Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Review of Industrial Organization 3/2021

Open Access 09.05.2020

Non-Controlling Minority Shareholdings and Collusion

verfasst von: Samuel de Haas, Johannes Paha

Erschienen in: Review of Industrial Organization | Ausgabe 3/2021

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This article merges theoretical literature on non-controlling minority shareholdings (NCMS) in a coherent model to study the effects of NCMS on competition and collusion. The model encompasses both the case of a common owner holding shares of rival firms as well as the case of cross ownership among rivals. We find that by softening competition, NCMS weaken the sustainability of collusion under a greater variety of situations than was indicated by earlier literature. Such effects exist, in particular, in the presence of an effective competition authority.
Hinweise
Earlier versions of this article were circulated under the title “Partial cross ownership and collusion”.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

1 Introduction

Corporations sometimes acquire a minority (less than 50%) equity stake in a rival firm that allows them to share in the profitability of the rival without obtaining control: The buyer acquires a passive interest; see Salop and O’Brien (2000), Tzanaki (2015), and Nain and Wang (2018) for evidence of such acquisitions. Similarly, the majority shareholder of a firm may decide to acquire a non-controlling share in a rival firm (common ownership).
Competition authorities have shown an interest in the economic effects of the acquisition of non-controlling minority shareholdings (NCMS) of both types. For example, in July 2014 the EU issued a White Paper that discusses an amendment of the current EU Merger Regulation towards assessing NCMS. Since then, especially common ownership has received increasing attention.
Theoretical literature such as Reynolds and Snapp (1986), Flath (1991), Flath (1992), Malueg (1992), and Gilo et al. (2006) has studied the effects of NCMS on firms’ profits and the sustainability of collusion under a variety of assumptions with respect to a number of key parameters such as firms’ profit function, their strategic variables (prices versus quantity), and the degree of product differentiation. This diversity of assumptions constitutes an impediment to the comparability of different articles’ results.
Our article integrates these earlier models into a more comprehensive one, which fills a gap in the literature because we analyze several combinations of assumptions that have not been studied jointly by prior literature. We also provide analytic proofs for effects that have been established only numerically by prior literature.
The model confirms two insights: First, NCMS of firm i in firm j raise firms’ profits in competition. These are the profits that are made when every firm plays its best response to the other firm’s choice of its strategic variable. But this increase in competitive profits also increases the incentive to deviate from collusion. This is because the deviator i’s profits in the punishment phase will be higher because of the reduced intensity of competition. Second, NCMS decrease firm i’s incentive to deviate because firm i (or its majority shareholder) would then receive lower dividends from the cheated firm j. Hence, minority shareholdings increase the deviation incentive if the first effect prevails over the second; as has been shown by Malueg (1992) for convex demand.
We advance the literature in two directions. First, our model is the first to study analytically how a competition authority influences the effect of minority shareholdings on the sustainability of collusion. We find that the collusion-destabilizing effect of NCMS is particularly strong in the presence of an effective competition authority. This effect can be observed even when demand is non-convex.
Second, prior literature has typically concentrated on the question of how firm i’s shares in firm j affect i’s decision whether to deviate from collusion. In addition, we show that firm j’s shareholdings in firm i destabilize collusion by raising firm i’s critical discount factor whenever the cross shareholdings raise the firms’ profits in competition. This indicates that minority shareholdings destabilize collusion under a wider set of assumption than was suggested by earlier literature.
The article is structured as follows. Section 2 shows how the present study contributes to the existing literature. Section 3 provides the model and studies the effects of NCMS on firms’ stage game profits. Section 4 analyzes the effects of NCMS on the sustainability of collusion. Section 5 adds the competition authority. Our results are robust to changes in the assumptions about firms’ profit functions, which might either model cross ownership or common ownership, as is demonstrated in Sect. 6. Section 7 concludes the article. Proofs are provided in the “Appendix”.

2 Literature Review

Reynolds and Snapp (1986) established that in a static Cournot model with symmetric firms and homogeneous products NCMS make it a best response for the firms to restrict aggregate output and raise aggregate profits.1 Malueg (1992) later extended this model to an infinitely repeated game and showed that NCMS may have an ambiguous impact on the stability of collusion by reducing the short-run gain from cheating while, at the same time, softening the long-run punishment that is imposed on the deviating firm.
In addition, Flath (1991, 1992) presented a static model to study the effects of NCMS on firms’ profits not only in Cournot competition with homogeneous products, but also in Bertrand competition with either differentiated or homogeneous products.2 Unfortunately, these results cannot be compared to those of Reynolds and Snapp (1986) or Malueg (1992). This is because Flath (1991) assumed that the firms maximize a profit function that is commonly used for cross ownership whereas Reynolds and Snapp (1986) and Malueg (1992) assume that the firms maximize a profit function that is commonly used to model common ownership. We implement our model under both assumptions to enhance comparisons of these earlier contributions.
Gilo et al. (2006) extended the model of Flath (1991) to a dynamic game, which allows them to study the effect of minority shareholdings on collusion. They focus on a Bertrand model with homogeneous products where minority shareholdings cannot raise the profits that the firms make in competition, which however played a prominent role in the analysis of Malueg (1992). We extend their model by assuming also Cournot competition and Bertrand competition with differentiated products where NCMS raise firms’ profits in competition. Contrary to Gilo et al. (2006), this points towards a variety of situations where NCMS hinder collusion.
We add a new element to this strand of the literature by assuming that a competition authority behaves along the lines of Aubert et al. (2006): Collusion may be detected with a certain probability and penalized thereafter. We show that in the presence of an effective competition authority NCMS may weaken the sustainability of collusion even under conditions where the literature cited above suggested a stabilizing effect of NCMS on collusion; for example, NCMS are found to destabilize collusion also for non-convex demand, which contributes to Malueg (1992), and even for Bertrand competition with homogeneous products, which extends the results of Gilo et al. (2006).
The present article along with the literature cited above concentrates on acquisition decisions of NCMS that are driven by the rationale of receiving a dividend and raising the acquirer’s expected profits. Karle et al. (2011) argued that NCMS may also be driven by efficiency considerations such as the generation of economies of scope in the production process. Ouimet (2013) concentrated on NCMS that are made to provide a financially constrained target firm with additional funds for solving hold-up problems when engaging in joint investment projects. López and Vives (2016) analyzed the effect of cross ownership on firms’ R&D-efforts. Our model indicates that even NCMS that were acquired to only raise the profits of the acquirer may have pro-competitive effects by disrupting collusion. To make this point most clearly we abstract from further efficiency considerations.

3 The Model

Section 3.1 presents the setup of the model. Section 3.2 establishes the effects of minority shareholdings on firms’ stage game profits.

3.1 Setup

The model assumes two cost-symmetric, risk-neutral firms \(i,j \in \lbrace 1,2\rbrace\). The majority owner of firm i may hold a minority stake \(\alpha _i\) in firm j while the majority owner of firm j may hold a minority stake \(\alpha _{j}\) in firm i. The stakes may be asymmetric \((\alpha _i\ne \alpha _{j})\), and they are assumed to have been chosen prior to the game analyzed here, which is in line with Reynolds and Snapp (1986), Malueg (1992), and Gilo et al. (2006).
The firms i and j play an infinitely repeated game with the objective of maximizing the discounted sum of their majority owners’ individual profits. The discount factors are denoted \(\delta _i,\delta _j\in (0,1)\). In each period, the firms choose a product market strategy \(s_i,s_j \in \lbrace c,k\rbrace\) with c indicating best-response behavior in the product market while k represents the collusive choice of their strategic variable. We analyze the firms’ choice of \(s_i,s_j\) in Sect. 4.
Our analysis is conducted in the three models that were studied by Flath (1991): Cournot competition; Bertrand competition with differentiated products; and Bertrand competition with homogeneous products. Therefore, the product market profit/operating profit \(\pi _i\) of firm i is a function of the firms’ strategic variables – quantities in Cournot competition, and prices in Bertrand competition – and these strategic variables are functions of firms’ endogenous choice of \(s_i,s_j\) and the exogenous shareholdings \(\alpha _i,\alpha _j\). The profits can be expressed as \(\pi _i\left( q_i(q_j,s_i,\alpha _i,\alpha _j),q_j(q_i,s_j,\alpha _j,\alpha _i)\right)\) in Cournot competition and \(\pi _i\left( p_i(p_j,s_i,\alpha _i,\alpha _j),p_j(p_i,s_j,\alpha _j,\alpha _i)\right)\) in Bertrand competition.
In Sect. 3.2, we determine the firms’ collusive strategies and their non-collusive best responses in the product market. Firms’ best responses are initially obtained under the assumption of equation (1). Firm i is assumed to maximize its majority owner’s payoff \(\tilde{\pi }_i\): Firm i’s product market profit \(\pi _i\), minus the dividend \(\alpha _j \pi _i\) that is paid to firm j, plus the dividend \(\alpha _i \pi _j\) that is received from firm j (Reynolds and Snapp 1986; Malueg 1992):
$$\begin{aligned} max\text { }\tilde{\pi }_i=(1-\alpha _{j})\pi _i+\alpha _i\pi _{j}. \end{aligned}$$
(1)
Flath (1991, 1992), Gilo et al. (2006), and Shelegia and Spiegel (2012) modeled cross ownership and used a different profit function where the firms maximize their accounting profits: \(\hat{\pi }_i=\pi _i+\alpha _i \hat{\pi _j}\). In Sect. 6, we discuss the exact interpretation of this profit function, and we show that the effects that are presented in this article are qualitatively identical for both profit functions.
Plugging the collusive strategies and competitive best responses into the profit functions for all four combinations of \(s_i,s_j\) yields values of the profits that are dependent on the value of the shareholdings \(\alpha _i\) and \(\alpha _{j}\). For reasons of conciseness, we use indices to denote the strategy combinations \((s_i,s_j)\): c for (cc); k for (kk); d if i is the deviator in (ck); and \(-d\) if i is the cheated firm in (kc). Notation is further explicated in Sect. 3.2. In the models that we analyze, the inequalities that are shown in (2) apply, which impose a prisoner’s dilemma structure on the game:
$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{i,d}>\pi _{i,k}> & {} \pi _{i,c}\ge \pi _{i,-d}\text { and }\pi _{i,d}+\pi _{i,-d}<2\pi _{i,k} \quad \text { for all } i \in \lbrace 1,2\rbrace . \end{aligned}$$
(2)
The total payoffs \(\tilde{\pi }_{i,c}\), \(\tilde{\pi }_{i,k}\), \(\tilde{\pi }_{i,d}\) of majority owner i can be expressed as in (3)-(5):
$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{\pi }_{i,c}= & {} (1-\alpha _{j})\pi _{i,c}+\alpha _i\pi _{j,c} ; \end{aligned}$$
(3)
$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{\pi }_{i,k}= & {} (1-\alpha _{j}) \pi _{i,k} +\alpha _i\pi _{j,k} ; \end{aligned}$$
(4)
$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{\pi }_{i,d}= & {} (1-\alpha _{j})\pi _{i,d}+\alpha _i\pi _{j,-d} . \end{aligned}$$
(5)

