Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

A Harris-Todaro agent-based model to rural-urban migration

Abstract

The Harris-Todaro model of the rural-urban migration process is revisited under an agent-based approach. The migration of the workers is interpreted as a process of social learning by imitation, formalized by a computational model. By simulating this model, we observe a transitional dynamics with continuous growth of the urban fraction of overall population toward an equilibrium. Such an equilibrium is characterized by stabilization of rural-urban expected wages differential (generalized Harris-Todaro equilibrium condition), urban concentration and urban unemployment. These classic results obtained originally by Harris and Todaro are emergent properties of our model.

Agent-based model; Harris-Todaro model; Econophysics; Complex system


A Harris-Todaro agent-based model to rural-urban migration

Aquino L. EspíndolaI; Jaylson J. SilveiraII; T. J. P. PennaIII

IInstituto de Física, Universidade Federal Fluminense 24.210-340, Niterói, RJ, Brazil

IIDepto de Economia, Universidade Estadual Paulista - UNESP 14.800-901, Araraquara, SP, Brazil

IIIInstituto de Física, Universidade Federal Fluminense 24.210-340, Niterói, RJ, Brazil

ABSTRACT

The Harris-Todaro model of the rural-urban migration process is revisited under an agent-based approach. The migration of the workers is interpreted as a process of social learning by imitation, formalized by a computational model. By simulating this model, we observe a transitional dynamics with continuous growth of the urban fraction of overall population toward an equilibrium. Such an equilibrium is characterized by stabilization of rural-urban expected wages differential (generalized Harris-Todaro equilibrium condition), urban concentration and urban unemployment. These classic results obtained originally by Harris and Todaro are emergent properties of our model.

Keywords: Agent-based model; Harris-Todaro model; Econophysics; Complex system

I. INTRODUCTION

In this paper we turn upon the seminal Harris and Todaro [1] work, which together with Todaro [2] is considered one of the starting points of the classic rural-urban migration theory [3]. The hypothesis and predictions of Harris-Todaro model have been subjected to econometric evaluation and have been corroborated by several studies [4-7]. The key hypothesis of Harris and Todaro are that migrants react mainly to economic incentives, earnings differentials, and the probability of getting a job at the destination have influence on the migraton decision. In other words, these authors posit that rural-urban migration will occur while the urban expected wage [12] exceed the rural wage. From this crucial assumption, as denominated by Harris-Todaro [1], is deduced that the migratory dynamics leads the economic system toward an equilibrium with urban concentration and high urban unemployment.

In our previous works [8,9] we analyzed the rural-urban migration by means of an agent-based computational model taking into account the influence of the neighborhood in the migration decision. The inclusion of the influence of neighbors was done via an Ising like model. The economic analogous to the external field in the Ising hamiltonian was the differential of expected wages between urban and rural sectors. Therefore, in theses works [8,9] the crucial assumption of Harris and Todaro were taken for granted.

Now, we are motivated by the following question: can the crucial assumption and equilibrium with urban concentration and urban unemployment obtained from the original Harris-Todaro model be generated as emergent properties from the interaction among adaptative agents? In order to answer this question we implemented an agent-based computational model in which workers grope for best sectorial location over time in terms of earnings. The economic system simulated is characterized by the assumption originally made by Harris and Todaro.

The paper is arranged as follows. Section describes the analytical Harris-Todaro model showing its basic equilibrium properties. In Section we present the implementation of the computational model via an agent-based simulation and compare its aggregate regularities with the analytical equilibrium properties. Section shows concluding remarks.

II. THE HARRIS-TODARO MODEL

A. Assumptions

Harris and Todaro [1] studied the migration of workers in a two-sector economic system, namely, rural sector and urban sector. The difference between these sectors are the type of goods produced, the technology of production and the process of wage determination. The rural sector is specialized in the production of agricultural goods. The productive process of this sector can be described by a Cobb-Douglas production function:

where Ya is the production level of the agricultural good, Na is the amount of workers used in the agricultural production, Aa > 0 and 0 < f < 1 are parametric constants.

Similarly, the urban sector also has its productive process described as Cobb-Douglas production function:[13]

where Ym is the production level of the manufactured good, Nm is the quantity of workers employed in the production of manufactured goods, Am > 0 and 0 < a < 1 are parametric constants.[14]

Both goods and labor markets are perfectly competitive. Nevertheless, there is segmentation in the labor market due to a high minimum urban wage politically determined.

