Skip to main content

2019 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

2. Methodological Foundations

verfasst von : Joachim Weimann, Jeannette Brosig-Koch

Erschienen in: Methods in Experimental Economics

Verlag: Springer International Publishing

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Now that we have prepared the stage for experimental economics in the first chapter, the second chapter deals with the methodological foundations. The times are long gone when economists “just did an experiment” to see what happens when you let subjects play games. In the meantime, methodological standards and procedures have evolved. Following these procedures is an important prerequisite for obtaining experimental results that can claim to meet the scientific standards of the economics profession. We have put the most important methodological fundamentals into groups, each of which is based on one component of an experiment.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
The exceptions are Volk et al. (2012), Carlsson et al. (2014), Sass and Weimann (2015), Brosig-Koch et al. (2017), and Sass et al. (2018).
 
2
For a survey see Feltovich (2011).
 
3
However, there is also evidence that monetary incentives can destroy intrinsic motivation (see, for example, Frey and Oberholzer-Gee 1997, Gneezy and Rustichini 2000, Mellström and Johannesson 2008, Fryer 2013).
 
4
Cox et al. (1992), Friedman (1992), Harrison (1992), Kagel and Roth (1992) and Merlo and Schotter (1992).
 
5
This experience was gained by talking to an experienced experimenter who had often conducted such experiments.
 
6
The statistical analysis of panel data differs from that of a time series, where the individual observations are independent. We will discuss this point briefly in 7 Chap. 4.
 
7
This means that neither the subjects among themselves nor the experimenter can observe what a subject is doing. How such designs can be achieved and what effects they have will be explained in more detail later in 7 Sect. 2.5.2.
 
8
See Ortmann and Hertwig (2002) for a survey.
 
9
In fact, this is exactly what they do (cf. Andreoni 1988).
 
10
One example is Harrison and List (2004).
 
11
We will come back to this point in 7 Sect. 2.5.1.
 
12
There is now a large body of literature on the selection biases that can be associated with student subjects. For example, Harrison et al. (2009), Feltovich (2011), Anderson et al. (2013), Cleave et al. (2013), Exadaktylos et al. (2013), Falk et al. (2013), Abeler and Nosenzo (2015), Belot et al. (2015) as well as Cappelen et al. (2015).
 
13
This will be explained in more detail in the next Section.
 
14
Strictly speaking, the second derivative of the utility function is decisive for the distinction between risk neutrality (second derivative equals zero), risk aversion (second derivative is negative) and risk seeking (second derivative is positive). There are also characterizations of risk preferences that are based on higher derivatives of the utility function, such as prudence (positive third derivative of the utility function, see Kimball 1990) and temperance (negative fourth derivative of the utility function, see Kimball 1992).
 
15
For example, the contribution of Harrison and Rutström (2008) in volume 12 of “Research in Experimental Economics” contains about 150 pages on this topic alone.
 
16
The numbers and the. Table 2.3 are taken from Harrison and Rutström (2008).
 
17
In Hey and Orme, this is 0, 10, 20 and 30 pounds sterling with 100 decisions having to be made.
 
18
Indeed, such proposals are almost always accepted. See e.g. Güth and Kocher (2014).
 
19
Schotter and Trevino (2014), p. 107, also see Holt and Smith (2009) and Karni (2009).
 
20
Nyarko and Schotter (2002), Costa-Gomes and Weizäcker (2008), Ivanov (2011) and Schotter and Trevino (2014).
 
21
The full strategy method will be discussed in 7 Sect. 2.7.1. In this method, subjects specify complete strategies instead of reacting to a specific move made by the other subject. In the ultimatum game, for example, responders must specify as of which proposal of the proposer they are willing to accept the proposal.
 
22
See Zizzo (2010), p. 83, footnote 11.
 
23
In Brosig et al. (2004), this aspect of the strategy method is used, among other things, to explain the differences between “hot” (without strategy method) and “cold” (with strategy method) experiments. See 7 Sect. 2.7.1.
 
24
See, for example, the work of Krupka and Weber (2013), which shows that allocations in the dictator game can be interpreted as the price to pay for being able to be in accordance with a social norm.
 
25
This is also pointed out by Zizzo (2010).
 
26
See also Abbink and Hennig-Schmidt (2006).
 
27
The experiment was actually also presented as a climate negotiation, i.e. the subjects were asked to imagine representing their country at an international climate negotiation. For the effect of such frames, see 7 Sect. 2.5.3.
 
28
In contrast, the proportion of eastern German subjects at the western German university was well below 2%.
 
29
This is not exactly a trivial problem, because a receipt from the subject is usually required for the settlement of the money from the experiment.
 
30
It should be noted that the term double blind used here is not identical to that used in medicine, for example. In drug studies, this means that neither the physician administering the drug nor the patient participating in the study knows whether the drug to be tested or a placebo is being administered.
 
31
The game can be presented either in the usual normal form or in the “decomposed game” version, in each case indicating how the choice of one’s own strategy affects one’s own payoff and the payoff of the other player.
 
32
An exception, which has already been mentioned, is Zizzo (2010).
 
33
They refer, for example, to Irlenbusch and Sutter (2006), who use an abstract experiment to describe the behavior of EU states, or to Erhard and Keser (1999), who in the same way attempt to model joining a trade union.
 
34
Literally translated: Remember that he is in your hands. What is meant here is the receiver of the dictator’s transfer.
 
35
We suspect that the authors use the name “German tipping game” because tips in Germany are smaller on average (because waiters are better paid) than in the US.
 
36
Of course, the values can also be drawn at random for each subject. In order to control for these heterogeneous previous experiences, however, a correspondingly large sample is required (see chapter four).
 
37
For a detailed discussion of the behavioral effects of cheap talk predicted by game theory, see Crawford (1998).
 
38
This was done with the help of bipolar scales that questioned the following pairs of terms: “active – passive”, “lively – dull”, “attractive – unattractive”, “pleasant – unpleasant”, “strong – weak”, “influential – not influential”.
 
39
A whole series of studies provide different findings, i.e. the strategy method has an effect in some of the designs, but not in others. See Brandts and Charness (2011).
 
40
The intrinsic value of the work has, of course, contributed to this, but the effort involved in the “chosen efforts” is surprisingly low at 23%, which results in costs of 1.3 monetary units (0.13 euros). Measured in the payoff space, this is close to the equilibrium.
 
41
To provide an idea of the subjects’ work performance, in the second experiment (Fochmann and Weimann 2013) 43,300 letters were folded and placed in envelopes. On average, the subjects spent 72 minutes in the laboratory, with the duration of their stay being of their choice.
 
42
Cooper et al. (1996) experimentally show that the difference between repeated one-shot games and a repeated game can be substantial.
 
43
Merritt et al. (2010) provide a survey of the literature on “moral licensing”. More recent experimental studies relating to this effect have been conducted by Brañas-Garza et al. (2013), Ploner and Regner (2013), Clot et al. (2014), Cojoc and Stoian (2014) and Brosig-Koch et al. (2017), for example.
 