3.2 The Stage Game

This subsection establishes firms’ best responses and equilibrium profits in Cournot competition, Bertrand competition with differentiated products, and Bertrand competition with homogeneous products. It demonstrates the effects of \(\alpha _i,\alpha _j\) on the firms’ stage game profits.
Cournot competition In Cournot competition, the payoff \(\tilde{\pi }(q_i(q_j,s_i,\alpha _i,\alpha _j), q_{j}(q_i,s_j,\alpha _j,\alpha _i))\) of firm i’s majority owner, which will be abbreviated as \(\tilde{\pi }(q_i,q_{j})\), is a function of the outputs \(q_i\) and \(q_{j}\). The term \(\tilde{q}_{i}^R(q_{j},\alpha _i,\alpha _j)\) denotes firm i’s reaction function after choosing \(s_i=c\) if it maximizes payoff function \(\tilde{\pi _i}\). The arguments \(q_{j}\), \(\alpha _i\), and \(\alpha _j\) of the best-response function \(\tilde{q}_{i}^R\) are sometimes dropped for reasons of conciseness. The firms are said to compete if both play their best responses – \((s_i,s_j)=(c,c)\) – which generates the payoff \(\tilde{\pi }_i\left( \tilde{q}_i^R\left( \tilde{q}_j^R,\alpha _i,\alpha _j\right) ,\tilde{q}_{j}^R\left( \tilde{q}_i^R,\alpha _{j},\alpha _i\right) \right)\), which we abbreviate as \({\tilde{\pi }_{i,c}\left( \alpha _i,\alpha _{j}\right) }\). The discussion below relies on a result that is summarized in Lemma 1:
Lemma 1
\(\frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _i}<0\text { and }\frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}>0\text { if }\frac{\partial q_i^R}{\partial q_j}<0\).
Proof
See “Appendix 13\(\square\)
Lemma 1 implies that the product-market profits \(\pi _{i,c}\) of firm i in competition fall if the majority owner of firm i holds a higher share \(\alpha _i\) in firm j. This occurs if quantities are strategic substitutes: \(\partial q_i^R/\partial q_j<0\), with \(q_{i}^R(q_{j})=\tilde{q}_i^R(q_j,0,0)\) denoting firm i’s reaction function when \(\alpha _i,\alpha _j=0\); when maximizing product market profits \(\pi _i\) only. Firm i finds it optimal to reduce both its own output (\(\partial \tilde{q}_i^R/\partial \alpha _i<0\)) and its product-market profits \(\pi _{i,c}\) in order to raise the total payoff \(\tilde{\pi }_{i,c}\) of its majority owner by raising the other firm’s profit \(\pi _{j,c}\), so that the majority owner of firm i receives a higher dividend from firm j (Reynolds and Snapp 1986). Conversely, a higher value of \(\alpha _{j}\) raises \(\pi _{i,c}\): The product-market profits \(\pi _{i,c}\) of firm i in competition rise if the majority owner of firm j holds a higher share \(\alpha _{j}\) in firm i.
As in Malueg (1992) and Gilo et al. (2006), the firms are assumed to collude in the product market by setting a 50%-share of the monopoly output: \(q_{i,k}=q_{j,k}=Q_k/2\). Because the collusive output is independent of \(\alpha _i\) and \(\alpha _{j}\), the collusive profits are also independent of the value of shareholdings: \(\partial \pi _{i,k}/\partial \alpha _i=0\), \(\partial \pi _{i,k}/\partial \alpha _{j}=0\).
Deviation profits are defined as \({\tilde{\pi }_{i,d}(\alpha _i,\alpha _j)=\tilde{\pi }_{i}\left( \tilde{q}_i^R(q_{j,k},\alpha _i,\alpha _j),q_{j,k}\right) }\) and \({\tilde{\pi }_{j,-d}(\alpha _i,\alpha _j)=\tilde{\pi }_{j}\left( q_{j,k},\tilde{q}_i^R(q_{j,k},\alpha _i,\alpha _j)\right) }\): Firm i plays its best response while firm j sets the agreed-upon output. Lemma 2 establishes the effect of \(\alpha _i\) on the product market profits in a deviation period:
Lemma 2
\(\frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _i}<0\text { and }\frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _i}>0\).
Proof
See “Appendix 1”. \(\square\)
If firm i deviates from collusion, its majority owner receives a lower dividend from firm j as compared to continued collusion (\(\alpha _i\pi _{j,-d}<\alpha _i\pi _{j,k}\)). The higher is the value of \(\alpha _i\) the stronger is this effect, and the lower is the payoff \(\tilde{\pi }_{i,d}\) that the majority owner of firm i earns after the payment of dividends. Accordingly, minority shareholdings \(\alpha _i>0\) induce the deviating firm i to set a lower deviation quantity than with \(\alpha _i=0\) and, thus, to earn lower deviation profits in the product market. This leaves higher profits for firm j: \(\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i>0\).
Bertrand competition with differentiated products Similar effects are found when we assume Bertrand competition with differentiated products. The payoff \(\tilde{\pi }(p_i,p_{j})\) of firm i’s majority shareholder is a function of the prices \(p_i\) and \(p_{j}\) of the two firms. Let \(\tilde{p}_i^R(p_{j},\alpha _i,\alpha _j)\) denote the best-response function of firm i after choosing \(s_i=c\). The firms compete when both play their best responses, making profits \({\tilde{\pi }_{i,c}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})=\tilde{\pi }_i\left( \tilde{p}_i^R\left( \tilde{p}_j^R,\alpha _i,\alpha _j\right) ,\tilde{p}_{j}^R\left( \tilde{p}_i^R,\alpha _{j},\alpha _i\right) \right) }\). Our analysis relies on Lemma 3:
Lemma 3
\(\frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}>0 \text { and } \frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _i} \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} >0 &{} \text {if } \alpha _i< \alpha _{j}+A \\ \le 0 &{} \text {if } \alpha _i\ge \alpha _{j}+A . \end{array} \right.\)
Proof
See “Appendix 1”. \(\square\)
As compared to Cournot competition, firm i’s competitive profit rises even for unilateral increases of its share \(\alpha _i\) in firm j as long as the shares are not too asymmetric: \({\alpha _i< \alpha _{j}+A}\). The exact value of the threshold A depends on the functional form of demand as is shown in the proof of Lemma 3. This effect emerges because in a Bertrand model with differentiated products prices are strategic complements. Shareholdings \(\alpha _i\) induce firm i to raise its price, and firm j follows suit. Therefore, even a somewhat asymmetric increase in \(\alpha _i\) may cause an increase in both firms’ profits. However, for \(\alpha _i\ge \alpha _j+A\) the reduction in output that results from the higher prices becomes the dominant force, which leads to \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i\le 0\).
The firms are assumed to collude in the product market by setting the same prices \(p_{i,k}\) and \(p_{j,k}\) that a jointly profit-maximizing monopolist would set. These prices are independent of \(\alpha _i\) and \(\alpha _{j}\), which implies \(\partial \pi _{i,k}/\partial \alpha _i=0\) and \(\partial \pi _{i,k}/\partial \alpha _{j}=0\). The deviation payoffs are defined as \(\tilde{\pi }_{i,d}(\alpha _i,\alpha _j)=\tilde{\pi }_{i}\left( \hat{p}_i^R(p_{j,k},\alpha _i,\alpha _j),p_{j,k}\right)\) and \(\tilde{\pi }_{j,-d}(\alpha _i,\alpha _j)=\tilde{\pi }_{j}\left( p_{j,k},\tilde{p}_i^R(p_{j,k},\alpha _i,\alpha _j)\right)\). “Appendix 1” shows that Lemma 2 (\({\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _i<0}\) and \({\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i>0}\)) applies also in Bertrand competition with differentiated products.
Bertrand competition with homogeneous products In Bertrand competition with homogeneous products “both firms set prices equal to marginal cost regardless of the state of any partial cross shareholding” (Flath 1991): The firms make zero profits (\({\pi _{i,c}=0}\), \({\pi _{j,c}=0}\), \({\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i=0}\), and \({\partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _i=0}\)), and minority shareholdings have no effect on firms’ profits in competition. Similarly, the collusive and the deviation profits are also independent of the value of minority shareholdings: \({\partial \pi _{i,k}/\partial \alpha _i=0}\); \({\partial \pi _{j,k}/\partial \alpha _i=0}\); \({\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _i=0}\); \({\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i=0}\). A deviating firm would cut the collusive price marginally and earn \({\pi _{i,d}=2\pi _{i,k}}\), while the betrayed firm would earn \(\pi _{j,-d}=0\).

4 The Dynamic Game

Using the framework introduced in Sect. 3, we study the effects of NCMS on the sustainability of collusion. Section 4.1 points out the forces that determine the effect of \(\alpha _i\) on the critical discount factor \(\tilde{\delta }_i^*\) in a general model. Section 4.2 applies this analysis to specific models of competition. Section 4.3 analyzes how minority shareholdings \(\alpha _{j}\) of firm j’s majority shareholder in firm i affect the critical discount factor \(\tilde{\delta }_i^*\) of firm i.