In the rural sector, the real wage, perfectly flexible, is equal to the marginal productivity of labor in this sector:[15]

where wa is the real wage and p is the price of the agricultural good, both expressed in units of manufactured good.

In the urban sector, a minimum wage, wm, is assumed fixed institutionally at a level above equilibrium in this labor market. It can be formalized as [16]

where Nu is the amount of workers in the urban sector.

The relative price of the agricultural good in terms of the manufactured good, p, varies according to the relative scarcity between agricultural and manufacturated goods. Then,[17]

where r > 0 and g > 0 are a parametric constants. g is the elasticity of p with respect to the ratio Ym/Ya.

The overall population of workers in the economy is N, which is kept constant during the whole period of analysis. By assumption there are only two sectors and rural prices are wholly flexible, which implies that there is full employment in the rural area, i.e., all workers living at the rural sector are employed at any period. Then at any period the following equality is verified:

B. Temporary Equilibrium

Given a parametric constant vector (Aa,Am,f,a,r,g), an initial urban population Nu, and a minimum wage wm one can calculate the temporary equilibrium of the economic system by using eqs. (1 - 6).

From eq. (4) one can find the employment level at the manufacturing sector

Replacing eq. (7) in eq. (2) we get the production level of the manufacturing sector

From eq. (6) one can obtain the relation

which is used with eq. (1) to obtain the agricultural production

By using eqs. (5), (8) and (10) the terms of trade are determined

Finally, by using eqs. (3), (9) and (11), the rural wage in units of manufacturated good is obtained

In sum, the vector (Nm,Ym,Na,Ya,p,wa) configures a temporary equilibrium that might be altered whether occurs a migration of workers, induced by the differential of sectorial wages, which changes the sectorial distribution of overall population.

C. The Long Run Equilibrium

Harris and Todaro, in determining the long run equilibrium, i.e., the absence of a net rural-urban migratory flow, argue that the rural workers, in their decision on migrating to the urban area, estimate the expected urban wage, , defined as:

The ratio Nm/Nu, which is the employment rate, is an estimative of the probability that a worker living at urban sector gets a job in this sector.

As mentioned before, the key assumption of the model of Harris and Todaro is that there will be a migratory flow from the rural to the urban sector while the expected urban wage is higher than the rural wage. Thus, the long run equilibrium is attained when the urban worker population reaches a level such that the expected urban wage equates the rural wage:

This equality is known in the economic literature as the Harris-Todaro condition. Harris and Todaro argue that the differential of expected wages in eq. (14) can be a constant value d ¹ 0. When this differential reaches d, the net migration ceases. This generalized Harris-Todaro condition can be expressed as follows:

The level of the urban population that satisfies the eq. (15), i.e., the equilibrium urban share = /N, is determined from the solution of the equation resulting from substitution of equations (12), (13) in eq. (15):

The solution of eq. (16) is parametrized by the vector (Aa,Am,r,g,a,f,wm).

Harris and Todaro [1], in order to evaluate the stability of the long run equilibrium, postulate a mechanism of adjustment that is based on the following function of sign preservation:

The differential equation that governs the state transition in the model of Harris and Todaro is obtained by replacing equations (12), (13) in eq. (17). Based on this postulated adjustment process, Harris and Todaro [1] show that the long run equilibrium is globally asymptotically stable. This means that the economy would tend to long run equilibrium with unemployment in the urban sector generated by the presence of a relatively high minimum wage for all possible initial conditions. From now on we will refer to the long run equilibrium simply as equilibrium.

Based on the numerical solutions of eq. (16) one can evaluate the impact that the variation of the minimum wage and the elasticity of the terms of trade on the equilibrium. In Fig. 1 we see that under the hypothesis of a Cobb-Douglas technology, the equilibrium urban share, , does not depend on the minimum wage wm. However, changes in the value of wm reduces the labor demand on the manufacturing sector what results in higher unemployment rates in the equilibrium.


In turn, as seen in Fig. 2, changes in the elasticity of the terms of trade alter slightly the equilibrium urban share and unemployment rate. A net migration toward urban sector shift the terms of trade to higher values. The greater g the greater this shift, what cause an increase in the rural wage in units of manufacturing good, becoming the urban sector less attractive.


