Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-gtxcr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T17:07:42.670Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Costs of Coalition: Coalition Theories and Italian Governments

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Carol Mershon*
Affiliation:
University of Virginia

Abstract

Governments in Italy both change and remain the same. From 1946 to 1992 the Christian Democratic Party always held governing power. But almost no cabinet stayed in office more than a few years, and many governments collapsed after only a few months. How can instability coexist with stability in this way? How can governments break up at such low cost and with so little effect on alternation? These questions are rooted in—but not resolved by—the available game-theoretic literature on coalitional behavior. My answer is that politicians' purposive actions can reduce the costs of coalition. I argue that the costs of making, breaking, and maintaining coalitions depend on political institutions and on the array of parties and voters in policy space. Institutional and spatial conditions structure politicians' opportunities and attempts to lower costs. Under some conditions, as I show, coalitions are cheap, and politicians can easily make coalitions even cheaper. The inference is that this framework comprehends both Italy's extremes and the degrees of stability found in other parliamentary democracies.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1996

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Allum, P.A. 1973. Italy—Republic without Government! New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Andeweg, Rudy B., and Bakema, Wilma. 1994. “The Netherlands: Ministers and Cabinet Policy.” In Cabinet Ministers and Parliamentary Government, ed. Laver, Michael and Shepsle, Kenneth A.. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert. 1970. Conflict of Interest: A Theory of Divergent Goals with Applications to Politics. Chicago: Markham.Google Scholar
Balboni, Enzo. 1988. “I nodi istituzionali di una difficile crisi di governo.” In Politico in Italia: I fatti dell'anno e le interpretazioni. Edizione '88, ed. Corbetta, Piergiorgio and Leonardi, Robert. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Baldassare, Antonio. 1985. “Le ‘performances’ del Parlamento italiano nell'ultimo quindicennio.” In Il sistema politico italiano, ed. Pasquino, Gianfranco. Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Barnes, Samuel. 1977. Representation in Italy: Institutionalized Tradition and Electoral Choice. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Barrera, Pietro. 1989. “La prima riforma istituzionale: la nuova disciplina dell'attività di governo.” In Politico in Italia. I fatti dell'anno e le interpretazioni. Edizione, '89, ed. Catanzaro, Raimondo and Nanetti, Raffaella Y.. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Browne, Eric C., and Franklin, Mark. 1973. “Coalition Payoffs in European Parliamentary Democracies.” American Political Science Review 67 (06):453–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browne, Eric C., Frendreis, John P., and Gleiber, Dennis W.. 1986. “The Process of Cabinet Dissolution: An Exponential Model of Duration and Stability in Western Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 30 (08):628–50.Google Scholar
Browne, Eric C., Frendreis, John P., and Gleiber, Dennis W.. 1988. “Contending Models of Cabinet Stability: Rejoinder.” American Political Science Review 82 (09):930–41.Google Scholar
Budge, Ian, and Keman, Hans. 1990. Parties and Democracy: Coalition Formation and Government Functioning in Twenty States. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Budge, Ian, Robertson, David, and Hearl, Derek, eds. 1987. Ideology, Strategy and Party Change: Spatial Analyses of Post-War Election Programmes in 19 Democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Caciagli, Mario. 1988. “Quante Italie? Persistenza e trasformazione delle culture politiche subnazionali.” Polis 2 (12):429–57.Google Scholar
Calise, Mauro, and Mannheimer, Renato. 1982. Govemanti in Italia. Un trentennio repubblicano, 1946–1976. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Casstevens, Thomas W. 1989. “The Circulation of Elites: A Review and Critique of a Class of Models.” American Journal of Political Science 33 (02):294317.Google Scholar