44
See, for example, the discussion initiated mainly by Levitt and List (2007).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Abbink, K., & Hennig-Schmidt, H. (2006). Neutral versus loaded instructions in a bribery experiment. Experimental Economics, 9(2), 103–121.CrossRef Abbink, K., & Hennig-Schmidt, H. (2006). Neutral versus loaded instructions in a bribery experiment. Experimental Economics, 9(2), 103–121.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Abeler, J., & Nosenzo, D. (2015). Self-selection into laboratory experiments: Pro-social motives versus monetary incentives. Experimental Economics, 18(2), 195–214.CrossRef Abeler, J., & Nosenzo, D. (2015). Self-selection into laboratory experiments: Pro-social motives versus monetary incentives. Experimental Economics, 18(2), 195–214.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alberti, F., & Güth, W. (2013). Studying deception without deceiving participants: An experiment of deception experiments. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 93, 196–204.CrossRef Alberti, F., & Güth, W. (2013). Studying deception without deceiving participants: An experiment of deception experiments. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 93, 196–204.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson, J., Burks, S., Carpenter, J., Gotte, L., Maurer, K., Nosenzo, D., Potter, R., Rocha, K., & Rustichini, A. (2013). Self-selection and variations in the laboratory measurement of other-regarding preferences across subject pools: Evidence from one college student and two adult samples. Experimental Economics, 16(2), 170–189.CrossRef Anderson, J., Burks, S., Carpenter, J., Gotte, L., Maurer, K., Nosenzo, D., Potter, R., Rocha, K., & Rustichini, A. (2013). Self-selection and variations in the laboratory measurement of other-regarding preferences across subject pools: Evidence from one college student and two adult samples. Experimental Economics, 16(2), 170–189.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson, L. R., Mellor, J. M., & Milyo, J. (2008). Inequality and public good provision: An experimental analysis. Journal of Socio-Economics, 37, 1010–1028.CrossRef Anderson, L. R., Mellor, J. M., & Milyo, J. (2008). Inequality and public good provision: An experimental analysis. Journal of Socio-Economics, 37, 1010–1028.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Andreoni, J. (1988). Why free ride?: Strategies and learning in public goods experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 37, 291–304.CrossRef Andreoni, J. (1988). Why free ride?: Strategies and learning in public goods experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 37, 291–304.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bardsley, N. (2008). Dictator game giving: Altruism or artefact? Experimental Economics, 11(2), 122–133.CrossRef Bardsley, N. (2008). Dictator game giving: Altruism or artefact? Experimental Economics, 11(2), 122–133.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barrera, D., & Simpson, B. (2012). Much ado about deception: Consequences of deceiving research participants in the social sciences. Sociological Methods Research, 41(3), 383–413.CrossRef Barrera, D., & Simpson, B. (2012). Much ado about deception: Consequences of deceiving research participants in the social sciences. Sociological Methods Research, 41(3), 383–413.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barmettler, F., Fehr, E., & Zehnder, C. (2012). Big experimenter is watching you! An-onymity and prosocial behavior in the laboratory. Games and Economic Behavior, 75(1), 17–34.CrossRef Barmettler, F., Fehr, E., & Zehnder, C. (2012). Big experimenter is watching you! An-onymity and prosocial behavior in the laboratory. Games and Economic Behavior, 75(1), 17–34.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Becker, G. M., DeGroot, M. H., & Marschak, J. (1964). Measuring utility by a single-response sequential method. Systems Research and Behavioral Science, 9(3), 226–232.CrossRef Becker, G. M., DeGroot, M. H., & Marschak, J. (1964). Measuring utility by a single-response sequential method. Systems Research and Behavioral Science, 9(3), 226–232.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Belot, M., Duch, R., & Miller, L. (2015). A comprehensive comparison of students and non-students in classic experimental games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 113, 26–33.CrossRef Belot, M., Duch, R., & Miller, L. (2015). A comprehensive comparison of students and non-students in classic experimental games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 113, 26–33.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ben-Ner, A., Putterman, L., & Ren, T. (2011). Lavish returns on cheap talk: Two-way communication in trust games. Journal of Socio-Economics, 40, 1–13.CrossRef Ben-Ner, A., Putterman, L., & Ren, T. (2011). Lavish returns on cheap talk: Two-way communication in trust games. Journal of Socio-Economics, 40, 1–13.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Binmore, K., Shaked, A., & Sutton, J. (1985). Testing noncooperative bargaining theory: A preliminary study. American Economic Review, 75(5), 1178–1180. Binmore, K., Shaked, A., & Sutton, J. (1985). Testing noncooperative bargaining theory: A preliminary study. American Economic Review, 75(5), 1178–1180.
Zurück zum Zitat Binswanger, H. P. (1980). Attitudes toward risk: Experimental measurement in rural India. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 62(3), 395–407.CrossRef Binswanger, H. P. (1980). Attitudes toward risk: Experimental measurement in rural India. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 62(3), 395–407.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Binswanger, H. P. (1981). Attitudes toward risk: Theoretical implications of an experiment in rural India. The Economic Journal, 91(364), 867–890.CrossRef Binswanger, H. P. (1981). Attitudes toward risk: Theoretical implications of an experiment in rural India. The Economic Journal, 91(364), 867–890.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blanco, M., Engelmann, D., Koch, A. K., & Normann, H. T. (2010). Belief elicitation in experiments: Is there a hedging problem? Experimental Economics, 13(4), 412–438.CrossRef Blanco, M., Engelmann, D., Koch, A. K., & Normann, H. T. (2010). Belief elicitation in experiments: Is there a hedging problem? Experimental Economics, 13(4), 412–438.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blaufuß, K., Fochmann, M., Hundsdoerfer, J., Kiesewetter, D., & Weimann, J. (2013). Net wage illusion in a real-effort experiment. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 115(2), 476–484. Blaufuß, K., Fochmann, M., Hundsdoerfer, J., Kiesewetter, D., & Weimann, J. (2013). Net wage illusion in a real-effort experiment. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 115(2), 476–484.
Zurück zum Zitat Blume, A., & Ortmann, A. (2000). The effect of costless pre-play communication: Experimental evidence from a game with Pareto-ranked equilibria. Journal of Economic Theory, 132, 274–290.CrossRef Blume, A., & Ortmann, A. (2000). The effect of costless pre-play communication: Experimental evidence from a game with Pareto-ranked equilibria. Journal of Economic Theory, 132, 274–290.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bortolotti, S., Casari, M., & Pancotto, F. (2015). Norms of punishment: Experiments with students and the general population. Economic Enquiry, 53, 1207–1223.CrossRef Bortolotti, S., Casari, M., & Pancotto, F. (2015). Norms of punishment: Experiments with students and the general population. Economic Enquiry, 53, 1207–1223.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bohnet, I., & Frey, B. S. (1999). The sound of silence in prisoner’s dilemma and dictator games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 38(1), 43–57.CrossRef Bohnet, I., & Frey, B. S. (1999). The sound of silence in prisoner’s dilemma and dictator games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 38(1), 43–57.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bonetti, S. (1998). Experimental economics and deception. Journal of Economic Psychology, 19, 377–395.CrossRef Bonetti, S. (1998). Experimental economics and deception. Journal of Economic Psychology, 19, 377–395.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brañas-Garza, P. (2007). Promoting helping behavior with framing in dictator games. Journal of Economic Psychology, 28, 477–486.CrossRef Brañas-Garza, P. (2007). Promoting helping behavior with framing in dictator games. Journal of Economic Psychology, 28, 477–486.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brañas-Garza, P., Bucheli, M., Espinosa, M. P., & García-Muñoz, T. (2013). Moral cleansing and moral licenses: Experimental evidence. Economics & Philosophy, 29(2), 199–212.CrossRef Brañas-Garza, P., Bucheli, M., Espinosa, M. P., & García-Muñoz, T. (2013). Moral cleansing and moral licenses: Experimental evidence. Economics & Philosophy, 29(2), 199–212.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brandts, J., & Charness, G. (2003). Truth or consequences: An experiment. Management Science, 49(1), 116–130.CrossRef Brandts, J., & Charness, G. (2003). Truth or consequences: An experiment. Management Science, 49(1), 116–130.