic Evidence.” Journal of Economic Surveys 19 (4):623–48.10.1111/j.0950-0804.2005.00264.xSearch in Google Scholar

Mayer, Thierry, and Gianmarco I. P. Ottaviano. 2007. The happy few: new facts on the internationalisation of European firms, Bruegel-CEPR EFIM2007 Report, Bruegel Blueprint Series.Search in Google Scholar

McLaren, John. 2000. “Globalisation and Vertical Structure.” American Economic Review 90 (5):1239–54.10.1257/aer.90.5.1239Search in Google Scholar

Melitz, Marc J. 2003. “The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity.” Econometrica 71 (6):1661–94.10.3386/w8881Search in Google Scholar

Nunn, Nathan, and Daniel Trefler. 2008. “The Boundaries of the Multinational Firm: An Empirical Analysis.” In The Organization of Firms in a Global Economy, edited by E. Helpman, D. Marin, and T. Verdier, 55–83. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.10.4159/9780674038547-002Search in Google Scholar

Olley, Stephen G., and Ariel Pakes. 1996. “The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equipment Industry.” Econometrica 64 (6):1263–97.10.3386/w3977Search in Google Scholar

Ottaviano, Gianmarco I. P., and Alessandro Turrini. 2007. “Distance and FDI When Contracts Are Incomplete.” Journal of the European Economic Association 5 (4):796–822.10.2139/ssrn.347881Search in Google Scholar

Petrin, Amil, Brian P. Poi, and James Levinsohn. 2004. “Production Function Estimation in Stata Using Inputs to Control for Unobservables.” The Stata Journal 4 (2):113–23.10.1177/1536867X0400400202Search in Google Scholar

Razzolini, Tiziano, and Davide Vannoni. 2011. “Export Premia and Sub-Contracting Discount Passive Strategies and Performance in Domestic and Foreign Markets.” The World Economy 34 (6):984–1013.10.1111/j.1467-9701.2011.01329.xSearch in Google Scholar

Serti, Francesco, and Chiara Tomasi. 2008a. “Self-Selection and Post-Entry Effects of Exports: Evidence From Italian Manufacturing Firms.” Review of World Economics 144 (4):660–94.10.1007/s10290-008-0165-9Search in Google Scholar

Serti, Francesco, and Chiara Tomasi. 2008b. “Firm Heterogeneity: Do Destinations of Exports and Origins of Imports Matter ?” In Multinationals and Local Competitiveness, edited by L. Piscitello and G. Santangelo, Milano: Franco Angeli.Search in Google Scholar

Serti, Francesco, and Chiara Tomasi. 2012. “Self-Selection Along Different Export and Import Markets.” Economics Letters 117 (1):102–5.10.1016/j.econlet.2012.04.099Search in Google Scholar

Serti, Francesco, Chiara Tomasi, and Antonello Zanfei. 2010. “Who Trades with Whom? Exploring the Links Between Firm’s International Activities, Skills and Wages.” Review of International Economics 18 (5):951–71.10.1111/j.1467-9396.2010.00919.xSearch in Google Scholar

Singh, Tarlok. 2010. “Does International Trade Cause Economic Growth? A Survey.” The World Economy 33 (11):1517–64.10.1002/9781444343991.ch7Search in Google Scholar

Spencer, Barbara J. 2005. “International Outsourcing and Incomplete Contracts.” Canadian Journal of Economics 38 (4):1107–35. 2005.10.3386/w11418Search in Google Scholar

Tomiura, Eiichi. 2005. “Foreign Outsourcing and Firm-Level Characteristics: Evidence From Japanese Manufacturers.” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 19 (2):255–71.10.1016/j.jjie.2005.03.007Search in Google Scholar

Tomiura, Eiichi. 2007a. “Foreign Outsourcing, Exporting, and FDI: A Productivity Comparison at the Firm-Level.” Journal of International Economics 72 (1):113–27.10.1016/j.jinteco.2006.11.003Search in Google Scholar

Tomiura, Eiichi. 2007b. “Global Sourcing, Technology, and Factor Intensity: Firm-Level Relationships”, RIETI Discussion Paper Series No. 24.Search in Google Scholar

Tomiura, Eiichi. 2009. “Foreign Versus Domestic Outsourcing: Firm-Level Evidence on the Role of Technology.” International Review of Economics and Finance 18 (2):219–26.10.1016/j.iref.2008.06.001Search in Google Scholar

Wagner, Joachim. 2007. “Exports and Productivity: A Survey of the Evidence From Firm-Level Data.” The World Economy 30 (1):60–72.10.1142/9789813109698_0001Search in Google Scholar

Wagner, Joachim. 2012. “International Trade and Firm Performance: A Survey of Empirical Studies Since 2006.” Review of World Economics 148 (2):235–67.10.1142/9789813109698_0002Search in Google Scholar

Yeaple, Stephen R. 2006. “Offshoring, Foreign Direct Investment, and the Structure of U.S. Trade.” Journal of the European Economic Association (Papers and Proceedings) 4 (2–3):602–11.10.1162/jeea.2006.4.2-3.602Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2015-12-8
Published in Print: 2016-4-1

©2016 by De Gruyter

Downloaded on 19.4.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejeap-2015-0030/html
Scroll to top button