Skip to content
Publicly Available Published by De Gruyter July 11, 2014

Randomization Inference in the Regression Discontinuity Design: An Application to Party Advantages in the U.S. Senate

  • Matias D. Cattaneo , Brigham R. Frandsen and Rocío Titiunik EMAIL logo

Abstract

In the Regression Discontinuity (RD) design, units are assigned a treatment based on whether their value of an observed covariate is above or below a fixed cutoff. Under the assumption that the distribution of potential confounders changes continuously around the cutoff, the discontinuous jump in the probability of treatment assignment can be used to identify the treatment effect. Although a recent strand of the RD literature advocates interpreting this design as a local randomized experiment, the standard approach to estimation and inference is based solely on continuity assumptions that do not justify this interpretation. In this article, we provide precise conditions in a randomization inference context under which this interpretation is directly justified and develop exact finite-sample inference procedures based on them. Our randomization inference framework is motivated by the observation that only a few observations might be available close enough to the threshold where local randomization is plausible, and hence standard large-sample procedures may be suspect. Our proposed methodology is intended as a complement and a robustness check to standard RD inference approaches. We illustrate our framework with a study of two measures of party-level advantage in U.S. Senate elections, where the number of close races is small and our framework is well suited for the empirical analysis.

1 Introduction

Inference on the causal effects of a treatment is one of the basic aims of empirical research. In observational studies, where controlled experimentation is not available, applied work relies on quasi-experimental strategies carefully tailored to eliminate the effect of potential confounders that would otherwise compromise the validity of the analysis. Originally proposed by Thistlethwaite and Campbell [1], the regression discontinuity (RD) design has recently become one of the most widely used quasi-experimental strategies. In this design, units receive treatment based on whether their value of an observed covariate or “score” is above or below a fixed cutoff. The key feature of the design is that the probability of receiving the treatment conditional on the score jumps discontinuously at the cutoff, inducing variation in treatment assignment that is assumed to be unrelated to potential confounders. Imbens and Lemieux [2], Lee and Lemieux [3] and Dinardo and Lee [4] give recent reviews, including comprehensive lists of empirical examples.

The traditional inference approach in the RD design relies on flexible extrapolation (usually nonparametric curve estimation techniques) using observations near the known cutoff. This approach follows the work of Hahn et al. [5], who showed that, when placement relative to the cutoff completely determines treatment assignment, the key identifying assumption is that the conditional expectation of a potential outcome is continuous at the threshold. Intuitively, since nothing changes abruptly at the threshold other than the probability of receiving treatment, any jump in the conditional expectation of the outcome variable at the threshold is attributed to the effects of the treatment. Modern RD analysis employs local nonparametric curve estimation at either side of the threshold to estimate RD treatment effects, with local-linear regression being the preferred choice in most cases. See Porter [6], Imbens and Kalyanaraman [7] and Calonico et al. [8] for related theoretical results and further discussion.

Although not strictly justified by the standard framework, RD designs are routinely interpreted as local randomized experiments, where in a neighborhood of the threshold treatment status is considered as good as randomly assigned. Lee [9] first argued that if individuals are unable to precisely manipulate or affect their score, then variation in treatment near the threshold approximates a randomized experiment. This idea has been expanded in Lee and Lemieux [3] and Dinardo and Lee [4], where RD designs are described as the “close cousins” of randomized experiments. Motivated by this common interpretation, we develop a methodological framework for analyzing RD designs as local randomized experiments employing a randomization inference setup.[1] Characterizing the RD design in this way not only has intuitive appeal but also leads to an alternative way of conducting statistical inference. Building on Rosenbaum [14, 15], we propose a randomization inference framework to conduct exact finite-sample inference in the RD design that is most appropriate when the sample size in a narrow window around the cutoff – where local randomization is most plausible – is small. Small sample sizes are a common phenomenon in the analysis of RD designs, since the estimation of the treatment effect at the cutoff typically requires that observations far from the cutoff be given zero or little weight; this may constrain researchers’ ability to make inferences based on large-sample approximations. In order to increase the sample size, researchers often include observations far from the cutoff and engage in extrapolation. However, incorrect parametric extrapolation invalidates standard inferential approaches because point estimators, standard errors and test statistics will be biased. In such cases, if a local randomization assumption is plausible, our approach offers a valid alternative that minimizes extrapolation by relying only on the few closest observations to the cutoff. More generally, our methodological framework offers a complement and a robustness check to conventional RD procedures by providing a framework that requires minimal extrapolation and allows for exact finite-sample inference.

To develop our methodological framework, we first make precise a set of conditions under which RD designs are equivalent to local randomized experiments within a randomization inference framework. These conditions are strictly stronger than the usual continuity assumptions imposed in the RD literature, but similar in spirit to those imposed in Hahn et al. ([5], Theorem 2) for identification of heterogeneous treatment effects. The key assumption is that, for the given sample, there exists a neighborhood around the cutoff where a randomization-type condition holds. More generally, this assumption may be interpreted as an approximation device to the conventional continuity conditions that allows us to proceed as if only the few closest observations near the cutoff are randomly assigned. The plausibility of this assumption will necessarily be context-specific, requiring substantive justification and empirical support. Employing these conditions, we discuss how randomization inference tools may be used to conduct exact finite-sample inference in the RD context.

Our resulting empirical approach consists of two steps. The first step is choosing a neighborhood or window around the cutoff where treatment status is assumed to be as-if randomly assigned. We develop a data-driven, randomization-based window selection procedure based on “balance tests” of pre-treatment covariates and illustrate how this approach for window selection performs in our empirical illustration. The second step is to apply established randomization inference tools, given a hypothesized treatment assignment mechanism, to construct hypothesis tests, confidence intervals, and point estimates.

Our approach parallels the conventional nonparametric RD approach but makes a different tradeoff: our randomization assumption (constitutes an approximation that) is likely valid within a smaller neighborhood of the threshold than the one used in the flexible local polynomial approach, but allows for exact finite-sample inference in a setting where large-sample approximations may be poor. Both approaches involve choices for implementation: standard local polynomial RD estimation requires selecting (i) a bandwidth and (ii) a kernel and polynomial order, while for our approach researchers need to choose (i) the size of the window around the cutoff where randomization is plausible and (ii) a randomization mechanism and test statistic. As is well known in the literature, bandwidth selection is difficult and estimation results can be highly sensitive to its choice [8]. In our approach, selecting the window is also crucial, and researchers should pay special attention to how it is chosen. On the other hand, selecting a kernel and polynomial order is relatively less important, as is choosing a randomization mechanism and test statistic in our approach.

We illustrate our methodological framework with a study of party-level advantages in U.S. Senate elections, comparing future Democratic vote shares in states where the Democratic party barely won an election to states where it barely lost. We find that the effect of barely winning an election for a seat has a large and positive effect on the vote share in the following election for that seat, but a null effect on the following election for the state’s other seat. Our null findings are consistent with the results reported by Butler and Butler [16], who studied balancing and related hypotheses using standard RD methods, although we find that these null results may be sensitive to the choice of window.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 sets up our statistical framework, formally states the baseline assumptions required to apply randomization inference procedures to the RD design, and describes these procedures briefly. Section 3 discusses data-driven methods to select the window around the cutoff where the randomization assumption may be plausible. Section 4 briefly reviews the classical notion of incumbency advantage in the Political Science literature and discusses its differences with RD-based measures, while Section 5 presents the results of our empirical analysis. Section 6 discusses several extensions and applications of our methodology, and Section 7 concludes.

2 Randomization inference in RD

Consider a setting with n units, indexed i=1,2,,n, where the scalar Ri is the score observed for unit i, with the n-vector R collecting the observations. In our application, Ri is the Democratic margin of victory (at election t) for state i. We denote unit i’s “potential outcome” by yi(r), where r is a given value of the vector of scores. The outcome yi(r) is called a potential outcome because it denotes the outcomes that unit i would exhibit under each possible value of the score vector r.[2] In the randomization inference framework, the potential outcome functions yi(r) are considered fixed characteristics of the finite population of n units, and the observed vector of scores R is random.[3] Thus, the observed outcome for unit i is Yiyi(R) and is likewise a random variable with observations collected in the n-vector Y. The essential feature of the RD design is embodied in a treatment variable Zi=1(Rir0), which is determined by the position of the score relative to the cutoff or threshold value r0. The n-vector of treatment status indicators is denoted Z, with Zi=1 if unit i receives treatment and Zi=0 otherwise. We focus on the so-called sharp RD design, where all units comply with their assigned treatment, but we extend our methodology to the so-called fuzzy design, where treatment status is not completely determined by the score, in Section 6.1.