4.1 The Critical Discount Factor

Collusion is profitable for the firms if inequality (6) is satisfied. Collusion is sustainable if inequality (7) applies:
$$\begin{aligned}&\pi _{i,k}-\pi _{i,c}>0 \quad \forall \quad i \in \lbrace 1,2 \rbrace ; \end{aligned}$$
(6)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\tilde{\pi }_{i,k}}{1-\delta _i}>\tilde{\pi }_{i,d}+\frac{\delta _i}{1-\delta _i}\tilde{\pi }_{i,c} \quad \forall \quad i \in \lbrace 1,2 \rbrace . \end{aligned}$$
(7)
In line with Malueg (1992), Aubert et al. (2006), and Gilo et al. (2006), the present value of deviation payoffs–the right-hand side of (7)–assumes a grim trigger strategy (Friedman 1971). With the use of equation (1), \(\tilde{\pi }_i=(1-\alpha _j)\pi _i+\alpha _i\pi _{j}\), the sustainability constraint (7) can be solved for the critical value \(\tilde{\delta }_i^*\) of the discount factor as is shown in equation (8). For individual discount factors above this threshold, collusion is a stable outcome:
$$\begin{aligned} \delta _i>\frac{(1-\alpha _{j})(\pi _{i,d}-\pi _{i,k})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,k})}{(1-\alpha _{j})(\pi _{i,d}-\pi _{i,c})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,c})}\equiv \tilde{\delta }_i^* . \end{aligned}$$
(8)
Proposition 1 establishes under which condition the critical discount factor rises in the value of minority shareholdings \(\alpha _i\):
Proposition 1
The inequality \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _i>0\) applies if inequality (9) is satisfied:
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{(1-\alpha _{j}) \left[ (\pi _{j,k}-\pi _{j,c})\pi _{i,d} - (\pi _{i,k}-\pi _{i,c})\pi _{j,-d} - (\pi _{i,c}-\pi _{j,c})\pi _{i,k} \right] }{(1-\alpha _{j})(\pi _{i,d}-\pi _{i,k})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,k})} \\ < (1-\alpha _{j}) \frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _i} + \alpha _i \frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _i} . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(9)
Proof
See “Appendix 2”. \(\square\)
To interpret condition (9), higher shareholdings \(\alpha _i\) have two effects on the sustainability of collusion:
Effect 1: Malueg (1992) argued that higher shareholdings have a destabilizing effect on collusion by increasing firms’ profits in competition and, thus, reducing the grim trigger punishment \(\pi _{i,c}-\pi _{i,k}\) that follows a deviation. This can be inferred from the right-hand side of (9), which captures the elevating effect of minority shareholdings on firms’ profits in competition. One finds \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _i>0\) when the right-hand side of inequality (9) is sufficiently high.
Effect 2: NCMS also have a stabilizing effect on collusion. If firm i deviates, the profits of firm j fall from \(\pi _{j,k}\) to \(\pi _{j,-d}\). This reduces the dividend that firm j pays to the majority owner of firm i. In absolute terms, this reduction of the dividend is stronger if the majority owner of firm i holds a greater share \(\alpha _i\) in firm j. This makes firm i more reluctant to deviate because \(\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,k})\) in the denominator of the left-hand side of (9) measures the loss of dividends that are received from firm j if firm i deviates. A higher value of \(\alpha _i\) raises the left-hand side of (9) and, thus, contributes to situations with \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _i<0\).

4.2 The Sustainability of Collusion in Different Models of Competition

This subsection explores the effect of minority shareholdings on the stability of collusion by exploring the relative strength of Effect 1 and Effect 2 in different models of competition.
Cournot competition In Cournot competition, an asymmetric increase in the shareholdings \(\alpha _i\) cannot destabilize collusion by raising \(\tilde{\delta }_i^*\) (Lemma 4), yet a symmetric increase can have this destabilizing effect (Lemma 5).
Lemma 4
In Cournot competition with \(\partial q_j^R/\partial q_i<0\), one finds that \((1-\alpha _j)\cdot \partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i+\alpha _i \cdot \partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _{i}<0\).
Proof
See “Appendix 2”. \(\square\)
Lemma 1 established that in Cournot competition firm i would want to reduce its output and, thus, soften competition if its majority shareholder acquires shares \(\alpha _i\) of its rival j. Because of the strategic substitutability of quantities \((\partial q_j^R/\partial q_i<0)\), firm j would however react by expanding its output, which leads to \({\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i<0}\) and \({\partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _{i}>0}\). Because firm i’s majority shareholder participates more in the decline of firm i’s profits than in the increasing profits of j, \((1-\alpha _j)>\alpha _i\), one finds that \((1-\alpha _j)\cdot \partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i+\alpha _i \cdot \partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _{i}<0\). Therefore, inequality (9) would be violated, which implies \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _i<0\).
Lemma 5 shows that this is different if the firms choose symmetric shareholdings and also if any increase in the shareholdings is symmetric: \(\alpha _i=\alpha _j=\alpha \text { } \forall \text { } \alpha _i,\alpha _j\).
Lemma 5
In Cournot competition with \(\partial q_j^R/\partial q_i<0\) and \(\alpha _i=\alpha _j=\alpha \text { } \forall \text { } \alpha _i,\alpha _j\), one finds that \({(1-\alpha )\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha +\alpha \cdot \partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha >0}\).
Proof
See “Appendix 2”. \(\square\)
The inequality \((1-\alpha )\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha +\alpha \cdot \partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha >0\) for symmetric increases of the shareholdings is a prerequisite for the destabilizing effect of NCMS on collusion as was shown by Malueg (1992). If the firms raise their shares in each other symmetrically, both firms’ profits \(\pi _{i,c},\pi _{j,c}\) rise. This reduces the loss that is inflicted on a firm by grim trigger punishments and contributes to raising the critical discount factor \(\tilde{\delta }_i^*\).
Bertrand competition with differentiated products Collusion-destabilizing effects of NCMS – \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _i>0\) – are more likely in Bertrand competition with differentiated products than in Cournot competition. This is because in Bertrand competition with differentiated products even asymmetric increases of \(\alpha _i\) may raise the right-hand side of inequality (9) as was shown by Lemma 3. This finding suggests that the pro-competitive effects of NCMS are even more prevalent than was suggested by Malueg’s (1992) seminal contribution.
Bertrand competition with homogeneous products NCMS do not have an impact on firms’ profits under the assumption of price competition with homogeneous products: \({\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i=0}, {\partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _{j}=0}\). Therefore, the right-hand side of inequality (9) takes a value of zero, which implies \(\partial \delta _i^*/\partial \alpha _i<0 \text { } \forall \text { } \alpha _i\). This result is in line with the finding of Gilo et al. (2006), who showed that under the assumption of Bertrand competition with homogeneous products “an increase in firm [i]’s stake in firm [j] never hinders tacit collusion”.4

4.3 The Effect of \(\alpha _{j}\) on \(\tilde{\delta }_i^*\)

The previous analysis was concerned with the effects of the stake \(\alpha _i\), which firm i’s majority shareholder possesses in firm j, on i’s critical discount factor \(\tilde{\delta }_i^*\). Proposition 2 goes beyond the prior literature by showing under what condition the stake \(\alpha _j\) of firm j’s majority stakeholder in firm i makes collusion harder to sustain by increasing firm i’s critical discount factor \(\tilde{\delta }_i^*\):
Proposition 2
The inequality \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _{j}>0\) applies if inequality (10) is satisfied:
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{\alpha _i \left[ (\pi _{j,k}-\pi _{j,c}) \pi _{i,d} - (\pi _{i,k}-\pi _{i,c})\pi _{j,-d} - (\pi _{i,c}-\pi _{j,c})\pi _{i,k}+(\pi _{i,k}-\pi _{j,k})\pi _{i,c}\right] }{(1-\alpha _{j})(\pi _{i,d}-\pi _{i,k})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,k})} \\ < (1-\alpha _{j}) \frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} + \alpha _i \frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(10)
Proof
See “Appendix 2”. \(\square\)
The inequality \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_{i}^*/\partial \alpha _{j}>0\), which results if inequality (10) applies, is a result of firm j’s incentive to soften competition after its majority shareholder acquires shares of firm i. This raises the profits that are made by both firms when competing, and it thus softens the grim trigger punishments, which makes it more attractive for firm i to deviate.
Note that inequality (10) in Proposition 2 is easier to satisfy than inequality (9) in Proposition 1. This can be seen particularly well when starting from a situation of symmetry (\(\alpha _i=\alpha _j\)) before analyzing an asymmetric expansion of \(\alpha _j\). Symmetry causes \(\pi _{i,c}-\pi _{j,c}=0\), \(\pi _{i,k}-\pi _{j,k}=0\), \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i=\partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _j\) and \(\partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _i=\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _j\). Together with \(\alpha _i<1-\alpha _j\), these equalities can be used to show that the right-hand side of (10) is weakly greater than that of (9).
Taken together, this causes \(\tilde{\delta }_i^*\) to be increased more easily by an increase in \(\alpha _j\) than by an increase in \(\alpha _i\). Because earlier literature focused on \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _{i}\), Proposition 2 implies that a collusion-destabilizing effect of minority shareholdings occurs under a wider set of conditions than was predicted by this earlier literature.

5 Competition Authority

As a further addition to prior literature, we merge our model with that of Aubert et al. (2006) to study the effect of a competition authority on the stability of collusion in the presence of common ownership. This is modeled by assuming that the competition authority detects a collusive agreement with probability \(\rho\) in every period and then imposes a fine F on every colluding firm.
Proposition 3 demonstrates the main result of this section: The collusion-destabilizing effect of common ownership is further enhanced by \(\rho F>0\).
Proposition 3
Given the detection probability \(\rho\) and fine F, the critical discount factor takes the functional form shown in (11). Inequality \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _i>0\) applies if inequality (12) is satisfied, which is easier to satisfy than the corresponding inequality (9) for \(\rho F=0\):
$$\begin{aligned}&\tilde{\delta }_i^*\equiv \frac{(1-\alpha _{j})(\pi _{i,d}-\pi _{i,k})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,k})}{(1-\alpha _{j})(\pi _{i,d}-\rho F-\pi _{i,c})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\rho F-\pi _{j,c})} ; \end{aligned}$$
(11)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{({1}-\alpha _{j}) \left[ (\pi _{j,k}-\rho F-\pi _{j,c})\pi _{i,d} - (\pi _{i,k}-\rho F-\pi _{i,c})\pi _{j,-d} -\, (\pi _{i,c}-\pi _{j,c})\pi _{i,k} \right]} {(1-\alpha _{j})(\pi _{i,d}-\pi _{i,k})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,k})}\nonumber \\ < (1-\alpha _{j}) \frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _i} + \alpha _i \frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _i} . \end{aligned}$$
(12)
Proof
See “Appendix 3”.
Proposition 3 suggests that \(\rho F>0\) makes minority shareholdings more likely to destabilize collusion. This is because the competition authority imposes a fine not only on firm i but also on firm j. This causes the expected dividend income of firm i’s minority shareholder to be low whether the firm adheres to the collusive agreement or not, which makes a deviation relatively more profitable for firm i. Mathematically, \(\rho F>0\) decreases the left-hand side of (12), which makes it more likely to find \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^* / \partial \alpha _i>0\).

6 Cross Ownership

Up to this point, we have relied on profit function (1): \(\tilde{\pi }_i=(1-\alpha _j)\pi _i+\alpha _i\pi _{j}\). The payoff \(\tilde{\pi }_i\) models the income of a common shareholder who possesses a majority share \(1-\alpha _j\) of firm i and a minority share \(\alpha _i\) of firm j.
A different profit function was used, for example, by Flath (1991), Gilo et al. (2006), and Shelegia and Spiegel (2012), which is shown in (13):
$$\begin{aligned} max\text { }\hat{\pi }_i=\pi _i+\alpha _i\hat{\pi }_{j} . \end{aligned}$$
(13)
The profit \(\hat{\pi }_i\) models firm i’s profit as it appears in its income statement: its operating profit \(\pi _i\) plus its investment income \(\alpha _i \hat{\pi }_j\). This profit function is typically used when modeling the effect of cross ownership, with \(\alpha _i\) denoting the share of firm i in firm j. An overview about the literature that surrounds the interpretation of profit functions (1) and (13) was given by Schmalz (2018).
In “Appendix 4”, we show that only the functional form but not the economic interpretation of our results changes if one instead assumes profit function (13). As above, the critical discount factor is shown to rise in \(\alpha _i\) and (even more easily) in \(\alpha _j\) if the NCMS raise firms’ profits in competition sufficiently strongly. A high value of the expected fine facilitates these situations.

7 Conclusion

This article presents a framework for the analysis of collusion in the presence of common ownership or cross ownership. We combined the established models of Reynolds and Snapp (1986), Flath (1991, 1992), Malueg (1992), and Gilo et al. (2006). These earlier contributions had not always been easy to compare: First, because they used different profit functions. Second, some combinations of assumptions had so far remained unexplored. Third, they sometimes relied on numerical proofs. We fill these gaps in the literature by studying the ‘missing’ combinations of assumptions and thus improving the comparability of these earlier contributions. The properties of our model are proven analytically. Additionally, we extend this literature by adding a competition authority (Aubert et al. 2006) and analyzing the effect of firm i’s shareholdings on the critical discount factor of firm j.
Malueg (1992) pointed out that NCMS raise the profits that firms make when competing, which contributes to weakening the sustainability of collusion. Our study indicates that NCMS weaken the sustainability of collusion under an even greater variety of circumstances than was acknowledged by this earlier literature.
The integrated framework that we proposed in this article establishes a basis for further theoretical extensions. For example, it will be interesting to endogenize firms’ decisions to acquire NCMS. The firms might decide about splitting the collusive profits unequally or making side payments, which might be necessary if the firms were asymmetric in costs. Future work should extend our duopoly model to the case of n firms and, additionally, explore the impact of other than grim trigger punishments. Several approaches have been proposed for modeling the effect of competition authorities on collusion among independent firms (see Harrington (2017) for a review), which may now also be applied to the study of collusion in the presence of common ownership or cross ownership.

Acknowledgements

Open Access funding provided by Projekt DEAL. We would like to thank Lawrence J. White (the editor) and two anonymous referees for helping us to improve this article greatly. Earlier versions were discussed with great care by Iwan Bos, Carsten Crede, Georg Götz, Daniel Herold, Inés Pérez-Soba Aguilar, and Yossi Spiegel. We are also grateful for the comments provided by the participants of the MaCCI (Mannheim, 2015), CISS (Marmaris, 2015), ERSA (Cape Town, 2015), EALE (Vienna, 2015), EARIE (Lisbon, 2016), Verein für Socialplitik (Augsburg, 2016) conferences, and a seminar held at the Düsseldorf Institute for Competition Economics (2016).
Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Anhänge

Appendix to Section 3

The following proofs assume that the firms produce subject to constant marginal costs taking a value of zero.
Proof
Lemma 1 proposes \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i<0\text { and }\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _{j}>0\) for Cournot competition with \(\partial q_i^R/\partial q_j<0\) and profit function (1). To prove this, reaction function (A.3) is determined by deriving profit function (A.1) for \(q_i\) and solving first-order condition (A.2) for \(q_i\), while we define \(q_i^R(q_j)=\tilde{q}_i^R(q_j,0,0)\):
$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{\pi }_{i}= & {} (1-\alpha _j)p(q_i,q_{j})q_i+\alpha _i p(q_i,q_{j})q_{j} ; \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \tilde{\pi }_{i}}{\partial q_i}= & {} (1-\alpha _j)\left[ \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i} q_i+p(q_i,q_{j})\right] +\alpha _i\frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_{j}=0 ; \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \tilde{q}_{i}^R(q_{j},\alpha _i,\alpha _j) = q_{i}^R(q_{j})-\frac{\alpha _i}{1-\alpha _j} \theta q_{j} . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)
The variable \(\theta\) is a scaling factor with \(0<\theta <1\). For a specific homogeneous products demand curve \(p=(1-q_i-q_{j})^x\) with \(x>0\) (Malueg 1992) one finds \(\theta =x/(1+x)\), and one can show that \({-1<\partial q_{i}^R/\partial q_{j}<0}\). Given \(\partial q_i^R/\partial q_j<0\), equation (A.3) implies \(\partial \tilde{q}_i^R/\partial q_j<0\) and, thus, \(\partial \tilde{q}_j^R/\partial q_i<0\).
To prove \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i<0\), note that equation (A.3) implies \(\tilde{q}_i^R(q_j,\alpha _i,\alpha _j)<q_i^R(q_j)\) for an unchanged value of \(q_j\). Because of \(\partial \tilde{q}_j^R/\partial q_i<0\) firm j will optimally expand its output, which causes firm i to contract its output even further. This implies that \(\tilde{q}_i^R(\tilde{q}_j^R,\alpha _i,\alpha _j)<q_i^R(q_j^R)\) and \(\tilde{q}_j^R(\tilde{q}_i^R,\alpha _j,\alpha _i)>q_j^R(q_i^R)\), \(\partial \tilde{q}_i^R/\partial \alpha _i<0\) and \(\partial \tilde{q}_j^R/\partial \alpha _i>0\). Firm i’s product market profit is reduced by selling a lower than the optimal quantity \(\tilde{q}_i^R<q_i^R\) while firm j raises its output, which implies and proves \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i<0\).
Because the output reduction of firm i exceeds the output expansion of firm j the equilibrium price rises: From \({-1<\partial \tilde{q}_{j}^R/\partial q_{i}}\) it follows that \(\partial \tilde{q}_{j}^R/\partial \alpha _i=(\partial \tilde{q}_{j}^R/\partial q_i) \cdot (\partial \tilde{q}_{i}^R/\partial \alpha _i) <-\partial \tilde{q}_{i}^R/\partial \alpha _i\), such that \({\partial (\tilde{q}_{i}^R+\tilde{q}_{j}^R)/\partial \alpha _i}<0\) and \(\partial p(\tilde{q}_{i}^R+\tilde{q}_{j}^R)/\partial \alpha _i>0\). Combining \(\partial p(\tilde{q}_{i}^R+\tilde{q}_{j}^R)/\partial \alpha _i>0\) and \(\partial \tilde{q}_{j}^R/\partial \alpha _i>0\) proves that \(\partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _{i}>0\) for Cournot competition and profit function (1). \(\square\)
Proof
Lemma 2 proposes for Cournot competition that \(\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _i<0\) and \(\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i>0\). Firm j keeps its output \(q_{j,-d}=q_{j,k}\) constant by assumption: \(\partial q_{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i=0\). Reaction function (A.3) with \({\partial \tilde{q}_{i}^R(q_{j,-d},\alpha _i,\alpha _j)/\partial \alpha _i<0}\) causes \(\partial (q_{j,-d}+\tilde{q}_{i}^R(q_{j,-d},\alpha _i,\alpha _j))/\partial \alpha _i<0\) and thus \(\partial p_d/\partial \alpha _i>0\). This proves that \({\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i=(\partial p_d/\partial \alpha _i) \cdot q_{j,-d}>0}\). Inequality \(\partial \tilde{q}_{i}^R(q_{j,-d},\alpha _i,\alpha _j)/\partial \alpha _i<0\) also implies that with \(\alpha _i>0\) firm i sets a lower output as in a case with \(\alpha _i,\alpha _j=0\), i.e., \(\tilde{q}_{i}^R(q_{j,-d},\alpha _i,\alpha _j)<q_{i}^R(q_{j,-d})\), which causes \({\pi _i(\tilde{q}_{i}^R,q_{j,-d})<\pi _i(q_{i}^R,q_{j,-d})}\). This proves \(\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _i<0\). \(\square\)
Proof
Lemma 3 proposes for Bertrand competition with differentiated products that \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i>0 \text { if } \alpha _i<\alpha _{j}+A\), \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i\le 0 \text { if } \alpha _i\ge \alpha _{j}+A\), and \({\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _{j}>0}\). The term \(\tilde{p}_{i}^R(p_{j},\alpha _i,\alpha _j)\) in equation (A.6) denotes the reaction function of firm i, and it is determined by maximizing profit function (A.4) with respect to \(p_i\). Equation (A.5) presents the first-order condition. The term \(p_{i}^R(p_{j})\) in (A.6) denotes the reaction function if firm i maximizes its own product market profits \(\pi _i\) only, i.e., \(p_{i}^R(p_{j})=\tilde{p}_{i}^R(p_{j},0,0)\):
$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{\pi }_{i}= & {} (1-\alpha _{j})q_i(p_i,p_{j})p_i+\alpha _i q_{j}(p_j,p_i)p_{j} ; \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \tilde{\pi }_{i}}{\partial p_i}= & {} (1-\alpha _j)\left[ \frac{\partial q_i}{\partial p_i} p_i+q_i(p_i,p_{j})\right] +\alpha _i\frac{\partial q_{j}}{\partial p_i}p_{j}=0 ; \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)
$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{p}_{i}^R(p_j,\alpha _i,\alpha _j)= & {} p_i^R(p_{j})+\frac{\alpha _i}{1-\alpha _j} B p_{j} . \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)
For a specific demand function such as \(q_i=1-p_i+\beta p_{j}\) with \({0<\beta <1}\), one can prove that \({0<\partial p_{i}^R/\partial p_{j}<1}\), and one finds that \(B=\beta /2>0\). Equation (A.6) indicates that \(\partial \tilde{p}_{i}^R/\partial \alpha _i>0\) for a given value of \(p_j\). Moreover, firm i will increase its price if firm j acquires shares of firm i, i.e., \(\partial \tilde{p}_{i}^R/\partial \alpha _{j}\), which can be written as in (A.7):
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \tilde{p}_{i}^R(\tilde{p}_j^R,\alpha _i,\alpha _j)}{\partial \alpha _{j}} = \frac{\partial p_i^R}{\partial p_{j}} \cdot \frac{\partial \tilde{p}_{j}^R}{\partial \alpha _{j}} + \frac{\alpha _i B p_j}{(1-\alpha _j)^2} + \frac{\alpha _i B}{1-\alpha _j} \cdot \frac{\partial \tilde{p}_{j}^R}{\partial \alpha _{j}} . \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)
Given (A.7), \(\partial p_i^R/\partial p_{j}>0\), and \(\partial \tilde{p}_{j}^R/\partial \alpha _{j}>0\), one finds that \(\partial \tilde{p}_{i}^R/\partial \alpha _{j}>0\) and, accordingly, \(\partial \tilde{p}_{j}^R/\partial \alpha _{i}>0\). For \(q_i=1-p_i+\beta p_{j}\) one can show that \(\partial \tilde{p}_{j}^R/\partial \alpha _{i}<\partial \tilde{p}_{i}^R/\partial \alpha _{i}\) and \(\partial q_i(\tilde{p}_i^R,\tilde{p}_{j}^R)/\partial \alpha _i<0\) apply. Because of \(\partial \tilde{p}_{j}^R/\partial \alpha _{j}>0\) after firm j acquires shares \(\alpha _{j}\) of firm i, the output and profit of firm i would rise even when holding its own price constant. Firm i will only raise its price (\(\partial \tilde{p}_{j}^R/\partial p_{j}>0\)) if this raises its profit even further, which proves \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _{j}>0\).
Yet, the inequalities \(\partial \tilde{p}_{i}^R/\partial \alpha _{i}>0\) and \(\partial q_i(\tilde{p}_i^R,\tilde{p}_{j}^R)/\partial \alpha _i<0\) suggest an ambiguous effect on the profits of firm i \((\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i\lesseqgtr 0)\). For proving that \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i>0 \text { if } \alpha _i<\alpha _{j}+A\), one has to assume a specific functional form for demand: We use \(q_i=1-p_i+\beta p_{j}\).5 The price and profit of firm i in the product market-equilibrium are then shown in (A.8) and (A.9):
$$\begin{aligned}&\tilde{p}_i^R\left( \tilde{p}_{j}^R ,\alpha _i,\alpha _j \right) = \frac{2+\left( \frac{1+(\alpha _i-\alpha _j)}{1-\alpha _j}\right) \beta }{4-\left( \frac{1+(\alpha _i-\alpha _j)}{1-\alpha _j}\right) \beta ^2 \left( \frac{1-(\alpha _i-\alpha _j)}{1-\alpha _i}\right) } ; \end{aligned}$$
(A.8)
$$\begin{aligned}&\pi _{i,c} = \pi _i\left( \tilde{p}_i^R,\tilde{p}_{j}^R\right) = q_i(\tilde{p}_i^R,\tilde{p}_j^R) \tilde{p}_i^R =(1-\tilde{p}_i^R+\beta \tilde{p}_{j}^R) \tilde{p}_i^R . \end{aligned}$$
(A.9)
Ideally, one would want to plug \(\tilde{p}_i^R\) and \(\tilde{p}_j^R\) into (A.9), determine \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i\) and solve inequality \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i>0\) for \(\alpha _i\), which would yield a term \(\alpha _i<\alpha _j+A\). Yet, the threshold A proves to be a highly nonlinear and lengthy function of \(\alpha _j\) and \(\beta\).
We thus resort to a more subtle proof: The condition \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i>0\) can be stated as in (A.10).
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _i}= & {} \left( -\frac{\partial \tilde{p}_i^R}{\partial \alpha _i} + \beta \frac{\partial \tilde{p}_j^R}{\partial \alpha _i}\right) \tilde{p}_i^R\nonumber \\&+ \left( 1-\tilde{p}_i^R+\beta \tilde{p}_j^R \right) \frac{\partial \tilde{p}_i^R}{\partial \alpha _i}> 0 \nonumber \\ {}&\frac{1+\beta \tilde{p}_j^R}{2-\left( \frac{\partial \tilde{p}_j^R/\partial \alpha _i}{\partial \tilde{p}_i^R/\partial \alpha _i}\right) \beta } > \tilde{p}_i^R \end{aligned}$$
(A.10)
When holding \(\alpha _j\) constant, a unilateral increase in \(\alpha _i\) increases \(\pi _{i,c}\) as long as \(\tilde{p}_i^R\) is smaller than the left-hand side of (A.10). Because of \(\partial \tilde{p}_{i}^R/\partial \alpha _{i}>\partial \tilde{p}_{j}^R/\partial \alpha _{i}\) an increase in \(\alpha _i\) increases \(\tilde{p}_i^R\) more strongly than the left-hand side of (A.10), so that \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i\le 0\) will apply once reaching or exceeding the tipping point \(\alpha _i\ge \alpha _j+A\). It can be seen that \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i>0\) is a consequence of the strategic complementarity of prices: Inequality (A.10) is more easily satisfied for higher values of both \(\partial \tilde{p}_j^R/\partial \alpha _i\) and \(\beta\). \(\square\)
Proof
Lemma 2 proposes for Bertrand competition with differentiated products \(\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _i<0\text { and }\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i>0\). The assumption \(p_{j,-d}=p_{j,k}\) implies \(\partial p_{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i=0\). Reaction function (A.6) causes a higher deviation price (\(\partial \tilde{p}_i^R(p_{j,-d},\alpha _i,\alpha _j)/\partial \alpha _i>0\)) in the presence of minority shareholdings and thus less business stealing (\(\partial q_{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i>0\)). This proves \(\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i=(\partial q_{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i)\cdot p_{j,-d}>0\). Finding \(\partial \tilde{p}_i^R(p_{j,-d},\alpha _i,\alpha _j)/\partial \alpha _i>0\) also implies that with \(\alpha _i>0\) firm i sets a higher than the profit-maximizing price \(p_{i}^R(p_{j,-d})<\tilde{p}_{i}^R(p_{j,-d},\alpha _i,\alpha _j)\), which causes \(\pi _i(p_{i}^R,p_{j,-d})>\pi _i(\tilde{p}_{i}^R,p_{j,-d})\). This proves \(\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _i<0\). \(\square\)

Appendix to Section 4

The proof of Proposition 1 relies on Lemma 6:
Lemma 6
\((1-\alpha _{j})\frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _i}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _i}=0\).
Proof
For Cournot competition with homogeneous products, the equality stated in Lemma 6 can be restated as in (B.1):
$$\begin{aligned} (1-\alpha _{j})\frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _i}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _i}=\frac{\partial q_i}{\partial \alpha _i}\left[ (1-\alpha _{j})\left( \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_i+p\right) +\alpha _i\frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_{j} \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(B.1)
The bracketed term on the right-hand side of equation (B.1) is the same as the bracketed term in first-order condition (A.2) that takes a value of zero in the optimum. For Bertrand competition with differentiated products, the equality stated in Lemma 6 can be restated as in (B.2):
$$\begin{aligned} (1-\alpha _j)\frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _i}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _i}=\frac{\partial p_i^R}{\partial \alpha _i}\left[ (1-\alpha _{j})\left( \frac{\partial q_i}{\partial p_i}p_i+q_i\right) +\alpha _i\left( \frac{\partial q_{j}}{\partial p_i}q_{j} \right) \right] =0. \end{aligned}$$
(B.2)
The bracketed term on the right-hand side of equation (B.2) is the same as the bracketed term in first-order condition (A.5) that takes a value of zero in the optimum. Section 3.2 established that \(\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _i=0\) and \(\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i=0\) for Bertrand competition with homogeneous products, which proves \((1-\alpha _j)(\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _i)+\alpha _i(\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i)=0\). \(\square\)
Proof
To determine \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _i>0\) (Proposition 1), re-write \(\tilde{\delta }_i^*\) as follows:
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \tilde{\delta }_i^*&=\frac{u(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}{v(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}\\ \text {with }u(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})&=(1-\alpha _{j})(\pi _{i,d}-\pi _{i,k})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,k})>0\\ \text {and }v(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})&=(1-\alpha _{j})(\pi _{i,d}-\pi _{i,c})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,c})>0 . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(B.3)
If we use \(\partial \pi _{i,k}/\partial \alpha _i=\partial \pi _{j,k}/\partial \alpha _i=0\) and \((1-\alpha _j)(\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _i)+\alpha _i(\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i)=0\) from Lemma 6, \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _i\) can be written as in (B.4):
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*}{\partial \alpha _i}&=\frac{\frac{\partial u(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _i}\cdot v(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})-\frac{\partial v(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _i}\cdot u(\alpha _i)}{v(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})^2}\\ \text {with }\frac{\partial u(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _i}&=\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,k}\\ \text {and }\frac{\partial v(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _i}&= \pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,c} - \left( (1-\alpha _j)\frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _i}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _i}\right) . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(B.4)
Given \(v(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})>0\) the sign of \(\partial \tilde{\delta }^*/\partial \alpha _i\) is the same as that of its numerator as is shown in (B.5):
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial u(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _i}\cdot v(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})-\frac{\partial v(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _i}\cdot u(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})=\dots \nonumber \\&(1-\alpha _{j}) \left[ (\pi _{i,k}-\pi _{i,c})\pi _{j,-d} - (\pi _{j,k}-\pi _{j,c})\pi _{i,d} - (\pi _{i,c}-\pi _{j,c})\pi _{i,k} \right] \nonumber \\&+ \left( (1-\alpha _{j})\frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _i}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _i}\right) u(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j}) . \end{aligned}$$
(B.5)
Equation (B.5), and thus \(\partial \tilde{\delta }^*/\partial \alpha _i\), is positive if inequality (9) applies. This proves Proposition 1. \(\square\)
The proof of Proposition 2 relies on Lemma 7:
Lemma 7
\((1-\alpha _j)\frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}=0\).
Proof
For Cournot competition with homogeneous products, the equality stated in Lemma 7 can be restated as in (B.6):
$$\begin{aligned} (1-\alpha _j)\frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} = \frac{\partial q_i}{\partial \alpha _{j}}\left[ (1-\alpha _j)\left( \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_i+p\right) + \alpha _i\left( \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_{j} \right) \right] =0 . \end{aligned}$$
(B.6)
The bracketed term on the right-hand side of equation (B.6) is the same as the bracketed term in first-order condition (A.2) that takes a value of zero in the optimum. For Bertrand competition with differentiated products, the equality that is stated in Lemma 7 can be restated as in (B.7):
$$\begin{aligned} (1-\alpha _j)\frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}=\frac{\partial p_i}{\partial \alpha _{j}}\left[ (1-\alpha _j)\left( \frac{\partial q_i}{\partial p_i}p_i+q_i\right) +\alpha _i\left( \frac{\partial q_{j}}{\partial p_i}q_{j} \right) \right] =0 . \end{aligned}$$
(B.7)
The bracketed term on the right-hand side of equation (B.7) is the same as the bracketed term in first-order condition (A.5) that takes a value of zero in the optimum. Section 3.2 established that \(\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _{j}=0\) and \(\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _{j}=0\) for Bertrand competition with homogeneous products, which proves \((1-\alpha _j)(\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _{j})+\alpha _i(\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _{j})=0\). \(\square\)
Proof
Lemma 4 proposes \((1-\alpha _j)\partial \pi _{i,c} / \partial \alpha _i + \alpha _i \cdot \partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _i <0\) in Cournot competition with \(\partial q_j^R/\partial q_i<0\). Given \(\pi _i=p \cdot q_i\) the first derivative \(\partial \pi _{i,c} / \partial \alpha _i\) can be written as in (B.8) if firm i chooses its output \(\tilde{q}_i^R\) according to the best response function (A.3). The first derivative \(\partial p / \partial \alpha _i\) can be written as in (B.9) if one considers \(Q=q_i+q_j\) and \(\partial p / \partial Q = \partial p / \partial q_i\) because of \(\partial Q / \partial q_i=1\). Similarly, the derivative \(\partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _i\) of \(\pi _j=p \cdot q_j\) is shown in (B.10):
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _i} = \frac{\partial p}{\partial \alpha _i} q_i + \frac{\partial \tilde{q}_i^R}{\partial \alpha _i} p = \frac{\partial \tilde{q}_i^R}{\partial \alpha _i} \left[ \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i} \left( 1+\frac{\partial q_j}{\partial q_i}\right) q_i+p \right] ; \end{aligned}$$
(B.8)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial p}{\partial \alpha _i} = \frac{\partial p}{\partial Q} \frac{\partial Q}{\partial \alpha _i} = \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i} \left[ \frac{\partial \tilde{q}_i^R}{\partial \alpha _i} + \frac{\partial q_j}{\partial \tilde{q}_i^R}\frac{\partial \tilde{q}_i^R}{\partial \alpha _i} \right] ; \end{aligned}$$
(B.9)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _i} = \frac{\partial p}{\partial \alpha _i}q_j + \frac{\partial q_j}{\partial \alpha _i}p = \frac{\partial \tilde{q}_i^R}{\partial \alpha _i} \left[ \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i} \left( 1+\frac{\partial q_j}{\partial q_i}\right) q_j+\frac{\partial q_j}{\partial q_i}p \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(B.10)
Using (B.8) and (B.10), the term \((1-\alpha _j)\partial \pi _{i,c} / \partial \alpha _i + \alpha _i \cdot \partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _i <0\) can be expressed as in (B.11):
$$\begin{aligned}&(1-\alpha _j)\frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _i} + \alpha _i \frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _i} =\dots \nonumber \\&\frac{\partial \tilde{q}_i^R}{\partial \alpha _i} \left[ \left[ (1-\alpha _j)\left( \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_i+p\right) +\alpha _i\frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_j \right] \left( 1+\frac{\partial q_j}{\partial {q}_i} \right) + \frac{\partial q_j}{\partial {q}_i}p(\alpha _i+\alpha _j-1) \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(B.11)
The term \((1-\alpha _j)(\partial p/\partial q_i\cdot q_i+p)+\alpha _i\cdot \partial p/\partial q_i\cdot q_j\) takes a value of zero as follows from first-order condition (A.2). Lemma 1 showed that \(\partial \hat{q}_i^R/\partial \alpha _i<0\). Combining this with \(\partial q_j / \partial \tilde{q}_i^R<0\) and \(\alpha _i+\alpha _j-1<0\), one finds \(\partial \pi _{i,c} / \partial \alpha _i + \alpha _i \cdot \partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _i <0\), which proves Lemma 4. \(\square\)
Proof
With \(\alpha _i=\alpha _j=\alpha\) the firms receive \(\pi _{i,c}=\pi _{j,c}\), so that proving that \({(1-\alpha )\cdot \partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha +\alpha \cdot \partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha >11}\) (Lemma 5) requires that \({\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha >0}\). This inequality is shown in (B.12) where we made use of (B.13), which requires \(Q=q_i+q_j\), \(\partial p/\partial Q = \partial p/\partial q_i\), and \(\partial q_i/\partial \alpha =\partial q_j/\partial \alpha\) because of symmetry \((q_i=q_j)\):
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha } = \frac{\partial p}{\partial \alpha }q_i + \frac{\partial \tilde{q}_i^R}{\partial \alpha }p = \frac{\partial \tilde{q}_i^R}{\partial \alpha } \left[ 2\frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_i+p \right] ; \end{aligned}$$
(B.12)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial p}{\partial \alpha } = \frac{\partial p}{\partial Q} \frac{\partial Q}{\partial \alpha } = \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i} \left[ \frac{\partial q_i}{\partial \alpha } + \frac{\partial q_j}{\partial \alpha } \right] = 2\frac{\partial q_i}{\partial \alpha }\frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i} . \end{aligned}$$
(B.13)
Under symmetry, first-order condition (A.2) simplifies to the first line in (B.14):
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_i+(1-\alpha )p = 0 \nonumber \\&\frac{1}{1-\alpha } \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i} q_i + p = 0 . \end{aligned}$$
(B.14)
Given \(\partial p / \partial q_i<0\) and \(1/(1-\alpha )<2\), this causes (B.15) where the term on the left-hand side was taken from (B.12):
$$\begin{aligned} 2\frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_i+p<\frac{1}{1-\alpha }\frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_i+p=0 . \end{aligned}$$
(B.15)
Combining inequality (B.15) with \(\partial \tilde{q}_i^R/\partial \alpha <0\) from Lemma 1 yields \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha >0\), which proves Lemma 5. \(\square\)
Proof
Proposition 2 suggests that \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _{j}>0\) if inequality (10) is met. Equation (B.16) provides that \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _{j}\), where the expressions for \(u(\alpha _i,\alpha _j)\) and \(v(\alpha _i,\alpha _j)\) are the ones given in (B.3):
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*}{\partial \alpha _{j}}&= \frac{\frac{\partial u(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _{j}} \cdot v(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j}) - \frac{\partial v(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _{j}} \cdot u(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{v(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})^2} \\ \text {with }\frac{\partial u(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _{j}}&= \pi _{i,k}-\pi _{i,d}+(1-\alpha _j)\left( \frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}-\frac{\partial \pi _{i,k}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} \right) + \alpha _i \left( \frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}-\frac{\partial \pi _{j,k}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} \right) \\ \text {and }\frac{\partial v(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _{j}}&= \pi _{i,c}-\pi _{i,d}+(1-\alpha _j)\left( \frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}-\frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} \right) + \alpha _i \left( \frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}-\frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} \right) . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(B.16)
Using \(\partial \pi _{i,k}/\partial \alpha _{j}=\partial \pi _{j,k}/\partial \alpha _{j}=0\) and \((1-\alpha _j)(\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _{j})+\alpha _i(\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _{j})=0\) from Lemma 7, the partial derivatives can be simplified as is shown in (B.17):
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial u(\alpha _i,\alpha _j)}{\partial \alpha _j}&= \pi _{i,k}-\pi _{i,d} \\ \frac{\partial v (\alpha _i,\alpha _j)}{\partial \alpha _j}&= \pi _{i,c}-\pi _{i,d} -(1-\alpha _j) \frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _j} - \alpha _i \frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _j} . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(B.17)
Equation (B.16) can thus be simplified as is shown in equation (B.18):
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*}{\partial \alpha _{j}} = \frac{ (\pi _{i,k}-\pi _{i,d}) \cdot v(\alpha _i,\alpha _j) + \left( \pi _{i,c}-\pi _{i,d} -(1-\alpha _j) \frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _j} - \alpha _i \frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _j}\right) \cdot u(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{v(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})^2} . \end{aligned}$$
(B.18)
Condition \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _j>0\) can be solved to yield (10), which proves Proposition 2. \(\square\)

Appendix to Section 5

Proof
Proposition 3 suggests that \(\partial \tilde{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _i>0\) if inequality (12) is satisfied. Given the detection probability \(\rho\) and fine F, firm i’s profits can be written as in (C.1) when colluding and as in (C.2) when deviating:
$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{\pi }_{i,k}= & {} (1-\alpha _{j})(\pi _{i,k}-\rho F)+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,k}-\rho F) ; \end{aligned}$$
(C.1)
$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{\pi }_{i,d}= & {} (1-\alpha _{j})(\pi _{i,d}-\rho F)+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\rho F) . \end{aligned}$$
(C.2)
Plugging (C.1) and (C.2) in (7) and solving for \(\delta _i\) yields the critical discount factor that is shown in (11). Performing the same calculations done for the proof of Proposition 1 yields inequality (12). It is straightforward to show that the left-hand side of (9) is bigger than the left-hand side of (12), which proves that (12) is easier to satisfy than (9). \(\square\)

Appendix to Section 6

This section demonstrates that only the functional form but not the economic interpretation of our results changes if one assumes profit function (13) for cross ownership. In this case, the competitive, collusive, and deviations profits can be stated as in (D.1)–(D.3):
$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\pi }_{i,c}= & {} \frac{\pi _{i,c}+\alpha _i\pi _{j,c}}{1-\alpha _i\alpha _{j}} ; \end{aligned}$$
(D.1)
$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\pi }_{i,k}= & {} \frac{(\pi _{i,k}-\rho F)+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,k}-\rho F)}{1-\alpha _i\alpha _{j}} ; \end{aligned}$$
(D.2)
$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\pi }_{i,d}= & {} \frac{(\pi _{i,d}-\rho F)+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\rho F)}{1-\alpha _i\alpha _{j}} . \end{aligned}$$
(D.3)
Lemmas 1-3 were established for profit function (13) by Flath (1991), Flath (1992), and Farrell and Shapiro (1990). We do not repeat these proofs because they resemble the ones that were presented in “Appendix 1”.
The analysis of \(\partial \hat{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _i\) relies on condition (D.4), which we will show to apply in Cournot competition, in Bertrand competition with differentiated products, and in Bertrand competition with homogeneous products:
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _i}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _i}=0 . \end{aligned}$$
(D.4)
In Cournot competition with homogeneous products, the profits of firm i can be written as in (D.5), and its first-order condition as in (D.6). Note that the profit (D.5) is expressed before the eventual payment of \(\rho F\), which constitutes a fixed cost and thus does not affect firm i’s choice of its strategic variable. Equality (D.4) can be restated as in (D.7):
$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\pi }_{i}= & {} \frac{1}{1-\alpha _i\alpha _{j}}\left[ p(q_i,q_{j})q_i+\alpha _i p(q_i,q_{j})q_{j}\right] ; \end{aligned}$$
(D.5)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \hat{\pi }_{i}}{\partial q_i}= & {} \frac{1}{1-\alpha _i\alpha _{j}}\left[ \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i} q_i+p(q_i,q_{j})+\alpha _i\frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_{j}\right] =0 ; \end{aligned}$$
(D.6)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _i}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _i} = \frac{\partial q_i^R}{\partial \alpha _i}\left[ \left( \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_i+p\right) + \alpha _i\left( \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_{j} \right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(D.7)
The bracketed term on the right-hand side of equation (D.7) is the same as the bracketed term in first-order condition (D.6) that takes a value of zero in the optimum, which proves (D.4).
For Bertrand competition with differentiated products, the profit of firm i (before paying \(\rho F\)) can be written as in (D.8), and its first-order condition as in (D.9). Equality (D.4) can be restated as in (D.10):
$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\pi }_{i}= & {} \frac{1}{1-\alpha _i\alpha _{j}}\left[ q_i(p_i,p_{j})p_i+\alpha _i q_{j}(p_j,p_i)p_{j}\right] ; \end{aligned}$$
(D.8)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \hat{\pi }_{i}}{\partial p_i}= & {} \frac{1}{1-\alpha _i\alpha _{j}}\left[ \frac{\partial q_i}{\partial p_i} p_i+q_i(p_i,p_{j})+\alpha _i\frac{\partial q_{j}}{\partial p_i}p_{j}\right] =0 ; \end{aligned}$$
(D.9)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _i}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _i}=\frac{\partial p_i^R}{\partial \alpha _i}\left[ \left( \frac{\partial q_i}{\partial p_i}p_i+q_i\right) +\alpha _i\left( \frac{\partial q_{j}}{\partial p_i}q_{j} \right) \right] =0 . \end{aligned}$$
(D.10)
The bracketed term on the right-hand side of equation (D.10) is the same as the bracketed term in first-order condition (D.9) that takes a value of zero in the optimum, which proves (D.4).
In Bertrand competition with homogeneous products both firms set prices equal to marginal cost regardless of the values of \(\alpha _i,\alpha _j\), which causes \({\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _i=0}\) and \({\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _i=0}\). This proves (D.4).
Turning to the finding of main interest, using profit functions (D.1)-(D.3), the critical discount factor \(\hat{\delta }_i^*\) can be written as in (D.11):
$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\delta }_i^* \equiv \frac{(\pi _{i,d}-\pi _{i,k})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,k})}{(\pi _{i,d}-\rho F-\pi _{i,c})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\rho F-\pi _{j,c})} . \end{aligned}$$
(D.11)
One finds \(\partial \hat{\delta }^*/\partial \alpha _i>0\) if inequality (D.12) is satisfied, which can be interpreted in the same way as inequalities (9) and (12) in the main text:
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\left( \pi _{i,k}-\rho F-\pi _{i,c} \right) \left( \pi _{i,d}-\pi _{j,-d} \right) }{(\pi _{i,d}-\pi _{i,k})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,k})} < \frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _i}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _i} . \end{aligned}$$
(D.12)
To determine \(\partial \hat{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _i\), re-write \(\hat{\delta }_i^*\) as follows:
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \hat{\delta }_i^*&=\frac{\hat{u}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}{\hat{v}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}\\ \text {with }\hat{u}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})&=(\pi _{i,d}-\pi _{i,k})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,k})>0\\ \text {and }\hat{v}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})&=(\pi _{i,d}-\rho F-\pi _{i,c})+\alpha _i(\pi _{j,-d}-\rho F-\pi _{j,c})>0 . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(D.13)
With the use of \(\partial \pi _{i,k}/\partial \alpha _i=\partial \pi _{j,k}/\partial \alpha _i=0\) and (D.4), \(\partial \delta _i^*/\partial \alpha _i\) can be written as in (D.14):
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \hat{\delta }_i^*}{\partial \alpha _i}&=\frac{\frac{\partial \hat{u}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _i}\cdot \hat{v}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})-\frac{\partial \hat{v}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _i}\cdot \hat{u}(\alpha _i)}{\hat{v}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})^2}\\ \text {with }\frac{\partial \hat{u}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _i}&=\pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{j,k}\\ \text {and }\frac{\partial \hat{v}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _i}&= \pi _{j,-d}-\rho F-\pi _{j,c} - \left( \frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _i}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _i}\right) . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(D.14)
Given \(\hat{v}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})>0\), the sign of \(\partial \hat{\delta }^*/\partial \alpha _i\) is the same as that of its numerator as is shown in (D.15):
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial \hat{u}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _i}\cdot \hat{v}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})-\frac{\partial \hat{v}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _i}\cdot \hat{u}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})=\dots \nonumber \\&\left( \pi _{i,k}-\rho F-\pi _{i,c} \right) \left( \pi _{j,-d}-\pi _{i,d} \right) + \left( \frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _i}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _i}\right) \hat{u}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j}) . \end{aligned}$$
(D.15)
This proves that \(\partial \hat{\delta }^*/\partial \alpha _i\) is positive if inequality (D.12) applies.
The analysis of \(\partial \hat{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _j\) relies on condition (D.16):
$$\begin{aligned} {\frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}}+\alpha _i{\frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}}=0 . \end{aligned}$$
(D.16)
For Cournot competition with homogeneous products, (D.16) can be restated as in (D.17):
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} = \frac{\partial q_i}{\partial \alpha _{j}}\left[ \left( \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_i+p\right) + \alpha _i\left( \frac{\partial p}{\partial q_i}q_{j} \right) \right] =0 . \end{aligned}$$
(D.17)
The bracketed term on the right-hand side of equation (D.17) is the same as the bracketed term in first-order condition (D.6) that takes a value of zero in the optimum. For Bertrand competition with differentiated products, (D.16) can be restated as in (D.18):
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}+\alpha _i\frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}=\frac{\partial p_i}{\partial \alpha _{j}}\left[ \left( \frac{\partial q_i}{\partial p_i}p_i+q_i\right) +\alpha _i\left( \frac{\partial q_{j}}{\partial p_i}q_{j} \right) \right] =0 . \end{aligned}$$
(D.18)
The bracketed term on the right-hand side of equation (D.18) is the same as the bracketed term in first-order condition (D.9) that takes a value of zero in the optimum. The equalities \(\partial \pi _{i,d}/\partial \alpha _{j}=0\) and \(\partial \pi _{j,-d}/\partial \alpha _{j}=0\) for Bertrand competition with homogeneous products also proves (D.16).
With respect to the second main result, inequality \(\partial \hat{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _{j}>0\) applies if inequality (D.19) is satisfied, whose interpretation is equivalent to that of (10) in the main text:
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} 0 < \frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} + \alpha _i \frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(D.19)
To prove that \(\partial \hat{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _{j}>0\) applies under condition (D.19), consider that equation (D.20) provides that \(\partial \hat{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _{j}\) when assuming profit function (13) and defining \(\hat{u}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j}), \hat{v}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})\) as in (D.13):
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \hat{\delta }_i^*}{\partial \alpha _{j}}&= \frac{\frac{\partial \hat{u}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _{j}} \cdot \hat{v}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j}) - \frac{\partial \hat{v}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _{j}} \cdot \hat{u}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{\hat{v}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})^2} \\ \text {with }\frac{\partial \hat{u}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _{j}}&= \left( \frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}-\frac{\partial \pi _{i,k}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} \right) + \alpha _i \left( \frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}-\frac{\partial \pi _{j,k}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} \right) \\ \text {and }\frac{\partial \hat{v}(\alpha _i, \alpha _{j})}{\partial \alpha _{j}}&= \left( \frac{\partial \pi _{i,d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}-\frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} \right) + \alpha _i \left( \frac{\partial \pi _{j,-d}}{\partial \alpha _{j}}-\frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} \right) . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(D.20)
With the use of \(\partial \pi _{i,k}/\partial \alpha _{j}=\partial \pi _{j,k}/\partial \alpha _{j}=0\) and (D.16), equation (D.20) can be simplified as is shown in equation (D.21):
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \hat{\delta }_i^*}{\partial \alpha _{j}} = \frac{ \left( \frac{\partial \pi _{i,c}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} + \alpha _i \frac{\partial \pi _{j,c}}{\partial \alpha _{j}} \right) \cdot \hat{u}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})}{\hat{v}(\alpha _{j})^2} . \end{aligned}$$
(D.21)
Given \(\hat{u}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})>0\text { and } \hat{v}(\alpha _i,\alpha _{j})>0\), the inequality \(\partial \hat{\delta }_i^*/\partial \alpha _{j}>0\) applies if inequality (D.19) is satisfied.
As in the case of the common ownership profit function (1), it can be shown for the cross ownership profit function (13) that \(\hat{\delta }_i^*\) can be raised more easily by an increase in \(\alpha _j\) than by an increase in \(\alpha _i\): Inequality (D.19) is more easily satisfied than is (D.12). The left-hand side of (D.12) is positive and, thus, greater than the left-hand side of (D.19). Assuming symmetry \((\alpha _i=\alpha _j)\) before an asymmetric expansion of \(\alpha _i\) or \(\alpha _j\) takes place causes \(\partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _i = \partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _j\) and \(\partial \pi _{j,c}/\partial \alpha _i = \partial \pi _{i,c}/\partial \alpha _j\). Using this in combination with Lemmas 1 and 3, one can show that the right-hand side of (D.19) is weakly greater than that of (D.12). Both observations ensure that inequality (D.19) is more easily satisfied than (D.12).
Fußnoten
1
Empirical evidence of the effects of cross ownership and the related issue of common ownership on firms’ profits in competition has been provided, for example, by Azar et al. (2016), Trivieri (2007), and Nain and Wang (2018).
 