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brandts, J., & Charness, G. (2011). The strategy versus the direct-response method: A first survey of experimental comparisons. Experimental Economics, 14, 375–398.CrossRef Brandts, J., & Charness, G. (2011). The strategy versus the direct-response method: A first survey of experimental comparisons. Experimental Economics, 14, 375–398.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brosig, J., Weimann, J., & Ockenfels, A. (2003). The effect of communication media on cooperation. German Economic Review, 4(2), 217–241.CrossRef Brosig, J., Weimann, J., & Ockenfels, A. (2003). The effect of communication media on cooperation. German Economic Review, 4(2), 217–241.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brosig, J., Weimann, J., & Yang, C. L. (2004). The hot versus cold effect in a simple bargaining experiment. Experimental Economics, 6(1), 75–90.CrossRef Brosig, J., Weimann, J., & Yang, C. L. (2004). The hot versus cold effect in a simple bargaining experiment. Experimental Economics, 6(1), 75–90.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brosig, J., Heinrich, T., Riechmann, T., Schöb, R., & Weimann, J. (2010). Laying off or not? The influence of framing and economics education. International Review of Economics Education, 9, 44–55.CrossRef Brosig, J., Heinrich, T., Riechmann, T., Schöb, R., & Weimann, J. (2010). Laying off or not? The influence of framing and economics education. International Review of Economics Education, 9, 44–55.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brosig-Koch, J., & Heinrich, T. (2018). The role of communication content and reputation in the choice of transaction partners: A study based on field and laboratory data. Games and Economic Behavior, 112, 49–66. Brosig-Koch, J., & Heinrich, T. (2018). The role of communication content and reputation in the choice of transaction partners: A study based on field and laboratory data. Games and Economic Behavior, 112, 49–66.
Zurück zum Zitat Brosig-Koch, J., Helbach, C., Ockenfels, A., & Weimann, J. (2011). Still different after all these years: Solidarity behavior in East and West Germany. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 1373–1376.CrossRef Brosig-Koch, J., Helbach, C., Ockenfels, A., & Weimann, J. (2011). Still different after all these years: Solidarity behavior in East and West Germany. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 1373–1376.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brosig-Koch, J., Riechmann, T., & Weimann, J. (2017). The dynamics of behavior in modified dictator games. PLoS One, 12(4), e0176199.CrossRef Brosig-Koch, J., Riechmann, T., & Weimann, J. (2017). The dynamics of behavior in modified dictator games. PLoS One, 12(4), e0176199.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brüggen, A., & Strobel, M. (2007). Real effort versus chosen effort in experiment. Economics Letters, 96, 232–236.CrossRef Brüggen, A., & Strobel, M. (2007). Real effort versus chosen effort in experiment. Economics Letters, 96, 232–236.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bruttel, L., & Kamecke, U. (2012). Infinity in the lab. How do people play repeates games. Theory and Decision, 72, 205–219.CrossRef Bruttel, L., & Kamecke, U. (2012). Infinity in the lab. How do people play repeates games. Theory and Decision, 72, 205–219.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Buchan, N. R., Johnson, E. J., & Croson, R. T. (2006). Let’s get personal: An international examination of the influence of communication, culture and social distance on other regarding preferences. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 60(3), 373–398.CrossRef Buchan, N. R., Johnson, E. J., & Croson, R. T. (2006). Let’s get personal: An international examination of the influence of communication, culture and social distance on other regarding preferences. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 60(3), 373–398.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Burnham, T., McCabe, K., & Smith, V. L. (2000). Friend-or-foe intentionality priming in an extensive form trust game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 43(1), 57–73.CrossRef Burnham, T., McCabe, K., & Smith, V. L. (2000). Friend-or-foe intentionality priming in an extensive form trust game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 43(1), 57–73.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cachon, G., & Camerer, C. (1996). Loss avoidance and forward induction in experimental coordination games. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(1), 166–194.CrossRef Cachon, G., & Camerer, C. (1996). Loss avoidance and forward induction in experimental coordination games. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(1), 166–194.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cappelen, A. W., Nygaard, K., Sørensen, E., & Tungodden, B. (2015). Social preferences in the lab: A comparison of students and a representative population. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1306–1326.CrossRef Cappelen, A. W., Nygaard, K., Sørensen, E., & Tungodden, B. (2015). Social preferences in the lab: A comparison of students and a representative population. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1306–1326.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Camerer, C. F., & Hogarth, R. M. (1999). The effects of financial incentives in experiments: A review and capital-labor-production framework. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 7–42.CrossRef Camerer, C. F., & Hogarth, R. M. (1999). The effects of financial incentives in experiments: A review and capital-labor-production framework. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 7–42.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carlsson, F., He, H., & Martinsson, P. (2013). Easy come, easy go. Experimental Economics, 16(2), 190–207.CrossRef Carlsson, F., He, H., & Martinsson, P. (2013). Easy come, easy go. Experimental Economics, 16(2), 190–207.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carlsson, F., Johansson-Stenman, O., & Nam, P. K. (2014). Social preferences are stable over long periods of time. Journal of Public Economics, 117, 104–114.CrossRef Carlsson, F., Johansson-Stenman, O., & Nam, P. K. (2014). Social preferences are stable over long periods of time. Journal of Public Economics, 117, 104–114.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Charness, G., & Dufwenberg, M. (2006). Promises and partnership. Econometrica, 74, 1579–1601.CrossRef Charness, G., & Dufwenberg, M. (2006). Promises and partnership. Econometrica, 74, 1579–1601.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Charness, G., & Gneezy, U. (2008). What’s in a name? Anonymity and social distance in dictator and ultimatum games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 68(1), 29–35.CrossRef Charness, G., & Gneezy, U. (2008). What’s in a name? Anonymity and social distance in dictator and ultimatum games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 68(1), 29–35.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Charness, G., Gneezy, U., & Kuhn, M. A. (2012). Experimental methods: Between-subject and within-subject design. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 81(1), 1–8.CrossRef Charness, G., Gneezy, U., & Kuhn, M. A. (2012). Experimental methods: Between-subject and within-subject design. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 81(1), 1–8.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Charness, G., Haruvy, E., & Sonsino, D. (2007). Social distance and reciprocity: An internet experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 63(1), 88–103.CrossRef Charness, G., Haruvy, E., & Sonsino, D. (2007). Social distance and reciprocity: An internet experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 63(1), 88–103.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cherry, T., Frykblom, P., & Shogren, J. (2002). Hardnose the dictator. American Economic Review, 92(4), 1218–1221.CrossRef Cherry, T., Frykblom, P., & Shogren, J. (2002). Hardnose the dictator. American Economic Review, 92(4), 1218–1221.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cherry, T. L., Kroll, S., & Shogren, J. F. (2005). The impact of endowment heterogeneity and origin on public good contributions: Evidence from the lab. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 57(3), 357–365.CrossRef Cherry, T. L., Kroll, S., & Shogren, J. F. (2005). The impact of endowment heterogeneity and origin on public good contributions: Evidence from the lab. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 57(3), 357–365.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cherry, T. L., & Shogren, J. F. (2008). Self-interest, sympathy and the origin of endowments. Economics Letters, 101(1), 69–72.CrossRef Cherry, T. L., & Shogren, J. F. (2008). Self-interest, sympathy and the origin of endowments. Economics Letters, 101(1), 69–72.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Clark, J. (2002). House money effects in public good experiments. Experimental Economics, 5(3), 223–231.CrossRef Clark, J. (2002). House money effects in public good experiments. Experimental Economics, 5(3), 223–231.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cleave, B. L., Nikiforakis, M., & Slonim, R. (2013). Is there selection bias in laboratory experiments? The case of social and risk preferences. Experimental Economics, 16(3), 372–382.CrossRef Cleave, B. L., Nikiforakis, M., & Slonim, R. (2013). Is there selection bias in laboratory experiments? The case of social and risk preferences. Experimental Economics, 16(3), 372–382.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Clot, S., Grolleau, G., & Ibanez, L. (2014). Smug alert! Exploring self-licensing behavior in a cheating game. Economics Letters, 123(2), 191–194.CrossRef Clot, S., Grolleau, G., & Ibanez, L. (2014). Smug alert! Exploring self-licensing behavior in a cheating game. Economics Letters, 123(2), 191–194.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cojoc, D., & Stoian, A. (2014). Dishonesty and charitable behavior. Experimental Economics, 17(4), 717–732.CrossRef Cojoc, D., & Stoian, A. (2014). Dishonesty and charitable behavior. Experimental Economics, 17(4), 717–732.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cooper, D. (2014). A note on deception in economic experiments. Journal of Wine Economics, 9(2), 111–114.CrossRef Cooper, D. (2014). A note on deception in economic experiments. Journal of Wine Economics, 9(2), 111–114.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cooper, R., DeJong, D. V., Forsythe, R., & Ross, T. W. (1996). Cooperation without reputation: Experimental evidence from prisoner’s dilemma games. Games and Economic Behavior, 12, 187–218.CrossRef Cooper, R., DeJong, D. V., Forsythe, R., & Ross, T. W. (1996). Cooperation without reputation: Experimental evidence from prisoner’s dilemma games. Games and Economic Behavior, 12, 187–218.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Costa-Gomes, M. A., & Weizsäcker, G. (2008). Stated beliefs and play in normal-form games. Review of Economic Studies, 75(3), 729–762.CrossRef Costa-Gomes, M. A., & Weizsäcker, G. (2008). Stated beliefs and play in normal-form games. Review of Economic Studies, 75(3), 729–762.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cox, J. C., & Deck, A. A. (2005). On the nature of reciprocal motives. Economic Inquiry, 43(3), 623–635.CrossRef Cox, J. C., & Deck, A. A. (2005). On the nature of reciprocal motives. Economic Inquiry, 43(3), 623–635.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cox, J. C., Robertson, B., & Smith, V. L. (1982). Theory and behavior of single object auctions. In V. L. Smith (Ed.), Research in experimental economics (Vol. 2, pp. 1–43). Greenwich: JAI Press. Cox, J. C., Robertson, B., & Smith, V. L. (1982). Theory and behavior of single object auctions. In V. L. Smith (Ed.), Research in experimental economics (Vol. 2, pp. 1–43). Greenwich: JAI Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Cox, J. C., Sadiraj, V., & Schmidt, U. (2015). Paradoxes and mechanisms for choice under risk. Experimental Economics, 18(2), 215–250.CrossRef Cox, J. C., Sadiraj, V., & Schmidt, U. (2015). Paradoxes and mechanisms for choice under risk. Experimental Economics, 18(2), 215–250.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cox, J. C., Smith, V. L., & Walker, J. M. (1992). Theory and misbehavior of first-price auctions: Comment. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1392–1412. Cox, J. C., Smith, V. L., & Walker, J. M. (1992). Theory and misbehavior of first-price auctions: Comment. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1392–1412.
Zurück zum Zitat Crawford, V. (1998). A survey of experiments on communication via cheap talk. Journal of Economic Theory, 78(2), 286–298.CrossRef Crawford, V. (1998). A survey of experiments on communication via cheap talk. Journal of Economic Theory, 78(2), 286–298.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Csukás, C., Fracalanza, P., Kovács, T., & Willinger, M. (2008). The determinants of trusting and reciprocal behaviour: Evidence from an intercultural experiment. Journal of Economic Development, 33(1), 71–95. Csukás, C., Fracalanza, P., Kovács, T., & Willinger, M. (2008). The determinants of trusting and reciprocal behaviour: Evidence from an intercultural experiment. Journal of Economic Development, 33(1), 71–95.
Zurück zum Zitat Dawes, R. M., McTavish, J., & Shaklee, H. (1977). Behavior, communication, and assumptions about other people’s behavior in a commons dilemma situation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 35(1), 1–11.CrossRef Dawes, R. M., McTavish, J., & Shaklee, H. (1977). Behavior, communication, and assumptions about other people’s behavior in a commons dilemma situation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 35(1), 1–11.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dreber, A., Ellingsen, T., Johannesson, M., & Rand, D. G. (2013). Do people care about social context? Framing effects in dictator games. Experimental Economics, 16(3), 349–371.CrossRef Dreber, A., Ellingsen, T., Johannesson, M., & Rand, D. G. (2013). Do people care about social context? Framing effects in dictator games. Experimental Economics, 16(3), 349–371.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dufwenberg, M., Gächter, S., & Hennig-Schmidt, H. (2011). The framing of games and the psychology of play. Games and Economic Behavior, 73, 459–478.CrossRef Dufwenberg, M., Gächter, S., & Hennig-Schmidt, H. (2011). The framing of games and the psychology of play. Games and Economic Behavior, 73, 459–478.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (1996). Altruism in anonymous dictator games. Games and Economic Behavior, 16(2), 181–191.CrossRef Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (1996). Altruism in anonymous dictator games. Games and Economic Behavior, 16(2), 181–191.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ellingsen, T., & Johannesson, M. (2004). Promises, threats and fairness. The Economic Journal, 114(495), 397–420.CrossRef Ellingsen, T., & Johannesson, M. (2004). Promises, threats and fairness. The Economic Journal, 114(495), 397–420.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Erkal, N., Gangadharan, L., & Nikiforakis, N. (2011). Relative earnings and giving in a real-effort experiment. American Economic Review, 101(7), 3330–3348.CrossRef Erkal, N., Gangadharan, L., & Nikiforakis, N. (2011). Relative earnings and giving in a real-effort experiment. American Economic Review, 101(7), 3330–3348.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Erhard, K.-A., & Keser, C. (1999). Mobility and cooperation: On the run (Scientific series). Montreal: CIRANO, 99s-24. Erhard, K.-A., & Keser, C. (1999). Mobility and cooperation: On the run (Scientific series). Montreal: CIRANO, 99s-24.
Zurück zum Zitat Exadaktylos, F., Espín, A. M., & Branas-Garza, P. (2013). Experimental subjects are not different. Scientific Reports, 3, 1213.CrossRef Exadaktylos, F., Espín, A. M., & Branas-Garza, P. (2013). Experimental subjects are not different. Scientific Reports, 3, 1213.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fahr, R., & Irlenbusch, B. (2000). Fairness as a constraint on trust in reciprocity: Earned property rights in a reciprocal exchange experiment. Economics Letters, 66, 275–282.CrossRef Fahr, R., & Irlenbusch, B. (2000). Fairness as a constraint on trust in reciprocity: Earned property rights in a reciprocal exchange experiment. Economics Letters, 66, 275–282.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Falk, A., Meier, S., & Zehnder, C. (2013). Do lab experiments misrepresent social preferences? The case of self selected student samples. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(4), 839–852.CrossRef Falk, A., Meier, S., & Zehnder, C. (2013). Do lab experiments misrepresent social preferences? The case of self selected student samples. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(4), 839–852.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Farrell, J., & Rabin, M. (1996). Cheap talk. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(3), 103–118.CrossRef Farrell, J., & Rabin, M. (1996). Cheap talk. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(3), 103–118.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fehr, E., Kirchler, E., Weichbold, A., & Gächter, S. (1998). When social norms over-power competition: Gift exchange in experimental labor markets. Journal of Labor Economics, 16(2), 324–351.CrossRef Fehr, E., Kirchler, E., Weichbold, A., & Gächter, S. (1998). When social norms over-power competition: Gift exchange in experimental labor markets. Journal of Labor Economics, 16(2), 324–351.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fehr, E., Kirchsteiger, G., & Riedl, A. (1993). Does fairness prevent market clearing? An experimental investigation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 437–460.CrossRef Fehr, E., Kirchsteiger, G., & Riedl, A. (1993). Does fairness prevent market clearing? An experimental investigation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 437–460.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (2006). The economics of fairness, reciprocity and altruism–experimental evidence and new theories. In S.-C. Kolm & J. M. Ythier (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of giving, altruism and reciprocity (Vol. 1, pp. 615–691). Amsterdam: North-Holland. Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (2006). The economics of fairness, reciprocity and altruism–experimental evidence and new theories. In S.-C. Kolm & J. M. Ythier (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of giving, altruism and reciprocity (Vol. 1, pp. 615–691). Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Zurück zum Zitat Feltovich, N. (2011). What’s to know about laboratory experimentation in economics. Journal of Economic Surveys, 25, 371–379.CrossRef Feltovich, N. (2011). What’s to know about laboratory experimentation in economics. Journal of Economic Surveys, 25, 371–379.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fischbacher, U., & Föllmi-Heusi, F. (2013). Lies in disguise—An experimental study on cheating. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(3), 525–547.CrossRef Fischbacher, U., & Föllmi-Heusi, F. (2013). Lies in disguise—An experimental study on cheating. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(3), 525–547.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fischbacher, U., & Gächter, S. (2010). Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 100(1), 541–556.CrossRef Fischbacher, U., & Gächter, S. (2010). Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 100(1), 541–556.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Economics Letters, 71(3), 397–404.CrossRef Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Economics Letters, 71(3), 397–404.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fochmann, M., & Weimann, J. (2013). The effects of tax salience and tax experience on individual work efforts in a framed field experiment. Public Finance Analysis, 69, 1–32.CrossRef Fochmann, M., & Weimann, J. (2013). The effects of tax salience and tax experience on individual work efforts in a framed field experiment. Public Finance Analysis, 69, 1–32.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fonseca, M. A., & Normann, H. T. (2008). Mergers, asymmetries and collusion: Experimental evidence. The Economic Journal, 118(527), 387–400.CrossRef Fonseca, M. A., & Normann, H. T. (2008). Mergers, asymmetries and collusion: Experimental evidence. The Economic Journal, 118(527), 387–400.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fonseca, M. A., & Normann, H. T. (2012). Explicit vs. Tacit collusion – The impact of communication in oligogoply experiments. European Economic Review, 56, 1759–1772.CrossRef Fonseca, M. A., & Normann, H. T. (2012). Explicit vs. Tacit collusion – The impact of communication in oligogoply experiments. European Economic Review, 56, 1759–1772.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Forsythe, R., Horowitz, J. L., Savin, N. E., & Sefton, M. (1994). Fairness in simple bar-gaining experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 6(3), 347–369.CrossRef Forsythe, R., Horowitz, J. L., Savin, N. E., & Sefton, M. (1994). Fairness in simple bar-gaining experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 6(3), 347–369.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Frank, R. H., Gilovich, T., & Regan, D. T. (1993). Does studying economics inhibit co-operation? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(2), 159–171.CrossRef Frank, R. H., Gilovich, T., & Regan, D. T. (1993). Does studying economics inhibit co-operation? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(2), 159–171.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fréchette, G. R., & Schotter, A. (2015). Handbook of experimental economic methodology. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Fréchette, G. R., & Schotter, A. (2015). Handbook of experimental economic methodology. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Frey, B. S., & Oberholzer-Gee, F. (1997). The cost of price incentives: An empirical analysis of motivation crowding-out. American Economic Review, 87(4), 746–755. Frey, B. S., & Oberholzer-Gee, F. (1997). The cost of price incentives: An empirical analysis of motivation crowding-out. American Economic Review, 87(4), 746–755.
Zurück zum Zitat Friedman, D. (1992). Theory and misbehavior of first-price auctions: Comment. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1374–1378. Friedman, D. (1992). Theory and misbehavior of first-price auctions: Comment. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1374–1378.
Zurück zum Zitat Fryer, R. G. (2013). Teacher incentives and student achievement: Evidence from New York City public schools. Journal of Labor Economics, 31(2), 373–407.CrossRef Fryer, R. G. (2013). Teacher incentives and student achievement: Evidence from New York City public schools. Journal of Labor Economics, 31(2), 373–407.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2000). Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 90(4), 980–994.CrossRef Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2000). Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 90(4), 980–994.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Geanakoplos, J. D., Pearce, J. D., & Stacchetti, E. (1989). Psychological games and sequential rationality. Games and Economic Behavior, 1(1), 60–79.CrossRef Geanakoplos, J. D., Pearce, J. D., & Stacchetti, E. (1989). Psychological games and sequential rationality. Games and Economic Behavior, 1(1), 60–79.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gill, D., & Prowse, V. (2012). A structural analysis of disappointment aversion in a real effort competition. American Economic Review, 102(1), 469–503.CrossRef Gill, D., & Prowse, V. (2012). A structural analysis of disappointment aversion in a real effort competition. American Economic Review, 102(1), 469–503.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gneezy, U., Niederle, M., & Rustichini, A. (2003). Performance in competitive environments: Gender differences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 1049–1074.CrossRef Gneezy, U., Niederle, M., & Rustichini, A. (2003). Performance in competitive environments: Gender differences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 1049–1074.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gneezy, U., & Rustichini, A. (2000). Pay enough or don’t pay at all. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 791–810.CrossRef Gneezy, U., & Rustichini, A. (2000). Pay enough or don’t pay at all. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 791–810.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goerg, S. J., Hennig-Schmidt, H., Walkowitz, G., & Winter, E. (2016). In wrong anticipation-miscalibrated beliefs between Germans, Israelis, and Palestinians. PLoS One, 11(6), e0156998.CrossRef Goerg, S. J., Hennig-Schmidt, H., Walkowitz, G., & Winter, E. (2016). In wrong anticipation-miscalibrated beliefs between Germans, Israelis, and Palestinians. PLoS One, 11(6), e0156998.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Greiner, B., Güth, W., & Zultan, R. (2012). Social communication and discrimination: A video experiment. Experimental Economics, 15, 398–417.CrossRef Greiner, B., Güth, W., & Zultan, R. (2012). Social communication and discrimination: A video experiment. Experimental Economics, 15, 398–417.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grimm, V., & Mengel, F. (2011). Let me sleep on it: Delay reduces rejection rates in ultimatum games. Economics Letters, 111(2), 113–115.CrossRef Grimm, V., & Mengel, F. (2011). Let me sleep on it: Delay reduces rejection rates in ultimatum games. Economics Letters, 111(2), 113–115.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Güth, W., & Kocher, M. G. (2014). More than thirty years of ultimatum bargaining experiments: Motives, variations, and a survey of the recent literature. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 108, 396–409.CrossRef Güth, W., & Kocher, M. G. (2014). More than thirty years of ultimatum bargaining experiments: Motives, variations, and a survey of the recent literature. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 108, 396–409.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Güth, W., Schmittberger, R., & Schwarze, B. (1982). An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 3, 367–388.CrossRef Güth, W., Schmittberger, R., & Schwarze, B. (1982). An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 3, 367–388.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harbring, C. (2006). The effect of communication in incentive systems – An experimental study. Managerial Decision Economics, 27, 333–353.CrossRef Harbring, C. (2006). The effect of communication in incentive systems – An experimental study. Managerial Decision Economics, 27, 333–353.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harrison, G. W. (1989). Theory and misbehavior of first-price auctions. American Economic Review, 79(4), 749–762. Harrison, G. W. (1989). Theory and misbehavior of first-price auctions. American Economic Review, 79(4), 749–762.
Zurück zum Zitat Harrison, G. W. (1992). Theory and misbehavior of first-price auctions: Reply. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1426–1443. Harrison, G. W. (1992). Theory and misbehavior of first-price auctions: Reply. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1426–1443.
Zurück zum Zitat Harrison, G. W. (2007). House money effects in public good experiments: Comment. Experimental Economics, 10(4), 429–437.CrossRef Harrison, G. W. (2007). House money effects in public good experiments: Comment. Experimental Economics, 10(4), 429–437.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., & Rutström, E. E. (2009). Risk attitudes, randomization to treatment, and self-selection into experiments. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 70(3), 498–507.CrossRef Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., & Rutström, E. E. (2009). Risk attitudes, randomization to treatment, and self-selection into experiments. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 70(3), 498–507.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harrison, G. W., & List, J. A. (2004). Field experiments. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(4), 1009–1055.CrossRef Harrison, G. W., & List, J. A. (2004). Field experiments. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(4), 1009–1055.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harrison, G. W., Martínez-Correa, J., & Swarthout, J. T. (2013). Inducing risk neutral preferences with binary lotteries: A reconsideration. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 94, 145–159.CrossRef Harrison, G. W., Martínez-Correa, J., & Swarthout, J. T. (2013). Inducing risk neutral preferences with binary lotteries: A reconsideration. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 94, 145–159.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harrison, G. W., Martínez-Correa, J., & Swarthout, J. T. (2015). Reduction of compound lotteries with objective probabilities: Theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 119, 32–55.CrossRef Harrison, G. W., Martínez-Correa, J., & Swarthout, J. T. (2015). Reduction of compound lotteries with objective probabilities: Theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 119, 32–55.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harrison, G. W., & Rutström, E. E. (2008). Risk aversion in the laboratory. In J. C. Cox & G. W. Harrison (Eds.), Risk aversion in experiments (Research in Experimental Economics) (Vol. 12, pp. 41–196). Bradford: Emerald Group Publishing Limited.CrossRef Harrison, G. W., & Rutström, E. E. (2008). Risk aversion in the laboratory. In J. C. Cox & G. W. Harrison (Eds.), Risk aversion in experiments (Research in Experimental Economics) (Vol. 12, pp. 41–196). Bradford: Emerald Group Publishing Limited.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat He, S., Offerman, T., & van de Ven, J. (2016). The sources of the communication gap. Management Science, 63, 2832–2846.CrossRef He, S., Offerman, T., & van de Ven, J. (2016). The sources of the communication gap. Management Science, 63, 2832–2846.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hey, J. D. (1998). Experimental economics and deception: A comment. Journal of Economic Psychology, 19, 397–401.CrossRef Hey, J. D. (1998). Experimental economics and deception: A comment. Journal of Economic Psychology, 19, 397–401.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hey, J. D., & Orme, C. (1994). Investigating generalizations of expected utility theory using experimental data. Econometrica, 62, 1291–1326.CrossRef Hey, J. D., & Orme, C. (1994). Investigating generalizations of expected utility theory using experimental data. Econometrica, 62, 1291–1326.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., Shachat, K., & Smith, V. L. (1994). Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games and Economic Behavior, 7(3), 346–380.CrossRef Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., Shachat, K., & Smith, V. L. (1994). Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games and Economic Behavior, 7(3), 346–380.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., & Smith, V. L. (1996). On expectations and the monetary stakes in ultimatum games. International Journal of Game Theory, 25, 289–300.CrossRef Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., & Smith, V. L. (1996). On expectations and the monetary stakes in ultimatum games. International Journal of Game Theory, 25, 289–300.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92(5), 1644–1655.CrossRef Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92(5), 1644–1655.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Holt, C. A., & Smith, A. M. (2009). An update on Bayesian updating. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 69(2), 125–134.CrossRef Holt, C. A., & Smith, A. M. (2009). An update on Bayesian updating. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 69(2), 125–134.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Irlenbusch, B., & Sutter, M. (2006). An experimental analysis of voting in the Sta-bility and Growth Pact in the European Monetary Union. Public Choice, 129(3–4), 417–434.CrossRef Irlenbusch, B., & Sutter, M. (2006). An experimental analysis of voting in the Sta-bility and Growth Pact in the European Monetary Union. Public Choice, 129(3–4), 417–434.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Isaac, R. M., Walker, J. M., & Thomas, S. H. (1984). Divergent evidence on free riding: An experimental examination of possible explanations. Public Choice, 43(2), 113–149.CrossRef Isaac, R. M., Walker, J. M., & Thomas, S. H. (1984). Divergent evidence on free riding: An experimental examination of possible explanations. Public Choice, 43(2), 113–149.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Isaac, R. M., & Walker, J. M. (1988). Group size effects in public goods provision: The voluntary contributions mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103(1), 179–199.CrossRef Isaac, R. M., & Walker, J. M. (1988). Group size effects in public goods provision: The voluntary contributions mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103(1), 179–199.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ivanov, A. (2011). Attitudes to ambiguity in one-shot normal-form games: An experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior, 71(2), 366–394.CrossRef Ivanov, A. (2011). Attitudes to ambiguity in one-shot normal-form games: An experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior, 71(2), 366–394.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jamison, J., Karlan, D., & Schechter, L. (2008). To deceive or not to deceive: The effect of deception on behavior in future laboratory experiments. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 68, 477–488.CrossRef Jamison, J., Karlan, D., & Schechter, L. (2008). To deceive or not to deceive: The effect of deception on behavior in future laboratory experiments. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 68, 477–488.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kagel, J. H., & Roth, A. E. (1992). Theory and misbehavior in first-price auctions: Comment. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1379–1391. Kagel, J. H., & Roth, A. E. (1992). Theory and misbehavior in first-price auctions: Comment. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1379–1391.
Zurück zum Zitat Kamecke, U. (1997). Rotations: Matching schemes that efficiently preserve the best reply structure of a one shot game. International Journal of Game Theory, 26(3), 409–417.CrossRef Kamecke, U. (1997). Rotations: Matching schemes that efficiently preserve the best reply structure of a one shot game. International Journal of Game Theory, 26(3), 409–417.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Karni, E. (2009). A mechanism for eliciting probabilities. Econometrica, 77(2), 603–606.CrossRef Karni, E. (2009). A mechanism for eliciting probabilities. Econometrica, 77(2), 603–606.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kartik, N. (2009). Strategic communication with lying costs. The Review of Eonomic Studies, 76, 1359–1395.CrossRef Kartik, N. (2009). Strategic communication with lying costs. The Review of Eonomic Studies, 76, 1359–1395.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kimball, M. S. (1990). Precautionary saving in the small and in the large. Econometrica, 58(1), 53–73.CrossRef Kimball, M. S. (1990). Precautionary saving in the small and in the large. Econometrica, 58(1), 53–73.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kimball, M. S. (1992). Precautionary motives for holding assets. In P. Newman, M. Milgate, & J. Falwell (Eds.), The new Palgrave dictionary of money and finance (Vol. 3, pp. 158–161). London: MacMillan. Kimball, M. S. (1992). Precautionary motives for holding assets. In P. Newman, M. Milgate, & J. Falwell (Eds.), The new Palgrave dictionary of money and finance (Vol. 3, pp. 158–161). London: MacMillan.
Zurück zum Zitat Kroll, E., Morgenstern, R., Neumann, T., Schosser, S., & Vogt, B. (2014). Bargaining power does not matter when sharing losses – Experimental evidence of equal split in the Nash bargaining game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 108, 261–272.CrossRef Kroll, E., Morgenstern, R., Neumann, T., Schosser, S., & Vogt, B. (2014). Bargaining power does not matter when sharing losses – Experimental evidence of equal split in the Nash bargaining game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 108, 261–272.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kroll, S., Cherry, T. L., & Shogren, J. F. (2007). The impact of endowment heterogeneity and origin on contributions in best-shot public good games. Experimental Economics, 10(4), 411–428.CrossRef Kroll, S., Cherry, T. L., & Shogren, J. F. (2007). The impact of endowment heterogeneity and origin on contributions in best-shot public good games. Experimental Economics, 10(4), 411–428.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Krupka, E. L., & Weber, R. A. (2013). Identifying social norms using coordination games: Why does dictator game sharing vary? Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(3), 495–524.CrossRef Krupka, E. L., & Weber, R. A. (2013). Identifying social norms using coordination games: Why does dictator game sharing vary? Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(3), 495–524.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Laury, S. K., Walker, J. M., & Williams, A. W. (1995). Anonymity and the voluntary provision of public goods. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 27, 365–380.CrossRef Laury, S. K., Walker, J. M., & Williams, A. W. (1995). Anonymity and the voluntary provision of public goods. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 27, 365–380.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Levitt, S. D., & List, J. A. (2007). What do laboratory experiments measuring social preferences reveal about the real world. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21, 153–174.CrossRef Levitt, S. D., & List, J. A. (2007). What do laboratory experiments measuring social preferences reveal about the real world. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21, 153–174.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Liberman, V., Samuels, S. M., & Ross, L. (2004). The name of the game: Predictive power of reputations versus situational labels in determining prisoner’s dilemma game moves. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 30(9), 1175–1185.CrossRef Liberman, V., Samuels, S. M., & Ross, L. (2004). The name of the game: Predictive power of reputations versus situational labels in determining prisoner’s dilemma game moves. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 30(9), 1175–1185.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lichtenstein, S., & Slovic, P. (1971). Reversals of preference between bids and choices in gambling decisions. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 89(1), 46–55.CrossRef Lichtenstein, S., & Slovic, P. (1971). Reversals of preference between bids and choices in gambling decisions. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 89(1), 46–55.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat List, J. A. (2007). On the interpretation of giving in dictator games. Journal of Political Economy, 115(3), 482–493.CrossRef List, J. A. (2007). On the interpretation of giving in dictator games. Journal of Political Economy, 115(3), 482–493.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Loewenstein, G., & Issacharoff, S. (1994). Source dependence in the valuation of objects. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 7(3), 157–168.CrossRef Loewenstein, G., & Issacharoff, S. (1994). Source dependence in the valuation of objects. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 7(3), 157–168.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Loomes, G. (1999). Some lessons from past experiments and some challenges for the future. The Economic Journal, 109(453), 35–45.CrossRef Loomes, G. (1999). Some lessons from past experiments and some challenges for the future. The Economic Journal, 109(453), 35–45.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Manski, C. F. (2002). Identification of decision rules in experiments on simple games of proposal and response. European Economic Review, 46(4), 880–891.CrossRef Manski, C. F. (2002). Identification of decision rules in experiments on simple games of proposal and response. European Economic Review, 46(4), 880–891.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Marwell, G., & Ames, R. E. (1981). Economists free ride, does anyone else? Experiments on the provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 15(3), 295–310.CrossRef Marwell, G., & Ames, R. E. (1981). Economists free ride, does anyone else? Experiments on the provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 15(3), 295–310.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McDaniel, T., & Starmer, C. (1998). Experimental economics and deception: A comment. Journal of Economic Psychology, 19, 403–440.CrossRef McDaniel, T., & Starmer, C. (1998). Experimental economics and deception: A comment. Journal of Economic Psychology, 19, 403–440.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mellström, C., & Johannesson, M. (2008). Crowding out in blood donation: Was Titmuss right? Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(4), 845–863.CrossRef Mellström, C., & Johannesson, M. (2008). Crowding out in blood donation: Was Titmuss right? Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(4), 845–863.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Merlo, A., & Schotter, A. (1992). Theory and misbehavior of first-price auctions: Comment. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1413–1425. Merlo, A., & Schotter, A. (1992). Theory and misbehavior of first-price auctions: Comment. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1413–1425.
Zurück zum Zitat Merritt, A. C., Effron, D. A., & Monin, B. (2010). Moral self-licensing: When being good frees us to be bad. Social and Personality Psychology Compass, 4(5), 344–357.CrossRef Merritt, A. C., Effron, D. A., & Monin, B. (2010). Moral self-licensing: When being good frees us to be bad. Social and Personality Psychology Compass, 4(5), 344–357.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Muehlbacher, S., & Kirchler, E. (2009). Origin of endowments in public good games: The impact of effort on contributions. Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology, and Economics, 2(1), 59–67.CrossRef Muehlbacher, S., & Kirchler, E. (2009). Origin of endowments in public good games: The impact of effort on contributions. Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology, and Economics, 2(1), 59–67.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Niederle, M. (2015). Intelligent design: The relationship of economic theory to experiments: Treatment driven experiments. In G. R. Fréchette & A. Schotter (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economic methodology (pp. 104–131). Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef Niederle, M. (2015). Intelligent design: The relationship of economic theory to experiments: Treatment driven experiments. In G. R. Fréchette & A. Schotter (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economic methodology (pp. 104–131). Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nyarko, Y., & Schotter, A. (2002). An experimental study of belief learning using elicited beliefs. Econometrica, 70(3), 971–1005.CrossRef Nyarko, Y., & Schotter, A. (2002). An experimental study of belief learning using elicited beliefs. Econometrica, 70(3), 971–1005.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ockenfels, A., & Weimann, J. (1999). Types and patterns: An experimental east-west comparison of cooperation and solidarity. Journal of Public Economics, 71, 275–287.CrossRef Ockenfels, A., & Weimann, J. (1999). Types and patterns: An experimental east-west comparison of cooperation and solidarity. Journal of Public Economics, 71, 275–287.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Offerman, T. J. S., & Sonnemans, J. H. (2001). Is the quadratic scoring rule behaviorally incentive compatible?. CREED Working Paper. Offerman, T. J. S., & Sonnemans, J. H. (2001). Is the quadratic scoring rule behaviorally incentive compatible?. CREED Working Paper.
Zurück zum Zitat Offerman, T., Sonnemans, J., Van de Kuilen, G., & Wakker, P. P. (2009). A truth serum for non-bayesians: Correcting proper Scoring Rules for risk attitudes. Review of Economic Studies, 76(4), 1461–1489.CrossRef Offerman, T., Sonnemans, J., Van de Kuilen, G., & Wakker, P. P. (2009). A truth serum for non-bayesians: Correcting proper Scoring Rules for risk attitudes. Review of Economic Studies, 76(4), 1461–1489.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ortmann, A., & Hertwig, R. (2002). The costs of deception: Evidence from psychology. Experimental Economics, 5, 111–131.CrossRef Ortmann, A., & Hertwig, R. (2002). The costs of deception: Evidence from psychology. Experimental Economics, 5, 111–131.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Oxoby, R. J., & McLeish, K. N. (2004). Sequential decision and strategy vector methods in ultimatum bargaining: Evidence on the strength of other-regarding behavior. Economics Letters, 84(3), 399–405.CrossRef Oxoby, R. J., & McLeish, K. N. (2004). Sequential decision and strategy vector methods in ultimatum bargaining: Evidence on the strength of other-regarding behavior. Economics Letters, 84(3), 399–405.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Oxoby, R. J., & Spraggon, J. (2008). Mine and yours: Property rights in dictator games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 65, 703–713.CrossRef Oxoby, R. J., & Spraggon, J. (2008). Mine and yours: Property rights in dictator games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 65, 703–713.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ploner, M., & Regner, T. (2013). Self-image and moral balancing: An experimental analysis. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 93, 374–383.CrossRef Ploner, M., & Regner, T. (2013). Self-image and moral balancing: An experimental analysis. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 93, 374–383.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pruitt, D. G. (1967). Reward structure and cooperation: The decomposed Prisoner’s dilemma game. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 7, 21–25.CrossRef Pruitt, D. G. (1967). Reward structure and cooperation: The decomposed Prisoner’s dilemma game. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 7, 21–25.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rankin, F. W. (2003). Communication in ultimatum games. Economics Letters, 81(2), 267–271.CrossRef Rankin, F. W. (2003). Communication in ultimatum games. Economics Letters, 81(2), 267–271.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Riechmann, T., & Weimann, J. (2008). Competition as a coordination device: Experimental evidence from a minimum effort coordination game. European Journal of Political Economy, 24(2), 437–454.CrossRef Riechmann, T., & Weimann, J. (2008). Competition as a coordination device: Experimental evidence from a minimum effort coordination game. European Journal of Political Economy, 24(2), 437–454.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Roth, A. E. (1995). Bargaining experiments. In J. H. Kagel & A. E. Roth (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economics (pp. 253–348). Princeton: Princeton University Press. Roth, A. E. (1995). Bargaining experiments. In J. H. Kagel & A. E. Roth (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economics (pp. 253–348). Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Roth, A. E., & Malouf, M. W. (1979). Information in bargaining. Psychological Review, 86(6), 574–594.CrossRef Roth, A. E., & Malouf, M. W. (1979). Information in bargaining. Psychological Review, 86(6), 574–594.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Roux, C., & Thöni, C. (2015). Do control questions influence behavior in experiments. Experimental Economics, 18(2), 185–194.CrossRef Roux, C., & Thöni, C. (2015). Do control questions influence behavior in experiments. Experimental Economics, 18(2), 185–194.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rubinstein, A. (2006). A sceptic’s comment on the study of economics. The Economic Journal, 116, 1–9.CrossRef Rubinstein, A. (2006). A sceptic’s comment on the study of economics. The Economic Journal, 116, 1–9.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rydval, O., & Ortmann, A. (2005). Loss avoidance as selection principle: Evidence from simple stag-hunt games. Economics Letters, 88(1), 101–107.CrossRef Rydval, O., & Ortmann, A. (2005). Loss avoidance as selection principle: Evidence from simple stag-hunt games. Economics Letters, 88(1), 101–107.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sass, M., & Weimann, J. (2015). Moral self-licensing and the direct touch effect, Cesifo Working Paper 5174. Sass, M., & Weimann, J. (2015). Moral self-licensing and the direct touch effect, Cesifo Working Paper 5174.
Zurück zum Zitat Schotter, A., & Trevino, I. (2014). Belief elicitation in the laboratory. Annual Review of Economics, 6(1), 103–128.CrossRef Schotter, A., & Trevino, I. (2014). Belief elicitation in the laboratory. Annual Review of Economics, 6(1), 103–128.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Selten, R. (1967). Die Strategiemethode zur Erforschung des eingeschränkt rationalen Verhaltens im Rahmen eines Oligopolexperiments. In H. Sauermann (Hrsg.): Beiträge zur Experimentellen Wirtschaftsforschung (pp. 136–168). Tübingen: JCB Mohr (Paul Siebeck). Selten, R. (1967). Die Strategiemethode zur Erforschung des eingeschränkt rationalen Verhaltens im Rahmen eines Oligopolexperiments. In H. Sauermann (Hrsg.): Beiträge zur Experimentellen Wirtschaftsforschung (pp. 136–168). Tübingen: JCB Mohr (Paul Siebeck).
Zurück zum Zitat Selten, R., Sadrieh, A., & Abbink, K. (1999). Money does not induce risk neutral behavior, but binary lotteries do even worse. Theory and Decision, 46, 211–249.CrossRef Selten, R., Sadrieh, A., & Abbink, K. (1999). Money does not induce risk neutral behavior, but binary lotteries do even worse. Theory and Decision, 46, 211–249.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Smith, V. L. (1976). Experimental economics: Induced value theory. American Economic Review, 66(2), 274–279. Smith, V. L. (1976). Experimental economics: Induced value theory. American Economic Review, 66(2), 274–279.
Zurück zum Zitat Sturm, B., & Weimann, J. (2007). Unilateral emissions abatement: An experiment. In T. L. Cherry, J.-s. F. Shogren, & S. Kroll (Eds.), Experimental methods, environmental economics (pp. 157–183). London: Routledge. Sturm, B., & Weimann, J. (2007). Unilateral emissions abatement: An experiment. In T. L. Cherry, J.-s. F. Shogren, & S. Kroll (Eds.), Experimental methods, environmental economics (pp. 157–183). London: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Sutter, M., & Weck-Hannemann, H. (2003). Taxation and the veil of ignorance - a real effort experiment on the Laffer curve. Public Choice, 115, 217–240.CrossRef Sutter, M., & Weck-Hannemann, H. (2003). Taxation and the veil of ignorance - a real effort experiment on the Laffer curve. Public Choice, 115, 217–240.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sutter, M., & Strassmair, C. (2009). Communication, cooperation and collusion in team tournaments – An experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior, 66(1), 506–525.CrossRef Sutter, M., & Strassmair, C. (2009). Communication, cooperation and collusion in team tournaments – An experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior, 66(1), 506–525.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Trautmann, S. T., & van de Kuilen, G. (2015). Belief elicitation: A horse race among Thruth serums. The Economic Journal, 125, 2116–2135.CrossRef Trautmann, S. T., & van de Kuilen, G. (2015). Belief elicitation: A horse race among Thruth serums. The Economic Journal, 125, 2116–2135.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Vanberg, C. (2008). Why do people keep their promises? An experimental test of two explanations. Econometrica, 76(6), 1467–1480.CrossRef Vanberg, C. (2008). Why do people keep their promises? An experimental test of two explanations. Econometrica, 76(6), 1467–1480.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Van Huyck, J. B., Battalio, R. C., & Beil, R. O. (1990). Tacit coordination games, strategic uncertainty, and coordination failure. American Economic Review, 80(1), 234–248. Van Huyck, J. B., Battalio, R. C., & Beil, R. O. (1990). Tacit coordination games, strategic uncertainty, and coordination failure. American Economic Review, 80(1), 234–248.
Zurück zum Zitat Vieider, F. M. (2011). Separating real incentives and accountability. Experimental Economics, 14(4), 507–518.CrossRef Vieider, F. M. (2011). Separating real incentives and accountability. Experimental Economics, 14(4), 507–518.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Volk, S., Thöni, C., & Ruigrok, W. (2012). Temporal stability and psychological foundations of cooperation preferences. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 81(2), 664–676.CrossRef Volk, S., Thöni, C., & Ruigrok, W. (2012). Temporal stability and psychological foundations of cooperation preferences. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 81(2), 664–676.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wakker, P., & Deneffe, D. (1996). Eliciting von Neumann-Morgenstern utilities when probabilities are distorted or unknown. Management Science, 42(8), 1131–1150.CrossRef Wakker, P., & Deneffe, D. (1996). Eliciting von Neumann-Morgenstern utilities when probabilities are distorted or unknown. Management Science, 42(8), 1131–1150.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Weber, R. A. (2003). Learning’with no feedback in a competitive guessing game. Games and Economic Behavior, 44(1), 134–144.CrossRef Weber, R. A. (2003). Learning’with no feedback in a competitive guessing game. Games and Economic Behavior, 44(1), 134–144.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zizzo, D. J. (2010). Experimenter demand effects in economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 13(1), 75–98.CrossRef Zizzo, D. J. (2010). Experimenter demand effects in economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 13(1), 75–98.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Methodological Foundations
verfasst von
Joachim Weimann
Jeannette Brosig-Koch
Copyright-Jahr
2019
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-93363-4_2