Our approach begins by specifying conditions within a neighborhood of the threshold that allow us to analyze the RD design as a randomized experiment. Specifically, we focus on an interval or window W0=[r¯,r¯] on the support of the score, containing the threshold value r0, where the assumptions described below hold. We denote the subvector of R corresponding to units with Ri inside this window as RW0, and likewise for other vectors. In addition, we define FRi|RiW0(r) to be the conditional distribution function of the score Ri given RiW0, for each unit i. Our main condition casts the RD design as a local randomized experiment.

Assumption 1: Local Randomization. There exists a neighborhood W0=r_,rˉ with r_<r0<rˉ such that for all i with RiW0:

(a)FRi|RiW0(r)=F(r), and

(b)yi(r)=yi(zW0) for all r.

The first part of Assumption 1 says that the distribution of the score is the same for all units inside W0, implying that the scores can be considered “as good as randomly assigned” in this window. This is a strong assumption and would be violated if, for example, the score were affected by the potential outcomes even near the threshold – but may be relaxed, for instance, by explicitly modeling the relationship between Ri and potential outcomes. The second part of this assumption requires that potential outcomes within the window depend on the score only through treatment indicators within the window. This implicitly makes two restrictions. First, it prevents potential outcomes of units inside W0 from being affected by the scores of units outside (i.e., yi(r)=yi(rW0)). Second, for units in W0, it requires that potential outcomes depend on the score only through the treatment indicators but not the particular value of the scores (i.e., yi(rW0)=yi(zW0)). This part of the assumption is plausible in many settings where, for example, Ri is primarily an input into a mechanical formula allocating assignment to the treatment Zi. In our party advantages application, this assumption implies that, in a small window around the cutoff, a party’s margin of victory does not affect its vote share in the next election except through winning the previous election.

The conditions in Assumption 1 are stronger than those typically required for identification and inference in the classical RD literature. Instead of only assuming continuity of the relevant population functions at r0 (e.g., conditional expectations, distribution functions), our assumption implies that, in the window W0, these functions are not only continuous but also constant as a function of the score.[4] But Assumption 1 can also be viewed as an approximation to the standard continuity conditions in much the same way the nonparametric large-sample approach approximates potential outcomes as locally linear. This connection is made precise in Section 6.5. Assumption 1 has two main implications for our approach. First, it means that near the threshold we can ignore the score values for purposes of statistical inference and focus on the treatment indicators ZW0. Second, since the distribution of ZW0 does not depend on potential outcomes, comparisons of observed outcomes across the threshold have a causal interpretation.

In most settings, Assumption 1 is plausible only within a narrow window of the threshold, leaving only a small number of units for analysis. Thus, the problems of estimation and inference using this assumption in the context of RD are complicated by small-sample concerns. Following Rosenbaum [14, 15], we propose using exact randomization inference methods to overcome this potential small-sample problem. In the remainder of this section, we maintain Assumption 1 and take as given the window W0, but we discuss explicitly empirical methods for choosing this window in Section 3.

2.1 Hypothesizing the randomization mechanism

The first task in applying randomization inference to the RD design is to choose a randomization mechanism for ZW0 that is assumed to describe the data generating process that places units on either side of the threshold. A natural starting place for a setting in which Zi is an individual-level variable (as opposed to a group-level characteristic) assumes Zi is a Bernoulli random variable with parameter π. In this case, the probability distribution of ZW0 is given by Pr(ZW0=z)=πz1(1π)(1z)1, for all vectors z in ΩW0, which in this case consists of the 2nW0 possible vectors of zeros and ones, where nW0 is the number of units in W0 and 1 is a conformable vector of ones. This randomization distribution is fully determined up to the value π, which is typically unknown in the context of RD applications. A natural choice for π would be πˆ=ZW01/nW0, the fraction of units within the window with scores exceeding the threshold.[5]

While the simplicity of this Bernoulli mechanism is attractive, a practical disadvantage is that it results in a positive probability of all units in the window being assigned to the same group. An alternative mechanism that avoids this problem, and is also likely to apply in settings where Zi is an individual-level variable, is a random allocation rule or “fixed-margins randomization” in which the number of units within the window assigned to treatment is fixed at mW0. Under this mechanism, ΩW0 consists of the nW0mW0 possible nW0-vectors with mW0 ones and nW0mW0 zeros. The probability distribution is Pr(ZW0=z)=nW0mW01, for all zΩW0.

When Zi is a group-level variable, or where additional variables are known to affect the probability of treatment, other mechanisms approximating a block-randomized or stratified design will be more appropriate.

2.2 Test of no effect

Having chosen an appropriate randomization mechanism, we can test the sharp null hypothesis of no treatment effect under Assumption 1. No treatment effect means observed outcomes are fixed regardless of the realization of ZW0. Under this null hypothesis, potential outcomes are not a function of treatment status inside W0; that is, yi(z)=yi for all i within the window and for all zΩW0, where yi is a fixed scalar. The distribution of any test statistic T(ZW0,yW0) is known, since it depends only on the known distribution of ZW0, and yW0, the fixed vector of observed responses. The test thus consists of computing a significance level for the observed value of the test statistic. The one-sided significance level is simply the sum of the probabilities of assignment vectors z leading to values of T(z,yW0) at least as large as the observed value T˜, that is, Pr(T(ZW0,yW0)T˜)=zΩW01(T(z,yW0)T˜)Pr(ZW0=z), where Pr(ZW0=z) follows the assumed randomization mechanism.

Any test statistic may be used, including difference-in-means, the Kolmogorov–Smirnov test statistic, and difference-in-quantiles. While in typical cases the significance level of the test may be approximated when a large number of units is available, randomization-based inference remains valid (given Assumption 1) even for a small number of units. This feature is particularly important in the RD design where the number of units within W0 is likely to be small.

2.3 Confidence intervals and point estimates

While the test of no treatment effect is often an important starting place, and appealing for the minimal assumptions it relies on, in most applications we would like to construct confidence intervals and point estimates of treatment effects. This requires additional assumptions. The next assumption we introduce is that of no interference between units.

Assumption 2: Local stable unit treatment value assumption. For all i with RiW0: if zi=z˜i then yi(zW0)=yi(z˜W0).

This assumption means that unit i’s potential outcome depends only on zi, which, together with Assumption 1, allows us to write potential outcomes simply as yi(0) and yi(1) for units in W0. Assumptions 1–2 enable us to characterize the effects of treatment through inference on the distribution or quantiles of the population of nW0 potential outcomes in W0, {yi(z):RiW0}, as in Rosenbaum ([14], Chapter 5). The goal is to construct a confidence interval [a(q),b(q)] that covers with at least some specified probability the q-quantile of {yi(1):RiW0}, denoted Q1(q), which is simply the q×nW0-th order statistic of {yi(1):RiW0} for units within the window W0, and a similar confidence interval for Q0(q). The confidence interval for Q1(q) consists of the observed treated values x above the threshold (but in the window) such that the hypothesis H0:Q1(q)=x is not rejected by a test of at most some specified size. The test statistic is J(x)=ZW01(YW0x), the number of units above the threshold whose outcomes are less than or equal to x, and has distribution Pr(J(x)=j)=(q×nW0j)(nW0q×nW0mW0j)/(nW0mW0) under a fixed-margins randomization mechanism where mW0 denotes the number of treated units inside W0. Inference on the quantile treatment effect Q1(q)Q0(q) can be based on confidence regions for Q1(q) and Q0(q).

Point estimates and potentially shorter confidence intervals for the treatment effect can be obtained at the cost of a parametric model for the treatment effect. A simple (albeit restrictive) model that is commonly used is the constant treatment effect model described below.

Assumption 3: Local constant treatment effect model. For all i with RiW0: yi(1)=yi(0)+τ, for some τ.

Under Assumptions 1–3, and hypothesizing a value τ=τ0 for the treatment effect, the adjusted responses, Yiτ0Zi=yi(0), are constant under alternative realizations of ZW0. Thus, under this model, a test of the hypothesis τ=τ0 proceeds exactly as the test of the sharp null discussed above, except that now the adjusted responses are used in place of the raw responses. The test statistic is therefore T(ZW0,YW0τ0ZW0), and the significance level is computed as before. Confidence intervals for the treatment effect can be found by finding all values τ0 such that the test τ=τ0 is not rejected, and Hodges–Lehmann-type point estimates can also be constructed finding the value of τ0 such that the observed test statistic T(ZW0,YW0τ0ZW0) equals its expectation under the null hypothesis.

We discuss this constant and additive treatment effect model because it allows us to illustrate how confidence intervals can be easily derived by inverting hypothesis tests about a treatment effect parameter. But there is nothing in the randomization inference framework that we have adopted that necessitates Assumption 3. This assumption can be easily generalized to allow for non-constant treatment effects, such as Tobit or attributable effects (see Rosenbaum [15], Chapter 2). Indeed, the technique of constructing adjusted potential outcomes and inverting hypothesis tests of the sharp null hypothesis is general and allows for arbitrarily heterogeneous models of treatment effects. Furthermore, the confidence intervals for quantile treatment effects described above do not require a parametric treatment effect model.