Cazzola, Franco. 1985. “Struttura e potere del Partito socialista italiano.” In Il sistema politico italiano, ed. Pasquino, Gianfranco. Bari: Laterza.Google Scholar
Cioffi-Revilla, Claudio. 1984. “The Political Reliability of Italian Governments: An Exponential Survival Model.” American Political Science Review 78 (06):318–37.Google Scholar
Della Porta, Donatella. 1993. “La capitale immorale: le tangenti di Milano.” In Politica in Italia. I fatti dell'anno e le interpretazioni. Edizione '93, ed. Hellman, Stephen and Pasquino, Gianfranco. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Della Sala, Vincent. 1987. “Governare per decreto. Il governo Craxi e l'uso dei decreti-legge.” In Politica in Italia. I fatti dell'anno e le interpretazioni. Edizione '87, ed. Corbetta, Piergiorgio and Leonardi, Robert. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
De Swaan, Abram. 1973. Coalition Theories and Cabinet Formations. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Di Palma, Giuseppe. 1977. Surviving without Governing. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Di Palma, Giuseppe. 1979. “The Available State: Problems of Reform.” West European Politics 2 (10):149–65.Google Scholar
Di Scala, Spencer M. 1988. Renewing Italian Socialism: Nenni to Craxi. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Dodd, Lawrence C. 1976. Coalitions in Parliamentary Government. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Dogan, Mattei. 1984. “Come si diventa ministro in Italia: le regole non scritte del gioco politico.” In Il sistema politico italiano tra crisi e innovazione, Centro studi P. Farneti. Milan: Franco Angeli.Google Scholar
Eulau, Heinz, and Lewis-Beck, Michael S., eds. 1985. Economic Conditions and Electoral Outcomes: The United States and Western Europe. New York: Agathon.Google Scholar
Farneti, Paolo. 1983. Il sistema deipartiti in Italia 1946–1979. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Franklin, Mark N., and Mackie, Thomas T.. 1983. “Familiarity and Inertia in the Formation of Governing Coalitions in Parliamentary Democracies.” British Journal of Political Science 13 (07):275–98.Google Scholar
Franklin, Mark N., and Mackie, Thomas T.. 1984. “Reassessing the Importance of Size and Ideology for the Formation of Governing Coalitions in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 28 (11):671–92.Google Scholar
Galli, Giorgio, and Prandi, Alfonso. 1970. Patterns of Political Participation in Italy. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Gladdish, Ken. 1991. Governing from the Centre: Politics and Policy-Making in the Netherlands. London/S'Gravenhage: Hurst/Sdu Uitgeverij.Google Scholar
Guarnieri, Carlo. 1989. “Strutture e processi decisionali.” In Scienza politica, ed. Morlino, Leonardo. Turin: Fondazione Giovanni Agnelli.Google Scholar
Hellman, Stephen. 1992. “Italian Politics in Transition.” In European Politics in Transition, 2d ed., ed. Kesselman, Mark and Krieger, Joel. New York: D.C. Heath.Google Scholar
Herman, Valentine. 1976. Parliaments of the World: A Reference Compendium. Berlin and New York: De Gruyter.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katz, Richard S. 1985. “Preference Voting in Italy: Votes of Opinion, Belonging, or Exchange.” Comparative Political Studies 18 (07):229–49.Google Scholar
Katz, Richard S. 1986. “Intraparty Preference Voting.” In Electoral Laws and Their Political Consequences, ed. Grofman, Bernard and Lijphart, Arend. New York: Agathon.Google Scholar
Keesing's Contemporary Archives. 19451992. Bristol: Longman.Google Scholar
King, Gary, Alt, James E., Burns, Nancy Elizabeth, and Laver, Michael. 1990. “A Unified Model of Cabinet Dissolution in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 34 (08):846–71.Google Scholar
King, Gary, Keohane, Robert O., and Verba, Sidney. 1994. Designing Scientific Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Knight, Jack. 1992. Institutions and Social Conflict. New York and Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Budge, Ian. 1992. Party Policy and Government Coalitions. New York: St. Martin's.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Schofield, Norman. 1990. Multiparty Government: The Politics of Coalition in Europe. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Shepsle, Kenneth. 1990a. “Coalitions and Cabinet Government.” American Political Science Review 84 (09):873–90.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Shepsle, Kenneth. 1990b. “Government Coalitions and Intraparty Politics.” British Journal of Political Science 20 (10):485507.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Shepsle, Kenneth. 1990c. “The Size Principle and Minority Cabinets.” Presented at the Conference in Honor of William H. Riker, University of Rochester, October 12–13.Google Scholar