III. HARRIS-TODARO AGENT-BASED MODEL

In this section we describe the implementation of the computational model we proposed, as well as the aggregate patterns obtained numerically and the comparison with the respective analytical results.

A. Computational Implementation

Initially, workers are randomly placed in a square lattice with linear dimension L = 500. The reference values of the parameters used for these simulations are the same done to evaluate the equilibrium of the Harris-Todaro model, namely, Aa = 1.0, Am = 1.0, f = 0.3, a = 0.7, r = 1.0 and g = 1.0. The value of the minimum wage used is wm = 0.8 and the initial urban fraction of the total population is nu = 0.2, where nu = Nu/N is the normalized urban population also called urban share. The initial value nu = 0.2 is in agreement with historical data of developing economies. Given these parameters, one can calculate the vector which characterizes temporary equilibrium of the system by using eqs. (7 - 12).

By using eq. (7), the employment level of the urban sector, Nm, is obtained. If nu < Nm/N all workers in the urban sector are employed and each individual i earns the wage given by the manufacturing marginal productivity, wi = aAm. Otherwise, nu > Nm/N there will be a fraction of Nm/Nu workers employed, which earn the minimum wage, wi = wm, and (1-Nm/Nu) workers unemployed, which earn a wage wi = 0.

Each worker can be selected to review his sectorial location with probability a, called activity [11]. Therefore, in each time step only a fraction of workers becomes potential migrants, going through the sectorial location reviewing process. Potential migrants will determine their satisfaction level of being in the current sector by comparing their earnings, wi, among nearest neighbors.

The potential migrant starts the comparison process with a initial satisfaction level si = 0. When wi > wneighbor the satisfaction level si is added in one unit; if wi< wneighbor, si is diminished in one unit; if wi = wneighbor, si does not change. After the worker has passed through the reviewing process his/her satisfaction level is checked. The migration will occur only if si < 0, what means that the worker's i earnings is less than the most of his/her nearest neighbors.

After all the potential migrants complete the reviewing process and have decided migrate or not, a new configuration of the system is set. Therefore, once again a new temporary equilibrium of the system is calculated by using eqs. (8 - 12). The whole procedure is repeated until a pre-set number of steps is reached. It is important to emphasize that Nm is kept constant throughout the simulation. Its given by eq. (7) which depends on the technological parameters, a,Am, and the minimum wage, wm, which are constants too.

B. Analysis of the Emergent Properties

In this section we develop the analysis of the long run aggregate regularities of Harris-Todaro agent-based computational model. These long run properties will be compared between the solution of the analytical model and simulations we ran.

Figures 3, 4 and 5 show the basic characteristics of the transitional dynamics and long run equilibrium generated by simulations. When the economic system has a low initial urban share, nu = 0:2 or nu = 0:3, there is a net migration toward urban sector. This migration takes the urban sector from a full employment situation to an unemployment one. The positive differential of expected wages that pulls workers to the urban sector diminishes. However, if the economic system initiates with a high urban share, nu = 0:8, or nu = 0:9 there is net flow of migration toward rural sector in such a way that the unemployment rate of the urban sector decreases.




In this case, the differential of expected wages is negative. In an economy mainly rural (nu < 0:5), the transitional dynamics characterized by a continuous growth of population of the urban sector with a differential of expected wages relatively high is followed by the stabilization of rural-urban differential of expected wages. In other words, the generalized Harris-Todaro condition, eq. (15), arises as a long run equilibrium result of the agent-based migratory dynamics.

Figure 3 also shows that even after the urban share has reached an stable average value, there are small fluctuations around this average. Therefore, differently from the original Harris-Todaro model, our computational model shows in the long run equilibrium the reverse migration. This phenomenon has been observed in several developing countries as remarked in Ref. [10].

In Figures 6, 7 and 8 one can see that for a given value of a, the variation of wm practically does not change the equilibrium values of the urban share, the differential of expected wages and the unemployment rate. However, for a given wm, higher values of a make the urban sector less attractive due the reduction of the employment level. This causes a lower equilibrium urban share, a higher unemployment rate and a gap in the convergence of the expected wages.




In Figures 9, 10 and 11 can be seen that for a fixed value of g, the equilibrium values of the urban share, the differential of expected wages and unemployment rate do not have a strong dependence with wm. However, variations in g for a fixedwm, dramatically change the equilibrium values of the variable mentioned before. Higher values of g generate a lower urban concentration, a higher gap in the expected wages and a higher unemployment rate in the equilibrium.