3 Window selection

If there exists a window W0=[r_,rˉ] where our randomization-type condition Assumption 1 holds, and this window is known, applying randomization inference procedures to the RD design is straightforward. In practice, however, this window will be unknown and must be chosen by the researcher. This is the main methodological challenge of applying a randomization inference approach to RD designs and is analogous to the problem of bandwidth selection in conventional nonparametric RD approaches [7, 8].

Imposing Assumption 1 throughout, we propose a method to select W0 based on covariates. These could be either predetermined covariates (determined before treatment is assigned and thus, by construction, unaffected by it) or placebo covariates (determined after treatment is assigned but nonetheless expected to be unaffected by treatment given prior theoretical knowledge about how the treatment operates). In most RD empirical applications, researchers have access to predetermined covariates and use them to assess the plausibility of the RD assumptions and/or to reduce sampling variability. A typical strategy to validate the design is to test whether there is a treatment effect at the discontinuity for these covariates, and absence of such effect is interpreted as supporting evidence for the RD design.

Our window selection procedure is inspired by this common empirical practice. In particular, we assume that there exists a covariate for each unit, denoted xi(r), which is unrelated to the score inside W0 but related to it outside of W0. This implies that for a window WW0, the score and covariate will be associated for units with RiWW0 but not for units with RiW0. This means that if the sharp null hypothesis is rejected in a given window, that window is strictly larger than W0, which leads naturally to a procedure for selecting W0: perform a sequence of “balance” tests for the covariates, one for each window candidate, beginning with the largest window and sequentially shrinking it until the test fails to reject “balance”.

The first step to formalize this approach is to assume that the treatment effect on the covariate x is zero inside the window where Assumption 1 holds. We collect the covariates in X=(X1,X2,,Xn) where, as before, Xi=xi(R).

Assumption 4: Zero treatment effect for covariate. For all i with RiW0: the covariate xi(r) satisfies xi(r)=xi(zW0)=xi for all r.

Assumption 4 states that the sharp null hypothesis holds for Xi in W0. This assumption simply states what is known to be true when the available covariate is determined before treatment: treatment could not have possibly affected the covariates and therefore its effect is zero by construction. Note that if Xi is a predetermined covariate, the sharp null holds everywhere, not only in W0. However, we require the weaker condition that it holds only in W0 to include placebo covariates.

The second necessary step to justify our procedure for selecting W0 based on covariate balance is to require that the covariate and the score be correlated outside of W0. We formalize this requirement in the following assumption, which is stronger than needed, but justifies our proposed window selection procedure in an intuitive way, as further discussed below. Define W˜=[ρ_,r_)(rˉ,ρˉ] for a pair (ρ_,ρˉ) satisfying ρ_<r_<rˉ<ρˉ, and recall that r0W0=[r_,rˉ].

Assumption 5: Association outside W0 between covariate and score. For all i with RiW˜ and for all rW˜:

(a)FRi|RiW˜(r)=F(r;xi(r)), and

(b)For all jk, either (i) xj>xkF(r;xj)<F(r;xk) or (ii) xj>xkF(r;xj)>F(r;xk).

Assumption 5 is key to obtain a valid window selector, since it requires a form of non-random selection among units outside W0 that leads to an observable association between the covariate and the score for those units with RiW0, i.e., between the vectors XW˜ and RW˜. In other words, under Assumption 5 the vectors XW and RW will be associated for any window W such that WW0. Since x is predetermined or placebo, this association cannot arise because of a direct effect of r on x. Instead, it may be that x affects r (e.g., higher campaign contributions at t1 lead to higher margin of victory at t) or that some observed or unobserved factor affects both x and r (e.g., more able politicians are both more likely to raise high contributions and win by high margins). In other words, Assumption 5 leads to units with high Ri having high (or low) Xi, even when Xi is constant for all values of r.

Assumptions 1, 4 and 5 justify a simple procedure to find W0. This procedure finds the widest window for which the covariates and scores are not associated inside this window, but are associated outside of it. We base our procedure on randomization-based tests of the sharp null hypothesis of no effect for each available covariate x. Given Assumption 4 above, for units with RiW0, the treatment assignment vector ZW0 has no effect on the covariate vector XW0. Under this assumption, the size of the test of no effect is known, and therefore we can control the probability with which we accept a window where the assumptions hold. In addition, under Assumption 5 (or a similar assumption), this procedure will be able to detect the true window W0. Such a procedure can be implemented in different ways. A simple approach is to begin by considering all observations (i.e., choosing the largest possible window W0), test the sharp null of no effect of Zi on Xi for these observations and, if the null hypothesis is rejected, continue by decreasing the size of the window until the resulting test fails to reject the null hypothesis.

The procedure depends crucially on sequential testing in nested windows: if the sharp null hypothesis is rejected for a given window, then this hypothesis will also be rejected in any window that contains it (with a test of sufficiently high power). Thus, the procedure searches windows of different sizes until it finds the largest possible window such that the sharp null hypothesis cannot be rejected for any window contained in it. This procedure can be implemented as follows.

Window selection procedure based on predetermined covariates. Select a test statistic of interest, denoted T(X,R). Let R(j) be the jth order statistic of R in the sample of all observations indexed by i=1,,n.

Step 1: Define W(j0,j1)=[R(j0),R(j1)], and set j0=1, j1=n. Choose minimum values j0,min and j1,min satisfying j0,min<r0<j1,min, which set the minimum number of observations required in W(j0,min,j1,min).

Step 2: Conduct a test of no effect using T(XW(j0,j1),RW(j0,j1)).

Step 3: If the null hypothesis is rejected, increase j0 and decrease j1. If j0<j0,min and j1,min\gtj1 go back to Step 2, else stop and conclude that lower and upper ends for W0 cannot be selected. If the null hypothesis is not rejected, keep R[j0] and R[j1] as the ends of the selected window.

An important feature of this approach is that, unlike conventional hypothesis testing, we are particularly concerned about the possibility of failing to reject the null hypothesis when it is false (Type II error). Usually, researchers are concerned about controlling Type I error to avoid rejecting the null hypothesis too often when it is true, and thus prefer testing procedures that are not too “liberal”. In our context, however, rejecting the null hypothesis is used as evidence that the local randomization Assumption 1 does not hold, and our ultimate goal is to learn whether the data support the existence of a neighborhood around the cutoff where our null hypothesis fails to be rejected. In this sense, the roles of Type I and Type II error are interchanged in our context.[6] This has important implications for the practical implementation of our approach, which we discuss next.

3.1 Implementation

Implementing the procedure proposed above requires three choices: (i) a test statistic, (ii) the minimum sample sizes (j0,min, j1,min), and (iii) a testing procedure and associated significance level α. We discuss here how these choices affect our window selector, and give guidelines for researchers who wish to use this procedure in empirical applications.

3.1.1 Choice of test statistic

This choice is important because different test statistics will have power against different alternative hypotheses and, as discussed above, we prefer tests with low type II error. In our procedure, the sharp null hypothesis of no treatment effect could employ different test statistics such as difference-in-means, Wilcoxon rank sum or Kolmogorov–Smirnov, because the null randomization distribution of any of them is known. Lehmann [19] and Rosenbaum [14, 15] provide a discussion and comparison of alternative test statistics. In our application, we employ the difference-in-means test statistic.

3.1.2 Choice of minimum sample size

The main goal of setting a minimum sample size is to prevent the procedure from having too few observations when conducting the hypothesis test in the smallest possible window. These constants should be large enough so that the test statistic employed has “good” power properties to detect departures from the null hypothesis. We recommend setting j0,min and j1,min so that roughly at least 10 observations are included at either side of the threshold. One way of justifying this choice is by considering a two-sample standard normal shift model with a true treatment effect of one standard deviation and 10 observations in each group, in which case a randomization-based test of the sharp null hypothesis of no treatment effect using the difference-in-means statistic has power of roughly 80% with significance level of 0.15 (and 60 percent with significance level of 0.05). Setting j0,min and j1,min at higher values will increase the power to detect departures from Assumption 1 and will lead to a more conservative choice of W0 (assuming the chosen window based on those higher values is feasible, that is, has positive length).