Leiserson, Michael. 1968. “Factions and Coalitions in One-Party Japan: An Interpretation Based on the Theory of Games.” American Political Science Review 62 (09):770–87.Google Scholar
Leonardi, Robert. 1981. “The Victors: The Smaller Parties in the 1979 Italian Elections.” In Italy at the Polls, 1979: A Study of the Parliamentary Elections, ed. Penniman, Howard R.. Washington: American Enterprise Institute.Google Scholar
Lewis-Beck, Michael S. 1986. “Comparative Economic Voting: Britain, France, Germany, Italy.” American Journal of Political Science, 30 (08):315–46.Google Scholar
Lewis-Beck, Michael S. 1988. Economics and Elections: The Major Western Democracies. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Lijphart, Arend. 1984. Democracies: Patterns of Majoritarian and Consensus Government in Twenty-One Countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Linz, Juan J. 1978. “The Breakdown of Democratic Regimes: Crisis, Breakdown, and Reequilibration.” In The Breakdown of Democratic Regimes, ed. Linz, Juan J. and Stepan, Alfred. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Mannheimer, Renato, and Sani, Giacomo. 1987. Il mercato elettorale. Identikit dell'elettore italiano. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Manzella, Andrea. 1991. Il parlamento, nuova edizione. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Marradi, Alberto. 1982. “From ‘Centrism’ to Crisis of the Center-Left Coalitions.” In Government Coalitions in Western Democracies, ed. Browne, Eric C. and Dreijmanis, John. London and New York: Longman.Google Scholar
Mastropaolo, Alfio, and Slater, Martin. 1987. “Italy 1947–1979: Ideological Distances and Party Movements.” In Ideology, Strategy and Party Change: Spatial Analyses of Post-War Election Programmes in 19 Democracies, ed. Budge, Ian, Robertson, David, and Hearl, Derek. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D. 1976. “Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting Models and Some Implications for Agenda Control.” Journal of Economic Theory 12 (06):472–82.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D. 1979. “General Conditions for Global Intransitivities in Formal Voting Models.” Econometrica 47 (09):1085–112.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D., and Schofield, Norman. 1987. “Generalized Symmetry Conditions at a Core Point.” Econometrica 55 (07):923–33.Google Scholar
Mershon, Carol. 1994. “Expectations and Informal Rules in Coalition Formation.” Comparative Political Studies 27 (04):4079.Google Scholar
Mershon, Carol. 1995. “The Costs of Coalition: A Five-Nation Comparison.” Presented at the annual meeting of the European Consortium for Political Research, Bordeaux.Google Scholar
Mershon, Carol. N.d. “The Costs of Coalition.” University of Virginia. Typescript.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nocifero, Nicolò, and Valdini, Sergio. 1992. Il palazzo di vetro. Il lavoro dei deputati italiani nella decima legislatura. Florence: Vallecchi.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ozinga, James R., Casstevens, Thomas W., and Casstevens, Harold T.. 1989. “The Circulation of Elites: Soviet Politburo Members, 1919–1987.” Canadian Journal of Political Science 22 (09):609–17.Google Scholar
Parisi, Arturo, and Pasquino, Gianfranco. 1979. “Changes in Italian Electoral Behavior: The Relationships between Parties and Voters.” West European Politics 2 (10):630.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pasquino, Gianfranco. 1981. “The Italian Socialist Party: Electoral Stagnation and Political Indispensability.” In Italy at the Polls, 1979: A Study of the Parliamentary Elections, ed. Penniman, Howard R.. Washington: American Enterprise Institute.Google Scholar
Petracca, Orazio M. 1980. Storia della prima repubblica. Milan: Mondo Economico.Google Scholar
Pollio Salimbeni, Antonio. 1989. “Presidente per la sesta volta.” L'Unità, July 23.Google Scholar
Powell, G. Bingham Jr. 1982. Contemporary Democracies: Participation, Stability, and Violence. Cambridge and London: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, G. Bingham Jr., and Whitten, Guy D.. 1993. “A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context.” American Journal of Political Science 37 (05):391414.Google Scholar