Finally, in Fig. 12 is shown that the convergence of migratory dynamics for a urban share, compatible with historical data, is robust in relation to the variation of the key technological parameters, a and f. The impact of the variation of these parameters in the values of the equilibrium differential of expected wages, ( - wa), and the equilibrium urban unemployment rate, (1-Nm=Nu) can be seen in Fig. 13 and 14, respectively.




IV. CONCLUSION

In this paper we developed and agent-based computational model which formalizes the rural-urban allocation of workers as a process of social learning by imitation. We analyze a two-sectorial economy composed by adaptative agents, i.e., individuals that grope over time for best sectorial location in terms of earnings. This search is a process of imitation of successful neighbor agents.

The dispersed and non-coordinated individual migration decisions, made based on local information, generate aggregate regularities. Firstly, the crucial assumption of Harris and Todaro, the principle that rural-urban migration will occur while the urban expected wage exceed the rural wage, comes out as spontaneous upshot of interaction among adaptative agents.

Secondly, the migratory dynamics generated by agents that seek to adaptate to the economic environment that they co-create leads the economy toward a long run equilibrium characterized by urban concentration with urban unemployment. When this long run equilibrium is reached, the generalized Harris-Todaro condition is satisfied, i.e., there is a stabilization of the rural-urban expected wage differential.

Thirdly, the impact of the minimum wage and elasticity of terms of trade in a long run equilibrium obtained by simulations are in agreement with the predictions of the original Harris-Todaro model with Cobb-Douglas technology.

Finally, the simulations showed an aggregated pattern not found in the original Harris-Todaro model. There is the possibility of small fluctuations of the urban share around an average value. This phenomenon is known as reverse migration.

Acknowledgments

Aquino L. Espíndola thanks CAPES for the financial support. Jaylson J. Silveira acknowledges research grants from CNPq. T. J. P. Penna thanks CNPq for the fellowship.

[12] The urban sector wage times the probability of getting a job in this sector.

[13] Harris and Todaro set their model using sectorial production function with general functional form, i.e., in each sector i, Yi= fi(Ni) with i(Ni) > 0 and f¢¢i (Ni) < 0. Except where it is indicated, the results presented in this section are valid for this general case. The Cobb-Douglas form is a standard assumption about technology.

[14] The endowment of land of the rural sector and the stocks of capital of both sectors are given for the period of analysis.

[15] This marginal product is the derivative of the agricultural production function, eq. (1), with respect to Na multiplied by p.

[16] The right-hand side of this equation is the marginal productivity of the manufacturing labor, i.e., the derivative of manufacturing production function, eq. (2), with respect to Nm.

[17] Actually, Harris and Todaro worked with a general form, r denotes a function in their paper not a constant value as used by us.

Received on 6 September, 2005

  • [1] J. R. Harris and M. P. Todaro, American Economic Review 60, 126 (1970).
  • [2] M. P. Todaro, American Economic Review 59, 138 (1969).
  • [3] D. Ray, Development Economics (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1998).
  • [4] L. Y. L. Yap, Journal of Development Economics 4, 239 (1977).
  • [5] D. Mazumdar, Rural-urban Migration in Developing countries. In: Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, Elsevier, Amsterdam, 1987.
  • [6] L. Ghatak, P. Levine, and S. Price, Journal of Economics Surveys 10, 159 (1996).
  • [7] J. G. Willianson, Migration and Urbanization. In: Chenery, H. and Srinivasan, T.N., Handbook of developments economics, Elsevier, Amsterdam, 1988.
  • [8] J. J. Silveira, A. L. Espíndola, and T. J. P. Penna, physics/0506021, Physica A, to appear.
  • [9] A. L. Espíndola, T. J. P. Penna, J. J. Silveira, forthcoming International Journal of Modern Physics C 16, issue 12 (2005).
  • [10] R. H. Day et al, The Economic Journal 97, 940 (1987).
  • [11] D. Stauffer and T. J. P. Penna, Physica A 256, 284 (1998).

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    16 Oct 2006
  • Date of issue
    Sept 2006

History

  • Received
    06 July 2005
Sociedade Brasileira de Física Caixa Postal 66328, 05315-970 São Paulo SP - Brazil, Tel.: +55 11 3091-6922, Fax: (55 11) 3816-2063 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
E-mail: sbfisica@sbfisica.org.br