3.1.3 Choice of testing procedure and α

First, our procedure performs hypothesis tests in a sequence of nested windows and thus involves multiple hypothesis testing (see Efron [20] for a recent review). This implies that, even when the null hypothesis is true, it will be rejected several times (e.g., if the hypotheses are independent, they will be rejected roughly as many times as the significance level times the number of windows considered). For the family-wise error rate, multiple testing implies that our window selector will reject more windows than it should, because the associated p-values will be too small. But since we are more concerned about failing to reject a false null hypothesis (type II error) than we are about rejecting a true one (type I error), this implies that our procedure will be more conservative, selecting a smaller window than the true window (if any) where the local randomization assumption is likely to hold. For this reason, we recommend that researchers do not adjust p-values for multiple testing.[7] Second, we must choose a significance level α to test whether the local randomization assumption is rejected in each window. As our focus is on type II error, this value should be chosen to be higher than conventional levels for a conservative choice for W0. Based on the power calculations discussed above, a reasonable choice is to adopt α=0.15; higher values will lead to a more conservative choice of W0 if a feasible window satisfies the stricter requirement. Nonetheless, researchers should report all p-values graphically so that others can judge how varying α would alter the size of the chosen window. Finally, when the sharp null is tested for multiple covariates in every candidate window, the results of multiple tests must be aggregated in a single p-value. To be as conservative as possible, we choose the minimum p-value across all tests in every window.

In the upcoming sections, we illustrate how our methodological framework works in practice with a study of party advantages in U.S. Senate elections.

4 Regression discontinuity and the party incumbency advantage

Political scientists have long studied the question of whether the incumbent status of previously elected legislators translates into an electoral or incumbency advantage. This advantage is believed to stem from a variety of factors, including name recognition, the ability to perform casework and cultivate a personal vote, the ability to deter high-quality challengers, the implementation of pro-incumbent redistricting plans, and the availability of the incumbency cue amidst declining party attachments. Although the literature is vast, it has focused overwhelmingly on the incumbency advantage of members of the U.S. House of Representatives.[8]

Estimating the incumbency advantage is complicated by several factors. One is that high-quality politicians tend to obtain higher vote shares than their low-quality counterparts, making them more likely both to become incumbents in the first place and to obtain high vote shares in future elections. Another is that incumbents tend to retire strategically when they anticipate a poor performance in the upcoming election, making “open seats” (races where no incumbent is running) a dubious baseline for comparison. Any empirical strategy that ignores these methodological issues will likely overestimate the size of the incumbency advantage.

Recently, Lee [9] proposed using a regression discontinuity design based on the discontinuous relationship between the incumbency status of a party in a given election and its vote share in the previous election: in a two-party system, a party enjoys incumbency status when it obtains 50% of the vote or more in the previous election, but loses incumbency status to the opposing party otherwise. In this RD design, the score is the vote share obtained by a party at election t, the cutoff is 50%, and the treatment (incumbent status) is assigned deterministically based on whether the vote share at t exceeds the cutoff. The outcome of interest is the party’s vote share in the following election, at t+1. The design compares districts where the party barely won election t to districts where the party barely lost election t, and computes the difference in the vote share obtained by the party in the following election, at t+1. This difference is the boost in the party’s vote share obtained by barely winning relative to barely losing, and it is related but different from the classical notions of incumbency advantage in the Political Science literature. Caughey and Sekhon [26, p. 402] discuss the connection between a global polynomial RD estimator and the classical Gelman and King [23] estimator, and Erikson and Titiunik [25] discuss the relationship between the RD estimand and the personal incumbency advantage.

4.1 RD design in U.S. Senate elections: two estimands of party advantage

Our application of the RD design to U.S. Senate elections focuses on two specific estimands that capture local electoral advantages and disadvantages at the party level. The first estimand, which we call the incumbent-party advantage, focuses on the effect of the Democratic party winning a Senate seat on its vote share in the following election for that seat. The other estimand, which we call the opposite-party advantage following Alesina et al. [27], is unrelated to the traditional concept of the incumbency advantage and reveals the disadvantages faced by the party that tries to win the second seat in a state’s Senate delegation. Establishing whether the opposite-party advantage exists has been of central importance to theories of split-party Senate delegations, and there are different explanations of why it may arise.[9]

Both estimands, formally defined in terms of potential outcomes below, are derived from applying an RD design to the staggered structure of Senate elections, which we now describe briefly. Term length in the U.S. Senate is 6 years and there are 100 seats. These Senate seats are divided into three classes of roughly equal size (Class I, Class II and Class III), and every 2 years only the seats in one class are up for election. As a result, the terms are staggered: in every general election, which occurs every 2 years, only one third of Senate seats are up for election. Each state elects two senators in different classes to serve a 6-year term in popular statewide elections. Since its two senators belong to different classes, each state has Senate elections separated by alternating 2-year and 4-year intervals. Moreover, in any pair of consecutive elections, each election is for a different senate seat – that is, for a seat in a different class.[10]

Following Butler and Butler [16], we apply the RD design in the U.S. Senate analogously to its previous applications in the U.S. House, comparing states where the Democratic party barely won election t to states where the Democratic party barely lost. But in the Senate, the staggered structure of terms adds a layer of variability that allows us to both study party advantages and validate our design in more depth than would be possible in a non-staggered legislature such as the House. Using t, t+1 and t+2 to denote three successive elections, the staggered structure of the Senate implies that the incumbent elected at t, if he or she decides to run for reelection, will be on the ballot at t+2, but not at t+1, when the Senate election will be for the other seat in the state. As summarized in Table 1, this staggered structure leads to two different research designs analyzing two separate effects.

Table 1

Three consecutive Senate elections in a hypothetical state

ElectionSeat ASeat BDesign and outcomes
tElection held. Candidate C from party P winsNo election held
t+1No election heldElection held. (Candidate C is not a contestant in this race)Design II: Effect of P winning Seat A at t on P’s vote share for Seat B at t+1 (Opposite-party advantage)
t+2Election held. Candidate C may or may not be P’s candidateNo election heldDesign I: Effect of P winning Seat A at t on P’s vote share for Seat A at t+2 (Incumbent-party advantage)

The first design (Design I) focuses on the effect of party P’s barely winning at t on its vote share at t+2, the second election after election t, and defines the first RD estimand we study. As illustrated in the third row of Table 1, in Design I elections t and t+2 are for the same Senate seat, and this incumbent-party effect captures the added vote share received by the Democratic party due to having won (barely) the seat’s previous election. The second research design (Design II), illustrated in the second row of Table 1, allows us to analyze the effect of party P’s barely winning election t on the vote share it receives in election t+1 for the state’s other seat, when the incumbent candidate elected at t is, by construction, not contesting the election. Thus, Design II defines the second RD estimand, the opposite-party advantage, which will be negative when the party of the sitting senator (elected at t) is at a disadvantage relative to the opposing party in the election for the other seat (which occurs at t+1).

Using the notation introduced in Section 2, we consider two estimands defined by Designs I and II. We define the treatment indicator as Zit=1(Ritr0) and the potential outcomes in elections t+2 and t+1, respectively, as yit+2(Zit) and yit+1(Zit).[11] Thus, the incumbent-party advantage for an individual state i is defined as τiIP=yit+2(1)yit+2(0) and the opposite-party advantage as τiOP=yit+1(1)yit+1(0). Our randomization inference approach to RD offers hypothesis testing and point-type estimators (e.g., Hodges–Lehmann) of these parameters, possibly restricted by a treatment effect model, for the units in the window W0 where local randomization holds.

5 Results: RD-based party advantages in U.S. Senate elections

We analyze U.S. Senate elections between 1914 and 2010. This is the longest possible period to study popular U.S. Senate elections, as before 1914 Senate members were elected indirectly by state legislatures. We combine several data sources. We collected election returns for the period 1914–1990 from The Interuniversity Consortium for Political and Social Research (ICPSR) Study 7757, and for the period 1990–2010 from the CQ Voting and Elections Collection. We obtained population estimates at the state level from the U.S. Census Bureau. We also used ICPSR Study 3371 and data from the Senate Historical Office to establish whether each individual senator served the full 6 years of his or her term, and exclude all elections in which a subsequent vacancy occurs. We exclude vacancy cases because, in most states, when a Senate seat is left vacant the governor can appoint a replacement to serve the remaining time in the term or until special elections are held, and in most states appointed senators need not be of the same party as the incumbents they replace, leaving the “treatment assignment” of the previous election undefined.[12]

5.1 Selecting the window

We selected our window using the method based on predetermined covariates presented in Section 3. The largest window we considered was [100,100], covering the entire support of our running variable. Based on power considerations discussed above, the minimum window we considered was [0.5,0.5], because within this window there are 9 and 14 outcome observations to the left and right of the cutoff, respectively, and we wanted to set j0,min and j1,min to be approximately equal to 10. Using our notation in Section 3, this means we set [R(j0,min),R(j1,min)]=[0.50,0.50] and [R(1),R(n)]=[100,100]. We analyzed all symmetric windows around the cutoff between [0.5,0.5] and [100,100] in increments of 0.125 percentage points. In each window, we performed randomization-based tests of the sharp null hypothesis of no treatment effect for each of eight predetermined covariates: state-level Democratic percentage of the vote in the past presidential election, state population, Democratic percentage of the vote in the t1 Senate election, Democratic percentage of the vote in the t2 Senate election, indicator for Democratic victory in the t1 Senate election, indicator for Democratic victory in the t2 Senate election, indicator for open Senate seat at t, indicator for midterm (non-presidential) election at t and indicator for whether the president of the U.S. at t is Democratic. As discussed above, we set α=0.15, and use the difference-in-means as the test statistic in our randomization-based tests. These tests (and similar tests for the outcomes presented below) are based on 10,000 simulations of the randomization distribution of ZW0 assuming a fixed-margins assignment mechanism. For each window, we chose the minimum p-value across these eight covariates.

Figure 1 summarizes graphically the results of our window selector. For every symmetric window considered (x-axis), we plot the minimum p-value found in that window (y-axis). The x-axis is the absolute value of our running variable, the Democratic margin of victory at election t, which is equivalent to the upper limit of each window considered (since we only consider symmetric windows) and ranges from 0 to 100. For example, the point 20 on the x-axis corresponds to the [20,20] window. The figure also shows the conventional significance level of 0.05 and the significance level of 0.15 that we use for implementation. There are a few notable patterns in this figure. First, for most of the windows considered, the minimum p-value is indistinguishable from zero, which means that there is strong evidence against Assumption 1 in most of the support of our running variable. Second, the minimum p-value is above the conventional 5% significance level in very few windows (15 out of the total 797 windows considered). Third, the decrease in p-values is roughly monotonic and very rapid, suggesting that Assumption 1 is implausible except very close to the cutoff. Using α=0.15, our chosen window is [0.75,0.75], the third smallest window we considered, since this is the largest window where the minimum p-value exceeds 15% in that window and all the windows contained in it.

Figure 1 Window selector based on predetermined covariates
Figure 1

Window selector based on predetermined covariates

Table 2 shows the minimum p-values for the first five consecutive windows we considered and also for the windows [1.5,1.5], [2,2], [10,10] and [20,20]. The minimum p-value in our chosen window is 0.2682, and the minimum p-value in the next largest window, [0.875,0.875], is 0.0842. P-values decrease rapidly after that and, with some exceptions such as around window [1.50,1.50], do so monotonically. Note also that had we set α=0.10, our chosen window would still have been [0.75,0.75]. And if we had set α=0.05, our chosen window would have been [0.875,0.875], barely larger than our final choice, which shows the steep decline of the minimum p-value as we include observations farther from the cutoff.

Our window selection procedure suggests that Assumption 1 is plausible in the window [0.75,0.75]. Further inspection and analysis of the 38 observations in this window (23 treated and 15 control) shows that these observations are not associated in any predictable way. These electoral races are not concentrated in a particular year or geographic area: these 38 races are spread across 24 different years with no more than 3 occurring in the same year, and 26 different states with at most 4 occurring in the same state. This empirical finding further supports the idea that these observations might be treated as-if randomly assigned. Moreover, an important implication of this finding is that there is no observable clustering structure in the sample inside the window [0.75,0.75], which in turn implies that standard randomization inference techniques are directly applicable. Finally, we also performed standard density tests for sorting and found no evidence of any systematic discrepancy between control and treatment units.[13] Thus, below we proceed to make inferences about the treatment effects of interest under Assumption 1 in this window.

Table 2

Window selector based on pretreatment covariates: randomization-based p-valuesfrom balance tests for different windows

WindowMinimum p-valueCovariate with minimum p-value
[0.500,0.500]0.2639Dem Senate Vote t– 2
[0.625,0.625]0.4260Open Seat t
[0.750,0.750]0.2682Open Seat t
[0.875,0.875]0.0842Open Seat t
[1.000,1.000]0.0400Open Seat t
[1.500,1.500]0.0958Midterm t
[2.000,2.000]0.0291Midterm t
[10.00,10.00]0.0008Open Seat t
[20.00,20.00]0.0000Dem Senate Vote t– 1

5.2 Inference within the selected window

We now show that the results obtained by conventional methods are robust to our randomization-based approach in both Design I and Design II. Randomization-based results within the window imply a sizable advantage when a party’s same seat is up for election (Design I) that is very similar to results based on conventional methods. Randomization results on outcomes when the state’s other seat is up for reelection (Design II) show a null effect, also in accordance with conventional methods. However, as we discuss below, the null opposite advantage results from Design I are sensitive to our window choice, and a significant opposite-party advantage appears in the smallest window contained within our chosen window.

Our randomization-based results include a Hodges–Lehmann estimate, a treatment effect confidence interval obtained inverting hypothesis tests based on a constant treatment effect model, a quantile treatment effect confidence interval, and a sharp null hypothesis p-value calculated as described in the window selection section above. Table 3 contrasts the party advantage estimates and tests obtained using our randomization-based framework, reported in column (3), to those obtained from two classical approaches: a 4th-order parametric fit as in Lee [9] reported in column (1), and a nonparametric local-linear regression with a triangular kernel as suggested by Imbens and Lemieux [2], using a mean-squared-error (MSE) optimal bandwidth implementation described in Calonico et al. [8], reported in column (2). For both approaches, we show conventional confidence intervals; for the local linear regression results, we also show the robust confidence intervals developed by Calonico et al. [8], since the MSE optimal bandwidth is too large for conventional confidence intervals to be valid.[14] Panel A presents results for Design I on the incumbent-party advantage, in which the outcome is the Democratic vote share in election t+2. Panel B presents results for Design II on the opposite-party advantage, in which the outcome is the Democratic vote share in election t+1. Our randomization-based results are calculated in the window [0.75,0.75] chosen above. Note that, as mentioned above, there is no need for clustering in our window, nor is clustering empirically possible.

The point estimates in the first row of Panel A show an estimated incumbent-party effect of around 7 to 9 percentage points for standard RD methods and 9 percentage points for the randomization-based approach. These estimates are highly significant (p-values for all three approaches fall well below conventional levels) and point to a substantial advantage to the incumbent party when the party’s seat is up for re-election. In other words, our randomization-based approach shows that the results obtained with standard methods are remarkably robust: a local or global approximation that uses hundreds of observations far away from the cutoff yields an incumbent-party advantage that is roughly equivalent to the one estimated with the 38 races decided by three quarters of a percentage point or less. This robustness is illustrated in the top panel of Figure 2. Figure 2(a) displays the fit of the Democratic Vote Share at t+2 from a local linear regression on either side of the optimal bandwidth and shows a clear jump at the cutoff of roughly 7.4 percentage points (dots are binned means). Figure 2(b) on the right displays the mean of the Democratic Vote Share at t+2 on either side of our chosen [0.75,0.75] window (dots are individual data points) and shows a similar (slightly larger) positive jump at the cutoff.

In our data-driven window, estimates of the opposite-party party advantage also appear robust to the method of estimation employed. In Panel B, estimates on Democratic Vote Share at t+1 based on conventional methods show very small, statistically insignificant effects of around 0.64 to 0.35 in columns (1) and (2). These standard methods of inference for RD are therefore unable to reject the hypothesis of a null effect, and would suggest that, contrary to balancing and constituency-based theories, there is no opposite-party advantage in U.S. Senate elections. Our randomization-based approach, presented in column (3) of Panel B, arrives at a similar conclusion, finding a negative point estimate but a sharp null p-value above 0.80 and a 95% confidence interval for a constant treatment effect that ranges roughly between –8 and 5. Similarly, the 95% confidence intervals for the 25th and 75th quantile treatment effects are roughly centered around zero and are consistent with a null opposite-party advantage.

These results are illustrated in the bottom row of Figure 2, where Figure 2(c) and 2(d) are analogous to Figure 2(a) and 2(b), respectively. The effect of winning an election by 0.75% appears roughly equivalent to the effect estimated by standard methods. In our randomization-based window, the mean of the control group is slightly larger than the mean of the treatment group, but as shown in Table 3 we do not find statistically significant evidence of an opposite-party advantage.

Taken together, our results provide interesting evidence about party-level electoral advantages in the U.S. Senate. First, our results show that there is a strong and robust incumbent-party effect, with the party that barely wins a Senate seat at t receiving on average seven to nine additional percentage points in the following election for that seat. Second, our randomization-based approach confirms the previous finding of Butler and Butler [16], according to which there is no opposite-party advantage in the U.S. Senate. As we show below, however, and in contrast to the incumbent-party advantage results, the opposite-party advantage result is sensitive to our window choice and becomes large and significant as predicted by theory inside a smaller window.

Figure 2 RD design in U.S. Senate elections, 1914–2010 – standard local-linear approach vs. randomization-based approach
Figure 2

RD design in U.S. Senate elections, 1914–2010 – standard local-linear approach vs. randomization-based approach

Table 3

Incumbent- and opposite-party advantage in the U.S. Senate using an RD design

Conventional approachesRandomization-basedapproach
ParametricNonparametric
(1)(2)(3)
A. Design I (outcome = Dem Vote Share at t+2)
Point estimate9.417.439.32
p-value0.00000.00000.0004
95% CI[6.16, 12.65][4.49, 10.36][4.60, 14.78]
95% CI robust[4.07, 10.98]
0.25-QTE 95% CI[–2.00, 21.12]
0.75-QTE 95% CI[3.68, 18.94]
Bandwidth/Window16.79[–0.75, 0.75]
Sample size treated70231022
Sample size control59534315
B. Design II (outcome = Dem Vote Share at t+1)
Point estimate0.640.35–0.79
p-value0.790.820.62
95% CI[–3.16, 4.44][–2.69, 3.39][–8.25, 5.03]
95% CI robust[–2.83, 4.13]
0.25-QTE 95% CI[–8.75, 9.96]
0.75-QTE 95% CI[–11.15, 11.31]
Bandwidth/Window23.27[–0.75, 0.75]
Sample size treated73139723
Sample size control61042815

5.3 Sensitivity of results to window choice and test statistics

We study the sensitivity of our results to two choices: the window size and the test statistic used to conduct our tests. First, we replicate the randomization-based analysis presented above for different windows, both larger and smaller than our chosen [0.75,0.75] window. We consider one smaller window, [0.5,0.5], and two larger windows, [1.0,1.0] and [2.0,2.0]. We note that, given the results in Table 2, we do not believe that Assumption 1 is plausible in windows larger than [0.75,0.75] and we therefore would not interpret a change in results in larger windows as evidence against our chosen window. Nonetheless, it is valuable to know if our findings would continue to hold even under departures from Assumption 1 in larger windows. This observation, however, does not apply when considering smaller windows contained in [0.75,0.75], since if Assumption 1 holds inside our chosen window, it also must hold in all windows contained in it. Thus, analyzing the smaller window [0.5,0.5] can provide evidence on whether there is heterogeneity in the results found in the originally chosen window.

Second, we perform the test of the sharp null using different test statistics. Under Assumption 1, there is no relationship between the outcome and the score on either side of the threshold within W0. In this situation, performing randomization-based tests using the difference-in-means as a test statistic should yield the same results as using other test statistics that allow for a relationship between the conditional regression function and the score. This suggests using different test statistics in the same window as a robustness check. Let the window considered be [wl,wr] and recall that the cutoff is r0. In a similar spirit to conventional parametric and nonparametric RD methods, we consider two different additional test-statistics: the difference in the predicted values Yˆi from two regressions of Yi on Rir0 on either side of the cutoff evaluated at Ri=r0, and the difference in the predicted values Yˆi from two regressions of Yi on Rir0 and (Rir0)2 on either side of the cutoff evaluated at Ri=r0. Below, we call the p-values based on these test statistics “p-value linear” and “p-value quadratic”, respectively.

Table 4 presents the results from our sensitivity analysis. Panel A shows results for Democratic Vote Share at t+2 (Design I), and Panel B for Democratic Vote Share at t+1 (Design II). For each panel, we reproduce the results in our chosen [0.75,0.75] window and show results for the three additional windows mentioned above: [0.5,0.5], [1.0,1.0] and [2.0,2.0]. All results are calculated as in Table 3. The “p-value diffmeans” is equivalent to the p-value reported in Table 3, which corresponds to a test of the sharp null hypothesis based on the difference-in-means test statistic. The two additional p-values reported correspond to a test of the sharp-null hypothesis based on the two additional test statistics described above. All p-values less than or equal to 0.05 are shown in bold in the table.

There are important differences between our two outcomes. The results in Design I (Panel A) are robust to the choice of the test statistic in the originally chosen [0.75,0.75] window and in the smaller [0.50,0.50] window. The results are also insensitive to increasing the window, as seen in the last two columns of Panel A. In contrast, the null results found in Design II seem more fragile. First, the sharp null hypothesis is rejected in some larger windows when alternative test statistics are considered. Second, in our chosen window, the sharp null hypothesis is rejected with the linear regression test statistic, but not with the quadratic regression test statistic. As we showed before in Table 3 and reproduce in Table 4, this does not translate into a statistically significant constant or quantile treatment effect – all confidence intervals are roughly centered around zero. An interesting phenomenon that might explain this pattern occurs when we consider the smaller [0.5,0.5] window. In this window, the point estimate and confidence intervals show a negative effect and provide support for the opposite-party advantage hypothesis. The Hodges–Lehmann point estimate is about –8 percentage points, more than a 10-fold increase in absolute value with respect to the conventional estimates, and we reject the sharp null hypothesis of no effect at the 5% level with two of the three different test statistics considered. Our randomization-based confidence interval of the constant treatment effect ranges from –16.66 to –0.08, ruling out a non-negative effect. The confidence interval for the 25th quantile treatment effect also excludes zero and again provides support for the opposite-party advantage.

Table 4

Sensitivity of randomization-based RD results: incumbent-party and opposite-party advantages in the U.S. Senate for different window choices

A. Design I (outcome = Dem Vote Share at t+2)
WindowSmaller windowChosen WindowLarger Windows
[–0.50, 0.50][–0.75, 0.75][–1.00, 1.00][–2.00, 2.00]
Point estimate10.169.329.618.90
p-value diffmeans0.00370.00040.00000.0000
p-value linear0.00010.00000.00000.0000
p-value quadratic0.00890.00000.00000.0000
Treatment effect CI[3.62, 17.14][4.60, 14.78][5.85, 15.17][6.38, 13.98]
0.25-QTE CI[–2.75, 19.42][–2.00, 21.12][4.13, 21.25][4.88, 18.57]
0.75-QTE CI[1.93, 17.87][3.68, 18.94][1.78, 17.53][0.42, 13.69]
Sample size treated14222547
Sample size control9151849
B. Design II (outcome = Dem Vote Share at t+1)
WindowSmaller windowChosen WindowLarger Windows
[–0.50, 0.50][–0.75, 0.75][–1.00, 1.00][–2.00, 2.00]
Point estimate–8.17–0.792.320.56
p-value diffmeans0.04790.62280.50930.7252
p-value linear0.64550.00000.00000.2876
p-value quadratic0.01160.72970.48350.0599
Treatment effect CI[–16.66, –0.08][–8.25, 5.03][–4.89, 9.66][–3.87, 5.60]
0.25-QTE CI[–13.82, –0.16][–8.75, 9.96][–8.63, 14.65][–4.14, 4.85]
0.75-QTE CI[–25.92, 12.63][–11.15, 11.31][–10.72, 16.23][–8.26, 12.63]
Sample size treated15232750
Sample size control9151849

To investigate this issue further, Figure 3 plots the empirical cumulative distribution functions (ECDF) of our two outcomes in two different windows: the small [0.5,0.5] window and the window defined by [0.75,0.50)(0.5,0.75]. The union of these two windows is our chosen [0.75,0.75] window. Figure 3(a) shows that for Democratic Vote Share t+2, the ECDF of the treatment group is shifted to the right of the ECDF of the control group everywhere in both windows, showing that the treated quantiles are larger than the control quantiles. Since the treated outcome dominates the control outcome in both windows, combining the observations into our chosen window produces the robust incumbent-party advantage results that we see in the first two columns of Table 4.

In contrast, for Democratic Vote Share t+1, the outcome in Design I, the smaller [0.5,0.5] window exhibits a very different pattern from the [0.75,0.50)(0.5,0.75] window. The left plot in Figure 3(b) shows that the ECDF of the control group is shifted to the right of the ECDF of the treatment group everywhere, showing support for the negative effect (opposite-party advantage) reported in the first column of Table 4. But the right plot in Figure 3(b) shows that this situation reverses in the window [0.75,0.50)(0.5,0.75], where treated quantiles are larger than control quantiles almost everywhere. The combination of the observations in both windows is what produces the null effects in our chosen [0.75,0.75] window. In sum, the results in [0.5,0.5] suggest some support for the opposite-party advantage and show that our chosen window combines possibly heterogeneous treatment effects for Vote Share t+1 (but not for Vote Share t+2).

All in all, our sensitivity and robustness analysis in this section shows that the incumbent-party advantage results are robust but our opposite-party advantage results are more fragile and suggest some avenues for future research.

Figure 3 Empirical CDFs of outcomes for treated and control in different windows – U.S. Senate elections, 1914–2010. (a) Democratic vote share at t + 2. (b) Democratic vote share at t + 1
Figure 3

Empirical CDFs of outcomes for treated and control in different windows – U.S. Senate elections, 1914–2010. (a) Democratic vote share at t + 2. (b) Democratic vote share at t + 1

6 Extensions, applications and discussion

We introduced a framework to analyze regression discontinuity designs employing a “local” randomization approach and proposed using randomization inference techniques to conduct finite-sample exact inference. In this section, we discuss five natural extensions focusing on fuzzy RD designs, discrete-valued and multiple running variables, matching techniques and sensitivity analysis. In addition, we discuss a connection between our approach and the conventional large-sample RD approach.

6.1 Fuzzy RD with possibly weak instruments

In the sharp RD design, treatment assignment is equal to Zi=1(Rir0), and treatment assignment is equal to actual treatment status. In the fuzzy design, treatment status Di, with observations collected in n-vector D as above, is not completely determined by placement relative to r0, so Di may differ from Zi. Our framework extends directly to the fuzzy RD designs, offering a robust inference alternative to the traditional approaches when the instrument (i.e., the relationship between Di and Zi) is regarded as “weak”.

Let di(r) be unit i’s potential treatment status when the vector of scores is R=r. Similarly, we let yi(r,d) be unit i’s potential outcome when the vector of scores is R=r and the treatment status vector is D=d. Observed treatment status and outcomes are Di=di(R) and Yi=yi(R,D). This generalization leads to a framework analogous to an experiment with non-compliance, where Zi is used as an instrument for Di and randomization-based inferences are based on the distribution of Zi. Assumption 1 generalizes as follows.

Assumption 1′: Local randomized experiment. There exists a neighborhood W0=[r_,rˉ] with r_<r0<rˉ such that for all i with RiW0:

(a)FRi|RiW0(r)=F(r), and

(b)di(r)=di(zW0) and yi(r,d)=yi(zW0,dW0) for all r,d.

This assumption permits testing the null hypothesis of no effect exactly as described above, although the interpretation of the test differs, as now it can only be considered a test of no effect of treatment among those units whose potential treatment status di(zW0) varies with zW0. Constructing confidence intervals and point estimates in the fuzzy design requires generalizing Assumption 2 and introducing an additional assumption.

Assumption 2′: Local SUTVA (LSUTVA). For all i with RiW0:

(a)If zi=z˜i, then di(zW0)=di(z˜W0), and

(b)If zi=z˜i and di=d˜i, then yi(zW0,dW0)=yi(z˜W0,d˜W0).

Assumption 6: Local exclusion restriction. For all i with RiW0: yi(z,d)=yi(z˜,d) for all (z,z˜) and for all d.

Assumption 6 means potential responses depend on placement with respect to the threshold only through its effect on treatment status. Under assumptions 12 and Assumption 6, we can write potential responses within the window as yi(z,d)=yi(di). Furthermore, under the constant treatment effect model in Assumption 3, estimation and inference proceeds exactly as before, but defining the adjusted responses as YW0τ0DW0. Inference on quantiles in the fuzzy design also requires a monotonicity assumption (e.g., Frandsen et al. [33]).

Fuzzy RD designs are local versions of the usual instrumental variables (IV) model and thus concerns about weak instruments may arise in this context as well [34]. Our randomization inference framework, however, circumvents this concern because it enables us to conduct exact finite-sample inference, as discussed in Imbens and Rosenbaum [10] for the usual IV setting. Therefore, our framework also offers an alternative, robust inference approach for fuzzy RD designs under possibly weak instruments.

6.2 Discrete and multiple running variables

Another feature of our framework is that it can handle RD settings where the running variable is not univariate and continuous. Our results provide an alternative inference approach when the running variable is discrete or has mass points in its support (see, for example Lee and Card [35]). While conventional, nonparametric smoothing techniques are usually unable to handle this case without appropriate technical modifications, our randomization inference approach applies immediately to this case and offers researchers a fully data-driven approach for inference when the running variable is not continuously distributed. Similarly, our approach extends naturally to settings where multiple running variables are present (see, e.g., Keele and Titiunik [36] and references therein). For example, in geographic RD designs, which involve two running variables, Keele et al. [37] discuss how the methodological framework introduced herein can be used to conduct inference employing geographic RD variation.

6.3 Matching and parametric modeling

Conventional approaches to RD employ continuity of the running variable and large-sample approximations, and typically do not emphasize the role of covariates and parametric modeling, relying instead on nonparametric smoothing techniques local to the discontinuity. However, in practice, researchers often incorporate covariates and employ parametric models in a “small” neighborhood around the cutoff when conducting inference. Our framework gives a formal justification (i.e., “local randomization”) and an alternative inference approach (i.e., randomization inference) for this common empirical practice. For example, our approach can be used to justify (finite-sample exact) inference in RD contexts using panel or longitudinal data, specifying nonlinear models or relying on flexible “matching” on covariates techniques. For a recent example of such an approach, see Keele et al. [37].

6.4 Sensitivity analysis and related techniques

In the context of randomization-based inference, a useful tool to asses the plausibility of the results is a sensitivity analysis that considers how the results vary under deviations from the randomization assumption. Rosenbaum [14, 15] provides details of such an approach when the treatment is assumed to be randomly assigned conditionally on covariates. Under a randomization-type assumption, the probability of receiving treatment is equal for treated and control units; a sensitivity analysis proposes a model for the odds of receiving treatment and allows the probability of receiving treatment to differ between groups and recalculates the p-values, confidence intervals or point estimates of interest. The analysis asks whether small departures from the randomization-type assumption would alter the conclusions from the study. If, for example, small differences in the probability of receiving treatment between treatment and control units lead to markedly different conclusions (i.e., if the null hypothesis of no effect is initially rejected but then ceases to be rejected), then we conclude that the results are sensitive and appropriately temper our confidence in the results. This kind of analysis could be directly applied in our context inside W0. In this window, our assumption is that the probability of receiving treatment is equal for all units (and that we can estimate such probability); thus, a sensitivity analysis of this type could be applied directly to establish whether our conclusions survive under progressively different probabilities of receiving treatment for treated and control units inside W0.

6.5 Connection to standard RD setup

Our finite-sample RD inference framework may be regarded as an alternative approximation to the conventional RD identifying conditions in Hahn et al. [5]. This section defines a large-sample identification framework similar to the conventional one and discusses its connection to the finite-sample Assumption 1.

In the conventional RD setup, individuals have random potential outcomes Yi(r,d) which depend on the value of a running variable, r, and treatment status d{0,1}. The observed outcome is YiYi(Ri,Di), and identification is achieved by imposing continuity, near the cutoff r0, on E[Yi(r,d)|Ri=r] or FYi(r,d)|Ri=r(y)=Pr[Yi(r,d)y|Ri=r]. Consider the following alternative identifying condition.

Assumption 7: Conventional RD assumption. For all d{0,1} and i=1,2,,n:

(a)Ri is continuously distributed,

(b)Yi(r,d) is (a.s.) Lipschitz continuous in r at r0,

(c)FYi(r0,d)|Ri=r(y)=Pr[Yi(r0,d)y|Ri=r] is Lipschitz continuous in r at r0.

These conditions are very similar to those in Hahn et al. [5] and other (large-sample type) approaches to RD. The main difference is that we require continuity of potential outcome functions, as opposed to just continuity of the conditional expectation or distribution of potential outcomes. Continuity of the potential outcome functions rules out knife-edge cases where confounding differences in potential outcomes at the threshold (that is, discontinuities in Yi(r,d)) exactly offset sorting in the running variable at the threshold so that the conditional expectation of potential outcomes is still continuous at the threshold. In ruling out this knife-edge case, our condition is technically stronger, but arguably not stronger in substance, than conventional identifying conditions.

The conventional RD approach approximates the conditional distribution of outcomes near the threshold as locally linear and relies on large-sample asymptotics for inference. Our approach proposes an alternative local constant approximation and uses finite-sample inference techniques. The local linear approximation may be more accurate than local constant farther from the threshold but the large-sample sample approximations may be poor. The local constant approximation will likely be appropriate only very near the threshold, but the inference will remain valid for small samples. The following suggests that our finite-sample condition in Assumption 1 can be seen as an approximation obtained from the more conventional RD identifying conditions given in Assumption 7, with an approximation error that is controlled by the window width.

Result 1: connection between RD frameworks. Suppose Assumption 7 holds. Then:

(i)FRi|Ri[r_,rˉ],Yi(r0,d)=y(r)=FRi|Ri[r_,rˉ](r)+Oas(rˉr_), and

(ii)Yi(r,d)=Yi(r0,d)+Oas(rˉr_).

Part (i) of this result says that the running variable is approximately independent of potential outcomes near the threshold, or, in the finite-sample framework where potential outcomes are fixed, each unit’s running variable has approximately the same distribution (under i.i.d. sampling). This corresponds to part (a) of Assumption 1 (Local Randomization) and gives a formal connection between the usual RD framework and our randomization-inference framework. Similarly, part (ii) implies that potential outcomes depend approximately on treatment status only near the threshold r0, as assumed in Assumption 1(b).