Pustetto, Maria Bruno. 1991. Il manuale del candidato politico. Milan: Bridge.Google Scholar
Rhodes, Martin. 1988. “Craxi e l'area laico-socialista: terza forza o tre forze?” In Politica in Italia: I fatti dell'anno e le interpretazioni. Edizione '88, ed. Corbetta, Piergiorgio and Leonardi, Robert. Bologna: Il Mulino.Google Scholar
Ricolfi, Luca. 1993. L'ultimo Parlamento. Sulla fine delta prima Repubblica. Rome: La Nuova Italia Scientiflca.Google Scholar
Riker, William H. 1962. The Theory of Political Coalitions. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Robertson, John D. 1983. “Inflation, Unemployment, and Government Collapse: A Poisson Application.” Comparative Political Studies 15 (01):425–44.Google Scholar
Sani, Giacomo. 1994. “Il verdetto del 1992.” In La rivoluzione elettorale. L'Italia tra la prima e la seconda repubblica, ed. Mannheimer, Renato and Sani, Giacomo. Milan: Anabasi.Google Scholar
Sartori, Giovanni. 1976. Parties and Party Systems. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schofield, Norman. 1983. “Generic Instability of Majority Rule.” Review of Economic Studies 50 (10):695705.Google Scholar
Schofield, Norman. 1986. “Existence of a ‘Structurally Stable’ Equilibrium for a Noncollegial Voting Rule.” Public Choice 51 (3):267–84.Google Scholar
Schofield, Norman. 1993. “Political Competition and Multiparty Coalition Governments.” European Journal of Political Research 23 (January): 133.Google Scholar
Schofield, Norman, Grofman, Bernard, and Feld, Scott L.. 1988. “The Core and the Stability of Group Choice in Spatial Voting Games.” American Political Science Review 82 (03):195211.Google Scholar
Schofield, Norman, and Laver, Michael. 1985. “Bargaining Theory and Portfolio Payoffs in European Coalition Governments 1945–83.” British Journal of Political Science 15 (04):143–64.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1979. “Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models.” American Journal of Political Science 23 (02):2759.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1986. “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions.” In Political Science: The Science of Politics, ed. Weisberg, Herbert F.. New York: Agathon.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1987. “The Institutional Foundations of Committee Power.” American Political Science Review 81 (03):85104.Google Scholar
Spotts, Frederic, and Wieser, Theodor. 1986. Italy: A Difficult Democracy. New York and Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Strom, Gerald S. 1990. The Logic of Lawmaking: A Spatial Theory Approach. Baltimore and London: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Strom, Kaare. 1985. “Party Goals and Government Performance in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Political Science Review 79 (09):738–54.Google Scholar
Strom, Kaare. 1990a. “A Behavioral Theory of Competitive Political Parties.” American Journal of Political Science 34 (05):565–98.Google Scholar
Strom, Kaare. 1990b. Minority Government and Majority Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tamburrano, G. 1971. Storia e cronaca del centro sinistra. Milan: Feltrinelli.Google Scholar
Tarrow, Sidney. 1990. “Maintaining Hegemony in Italy: ‘The softer they rise, the slower they fall!’” In Uncommon Democracies: The One-Party Dominant Regimes, ed. Pempel, T. J.. Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Taylor, Michael, and Herman, Valentine. 1971. “Party Systems and Government Stability.” American Political Science Review 65 (03):2837.Google Scholar
Timmermans, Arco. 1994. “Cabinet Ministers and Policy-Making in Belgium: The Impact of Coalition Constraints.” In Cabinet Ministers and Parliamentary Government, ed. Laver, Michael and Shepsle, Kenneth A.. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, George. 1990. Nested Games: Rational Choice in Comparative Politics. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Venditti, Renato. 1981. Il manuale Cencelli. Rome: Editori Riuniti.Google Scholar
Warwick, Paul, and Easton, Stephen T.. 1992. “The Cabinet Stability Controversy: New Perspectives on a Classic Problem.” American Journal of Political Science 36 (02):122–46.Google Scholar
Zuckerman, Alan. 1979. The Politics of Faction. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar