Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter September 27, 2013

On Partially Honest Nash Implementation in Private Good Economies with Restricted Domains: A Sufficient Condition

  • Ahmed Doghmi EMAIL logo and Abderrahmane Ziad

Abstract

In this article, we study the problem of Nash implementation in private good economies with single-peaked, single-plateaued, and single-dipped preferences in the presence of at least one minimally honest agent. We prove that all solutions of the problem of fair division satisfying unanimity can be implemented in Nash equilibria as long as there are at least three agents participating in the mechanism (game form). To justify this result, we provide a list of solutions which violate the condition of no-veto power.

JEL classification: C72; D71

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Michele Lombardi for his suggestions and helpful comments. We would also like to thank the seminar participants at Maastricht University in Netherland. We are particularly grateful to two anonymous referees of the journal for comments that greatly improved this article. Of course any error is our own responsibility.

References

Doghmi, A.. 2013a. “Nash Implementation in Allocation Problem with Single-Dipped Preferences.” Games4:3849.10.3390/g4010038Search in Google Scholar

Doghmi, A.. 2013b. “Nash Implementation in Private Good Economies When Preferences Are Single-Dipped with Best Indifferent Allocations.” Mathematical Economics Letters. DOI 10.1515/mel-2013-0003.10.1515/mel-2013-0003Search in Google Scholar

Doghmi, A., and A.Ziad. 2008a. “Reexamination of Maskin’s Theorem on Nash Implementability.” Economics Letters100:1502.10.1016/j.econlet.2007.12.009Search in Google Scholar

Doghmi, A., and A.Ziad. 2008b. “Nash Implementation in Exchange Economies with Single-Peaked Preferences.” Economics Letters100:15760.10.1016/j.econlet.2007.12.010Search in Google Scholar

Doghmi, A., and A.Ziad. 2013a. “Nash Implementation in Private Good Economies with Single-Plateaued Preferences.” Working Paper.Search in Google Scholar

Doghmi, A., and A.Ziad. 2013b. “Nash Implementation in Domain Restrictions with Indifferences.” Working Paper. DOI 10.1515/mel-2013-0003.Search in Google Scholar

Dutta, B., and A.Sen. 2009[2012]. “Nash Implementation with Partially Honest Individuals.” Working Paper. Published 2012 in Games and Economic Behavior74:15469.10.1016/j.geb.2011.07.006Search in Google Scholar

Holden, R., N.Kartik, and O.Tercieux. 2012. “Simple Mechanisms and Preferences for Honesty.” Working Paper.Search in Google Scholar

Korpela, V. 2012. “Bayesian Implementation with Partially Honest Individuals.” Working paper, University of Turku.Search in Google Scholar

Lombardi, M., and N.Yoshihara. 2011. “Partially-Honest Nash Implementation: Characterization Results.” Working Paper, Hitotsubashi University.10.2139/ssrn.1759924Search in Google Scholar

Lombardi, M., and N.Yoshihara. 2012. “Natural Implementation with Partially Honest Agents.” Working Paper, Hitotsubashi University.10.2139/ssrn.2172419Search in Google Scholar

Maskin, E.1977[1999]. “Nash Equilibrium and Welfare Optimality.” M.I.T. mimeo. Published 1999 in the Review of Economic Studies66:2338.10.1111/1467-937X.00076Search in Google Scholar

Matsushima, H. 2008a. “Role of Honesty in Full Implementation.” Journal of Economic Theory139:3539.10.1016/j.jet.2007.06.006Search in Google Scholar

Matsushima, H. 2008b. “Behavioral Aspects of Implementation Theory.” Economics Letters100:1614.10.1016/j.econlet.2007.12.008Search in Google Scholar

Moore, J., and R.Repullo. 1990. “Nash Implementation: A Full Characterization.” Econometrica58:1083100.10.2307/2938301Search in Google Scholar

Thomson, W. 1990. “Manipulation and Implementation to Solutions to the Problem of Fair Allocations When Preferences Are Single-Peaked.” mimeo, University of Rochester.Search in Google Scholar

Thomson, W.. 2010. “Implementation to Solutions to the Problem of Fair Allocations When Preferences Are Single-Peaked.” Review of Economic Design14:115.10.1007/s10058-009-0092-9Search in Google Scholar

  1. 1

    The strict weak no-veto power condition has been introduced by Doghmi and Ziad (2008a, 2008b). An SCC F satisfies strict weak no-veto power, if for i, , and , for , and for all , then .

  2. 2

    The proof of the no-logical relationship between I-weak no-veto power and strict weak no-veto power is in Doghmi and Ziad (2013a).

  3. 3

    For all means that, for the agent i, to consume a share is as good as to consume the quantity . The asymmetrical part is written and the symmetrical part .

  4. 4

    The monotonic correspondences in our examples in the case of private good economies with single-peaked preferences are Pareto correspondence, no-envy correspondence, individually rational correspondence from equal division, and all intersections of them. For more details, see Thomson (1990, 2010).

  5. 5

    In standard Nash implementation, Doghmi (2013b) and Doghmi and Ziad (2013b) proved that many important monotonic correspondences studied in private good economies with single-dipped preferences by Doghmi (2013a) become no-monotonic when we allow multiple best/worst indifferent allocations. Thus, these correspondences can be examined in partially honest environment.

Received: 2012-12-27
Accepted: 2013-8-22
Published Online: 2013-9-27
Published in Print: 2013-1-1

©2013 by Walter de Gruyter Berlin / Boston

Downloaded on 19.4.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2012-0028/html
Scroll to top button