7 Conclusion

Motivated by the interpretation of regression discontinuity designs as local experiments, we proposed a randomization inference framework to conduct exact finite-sample inference in this design. Our approach is especially useful when only a few observations are available in the neighborhood of the cutoff where local randomization is plausible. Our randomization-based methodology can be used both for validating (and even selecting) this window around the RD threshold and performing statistical inference about the effects in this window. Our analysis of party-level advantages in U.S. Senate elections illustrated our methodology and showed that a randomization-based analysis can lead to different conclusions from standard RD methods based on large-sample approximations.

We envision our approach as complementary to existing parametric and nonparametric methods for the analysis of RD designs. Employing our proposed methodological approach, scholars can provide evidence about the plausibility of the as-good-as-random interpretation of their RD designs, and also conduct exact finite-sample inference employing only those few observations very close to the RD cutoff. If even in a small window around the cutoff the sharp null hypothesis of no effect is rejected for predetermined covariates, scholars should not rely on the local randomization interpretation of their designs, and hence should pay special attention to the plausibility of the continuity assumptions imposed by the standard approach.

Acknowledgments

We thank the co-Editor, Kosuke Imai, three anonymous referees, Peter Aronow, Jake Bowers, Devin Caughey, Andrew Feher, Don Green, Luke Keele, Jasjeet Sekhon, and participants at the 2010 Political Methodology Meeting in the University of Iowa and at the 2012 Political Methodology Seminar in Princeton University for valuable comments and suggestions. Previous versions of this manuscript were circulated under the titles “Randomization Inference in the Regression Discontinuity Design” and “Randomization Inference in the Regression Discontinuity Design to Study the Incumbency Advantage in the U.S. Senate” (first draft: July, 2010). Cattaneo and Titiunik gratefully acknowledge financial support from the National Science Foundation (SES 1357561).

References

1. ThistlethwaiteDL, CampbellDT. Regression-discontinuity analysis: an alternative to the ex-post facto experiment. J Educ Psychol1960;51:30917.10.1037/h0044319Search in Google Scholar

2. ImbensG, LemieuxT. Regression discontinuity designs: a guide to practice. J Econometrics2008;142:61535.10.1016/j.jeconom.2007.05.001Search in Google Scholar

3. LeeDS, LemieuxT. Regression discontinuity designs in economics. J Econ Lit2010;48:281355.10.1257/jel.48.2.281Search in Google Scholar

4. DinardoJ, LeeDS. Program evaluation and research designs. In: AshenfelterO, CardD, editors. Handbook of labor economics, vol. 4A. Amsterdam, Netherlands: Elsevier Science B.V., 2011:463536.Search in Google Scholar

5. HahnJ, ToddP, van der KlaauwW. Identification and estimation of treatment effects with a regression-discontinuity design. Econometrica2001;69:20109.10.1111/1468-0262.00183Search in Google Scholar

6. PorterJ. Estimation in the regression discontinuity model. Working paper, University of Wisconsin, 2003.Search in Google Scholar

7. ImbensGW, KalyanaramanK. Optimal bandwidth choice for the regression discontinuity estimator. Rev Econ Stud2012;79:93359.10.1093/restud/rdr043Search in Google Scholar

8. CalonicoS, CattaneoMD, TitiunikR. Robust nonparametric confidence intervals for regression-discontinuity designs. Econometrica2014.10.3982/ECTA11757Search in Google Scholar

9. LeeDS. Randomized experiments from non-random selection in U.S. house elections. J Econometrics2008;142:67597.10.1016/j.jeconom.2007.05.004Search in Google Scholar

10. ImbensGW, RosenbaumP. Robust, accurate confidence intervals with a weak instrument: quarter of birth and education. J R Stat Soc Ser A2005;168:10926.10.1111/j.1467-985X.2004.00339.xSearch in Google Scholar

11. HoDE, ImaiK. Randomization inference with natural experiments: an analysis of ballot effects in the 2003 election. J Am Stat Assoc2006;101:888900.10.1198/016214505000001258Search in Google Scholar

12. BarriosT, DiamondR, ImbensGW, KolesarM. Clustering, spatial correlations and randomization inference. J Am Stat Assoc2012;107:57891.10.1080/01621459.2012.682524Search in Google Scholar

13. HansenBB, BowersJ. Attributing effects to a cluster randomized get-out-the-vote campaign. J Am Stat Assoc2009;104:87385.10.1198/jasa.2009.ap06589Search in Google Scholar

14. RosenbaumPR. Observational studies, 2nd ed. New York: Springer, 2002.10.1007/978-1-4757-3692-2Search in Google Scholar

15. RosenbaumPR. Design of observational studies. New York: Springer, 2010.10.1007/978-1-4419-1213-8Search in Google Scholar

16. ButlerD, ButlerM. Splitting the difference? Causal inference and theories of split-party delegations. Pol Anal2006;14:43955.10.1093/pan/mpj010Search in Google Scholar

17. HollandPW. Statistics and causal inference. J Am Stat Assoc1986;81:94560.10.1080/01621459.1986.10478354Search in Google Scholar

18. WellekS. Testing statistical hypotheses of equivalence and noninferiority, 2nd ed. Boca Raton, FL: Chapman & Hall/CRC, 2010.10.1201/EBK1439808184Search in Google Scholar

19. LehmannEL. Nonparametrics: statistical methods based on ranks. New York: Springer, 2006.Search in Google Scholar

20. EfronB. Large-scale inference. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge, 2010.Search in Google Scholar

21. CraiuRV, SunL. Choosing the lesser evil: trade-off between false discovery rate and non-discovery rate. Stat Sin2008;18:86179.Search in Google Scholar

22. EriksonRS. The advantage of incumbency in congressional elections. Polity1971;3:395405.10.2307/3234117Search in Google Scholar

23. GelmanA, KingG. Estimating incumbency advantage without bias. Am J Pol Sci1990;34:114264.10.2307/2111475Search in Google Scholar

24. AnsolabehereS, SnyderJM. The incumbency advantage in U.S. Elections: an analysis of state and federal offices, 1942–2000. Election Law J: Rules, Pol Policy2002;1:31538.10.1089/153312902760137578Search in Google Scholar

25. EriksonR, TitiunikR. Using regression discontinuity to uncover the personal incumbency advantage. Working Paper, University of Michigan, 2014.Search in Google Scholar

26. CaugheyD, SekhonJS. Elections and the regression-discontinuity design: lessons from close U.S. House races, 1942–2008. Pol Anal2011;19:385408.10.1093/pan/mpr032Search in Google Scholar

27. AlesinaA, FiorinaM, RosenthalH. Why are there so many divided senate delegations? National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 3663, 1991.10.3386/w3663Search in Google Scholar

28. JungG-R, KennyLW, LottJR. An explanation for why senators from the same state vote differently so frequently. J Public Econ1994;54:6596.10.1016/0047-2727(94)90071-XSearch in Google Scholar

29. SeguraGM, NicholsonSP. Sequential choices and partisan transitions in U.S. senate delegations: 1972–1988. J Polit1995;57:86100.10.2307/2960272Search in Google Scholar

30. McCraryJ. Manipulation of the running variable in the regression discontinuity design: a density test. J Econometrics2008;142:698714.10.1016/j.jeconom.2007.05.005Search in Google Scholar

31. CalonicoS, CattaneoMD, TitiunikR. Robust data-driven inference in the regression-discontinuity design. Stata J2014.10.1177/1536867X1401400413Search in Google Scholar

32. CalonicoS, CattaneoMD, TitiunikR. Rdrobust: an R package for robust inference in regression-discontinuity designs. Working paper, University of Michigan, 2014.10.32614/RJ-2015-004Search in Google Scholar

33. FrandsenB, FrölichM, MellyB. Quantile treatments effects in the regression discontinuity design. J Econometrics2012;168:38295.10.1016/j.jeconom.2012.02.004Search in Google Scholar

34. MarmerV, FeirD, LemieuxT. Weak identification in fuzzy regression discontinuity designs. Working paper, University of British Columbia, 2014.Search in Google Scholar

35. LeeDS, CardD. Regression discontinuity inference with specification error. J Econometrics2008;142:65574.10.1016/j.jeconom.2007.05.003Search in Google Scholar

36. KeeleL, TitiunikR. Geographic boundaries as regression discontinuities. Pol Anal2014.Search in Google Scholar

37. KeeleL, TitiunikR, ZubizarretaJ. Enhancing a geographic regression discontinuity design through matching to estimate the effect of ballot initiatives on voter turnout. J R Stat Soc Ser A2014.10.1111/rssa.12056Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2014-7-11
Published in Print: 2015-3-1

©2015 by De Gruyter

Downloaded on 30.4.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/jci-2013-0010/html
Scroll to top button