2
A related analysis was conducted by Reitman (1994) in a conjectural variations model that was based on the analysis of joint ventures that was conducted by Kwoka (1992).
 
3
The proof of Lemma 1 relies on the assumption of \(\partial q_i^R/\partial q_j<0\), which applies for the demand for homogeneous products that were assumed by Flath (1991) and Malueg (1992) as well as for several Cournot models with differentiated products. The analysis of the less common case with \(\partial q_i^R/\partial q_j\ge 0\) is left for future research.
 
4
Note that Gilo et al. (2006) assumed that the firms maximize the profit function \(\hat{\pi }_i=\pi _i+\alpha _i\hat{\pi }_{j}\) rather than \(\tilde{\pi }_i=(1-\alpha _j)\pi _i+\alpha _i\pi _{j}\). Although these functions model different aspects of minority shareholdings – common ownership vs. cross ownership – their effect on our results is minor and has no impact on our qualitative conclusions as will be discussed in Sect. 6.
 
5
Flath (1991) provides proofs for a Hotelling model. A Salop circle model with three firms and asymmetric, controlling shareholdings was provided by Øystein et al. (2011). Yet, these proofs were done under the assumption of profit function (13).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Aubert, C., Rey, P., & Kovacic, W. E. (2006). The impact of leniency and whistle-blowing programs on cartels. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24, 1241–1266.CrossRef Aubert, C., Rey, P., & Kovacic, W. E. (2006). The impact of leniency and whistle-blowing programs on cartels. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24, 1241–1266.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Azar, J., Schmalz, M. C., & Tecu, I. (2016). Anti-competitive effects of common ownership. Working Paper No. 1235, Ross School of Business. Azar, J., Schmalz, M. C., & Tecu, I. (2016). Anti-competitive effects of common ownership. Working Paper No. 1235, Ross School of Business.
Zurück zum Zitat Farrell, J., & Shapiro, C. (1990). Asset ownership and market structure in oligopoly. The RAND Journal of Economics, 21, 275–292.CrossRef Farrell, J., & Shapiro, C. (1990). Asset ownership and market structure in oligopoly. The RAND Journal of Economics, 21, 275–292.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Flath, D. (1991). When is it rational for firms to acquire silent interests in rivals. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 9, 573–583.CrossRef Flath, D. (1991). When is it rational for firms to acquire silent interests in rivals. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 9, 573–583.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Flath, D. (1992). Horizontal shareholding interlocks. Managerial and Decision Economics, 13, 75–77.CrossRef Flath, D. (1992). Horizontal shareholding interlocks. Managerial and Decision Economics, 13, 75–77.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Foros, O., Kind, H. J., & Shaffer, G. (2011). Mergers and partial ownership. European Economic Review, 55, 916–926.CrossRef Foros, O., Kind, H. J., & Shaffer, G. (2011). Mergers and partial ownership. European Economic Review, 55, 916–926.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Friedman, J. W. (1971). A non-cooperative equilibrium for supergames. The Review of Economic Studies, 38, 1–12.CrossRef Friedman, J. W. (1971). A non-cooperative equilibrium for supergames. The Review of Economic Studies, 38, 1–12.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gilo, D., Moshe, Y., & Spiegel, Y. (2006). Partial cross ownership and tacit collusion. The RAND Journal of Economics, 37, 81–99.CrossRef Gilo, D., Moshe, Y., & Spiegel, Y. (2006). Partial cross ownership and tacit collusion. The RAND Journal of Economics, 37, 81–99.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harrington, J. E. (2017). The theory of collusion and competition policy. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.CrossRef Harrington, J. E. (2017). The theory of collusion and competition policy. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Karle, H., Stahl, K. O., & Klein, T. J. (2011). Ownership and control in a competitive industry. ZEW Discussion Papers 11-071, ZEW. Karle, H., Stahl, K. O., & Klein, T. J. (2011). Ownership and control in a competitive industry. ZEW Discussion Papers 11-071, ZEW.
Zurück zum Zitat Kwoka, J. E. (1992). The output and profit effects of horizontal joint ventures. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 40, 325–338.CrossRef Kwoka, J. E. (1992). The output and profit effects of horizontal joint ventures. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 40, 325–338.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat López, A. L., & Vives, X. (2016). Cross-ownership, r&d spillovers, and antitrust policy. Working Paper No. 5935, CESifo. López, A. L., & Vives, X. (2016). Cross-ownership, r&d spillovers, and antitrust policy. Working Paper No. 5935, CESifo.
Zurück zum Zitat Malueg, D. A. (1992). Collusive behavior and partial ownership of rivals. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 10, 27–34.CrossRef Malueg, D. A. (1992). Collusive behavior and partial ownership of rivals. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 10, 27–34.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nain, A., & Wang, Y. (2018). The product market impact of minority stake acquisitions. Management Science, 64(2), 825–844.CrossRef Nain, A., & Wang, Y. (2018). The product market impact of minority stake acquisitions. Management Science, 64(2), 825–844.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ouimet, P. P. (2013). What motivates minority acquisitions? The trade-offs between a partial equity stake and complete integration. The Review of Financial Studies, 26, 1021–1047.CrossRef Ouimet, P. P. (2013). What motivates minority acquisitions? The trade-offs between a partial equity stake and complete integration. The Review of Financial Studies, 26, 1021–1047.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Reitman, D. (1994). Partial ownership arrangements and the potential for collusion. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 42, 313–322.CrossRef Reitman, D. (1994). Partial ownership arrangements and the potential for collusion. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 42, 313–322.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Reynolds, R. J., & Snapp, B. R. (1986). The competitive effects of partial equity interests and joint ventures. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 4, 141–153.CrossRef Reynolds, R. J., & Snapp, B. R. (1986). The competitive effects of partial equity interests and joint ventures. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 4, 141–153.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Salop, S. C., & O’Brien, D. P. (2000). Competitive effects of partial ownership: Financial interest and corporate control. Antitrust Law Journal, 67, 559–614. Salop, S. C., & O’Brien, D. P. (2000). Competitive effects of partial ownership: Financial interest and corporate control. Antitrust Law Journal, 67, 559–614.
Zurück zum Zitat Schmalz, M. C. (2018). Common-ownership concentration and corporate conduct. Annual Review of Financial Economics, 10, 413–448.CrossRef Schmalz, M. C. (2018). Common-ownership concentration and corporate conduct. Annual Review of Financial Economics, 10, 413–448.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shelegia, S., & Spiegel, Y. (2012). Bertrand competition when firms hold passive ownership stakes in one another. Economic Letters, 114, 136–138.CrossRef Shelegia, S., & Spiegel, Y. (2012). Bertrand competition when firms hold passive ownership stakes in one another. Economic Letters, 114, 136–138.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Trivieri, F. (2007). Does cross-ownership affect competition? Evidence from the italian banking industry. International Financial Markets, Institutions & Money, 17, 79–101.CrossRef Trivieri, F. (2007). Does cross-ownership affect competition? Evidence from the italian banking industry. International Financial Markets, Institutions & Money, 17, 79–101.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tzanaki, A. (2015). The legal treatment of minority shareholdings under EU competition law: Present and future. Essays in honour of professor panayiotis I (pp. 861–886). Kanellopoulos, Athens: Sakkoulas Publications. Tzanaki, A. (2015). The legal treatment of minority shareholdings under EU competition law: Present and future. Essays in honour of professor panayiotis I (pp. 861–886). Kanellopoulos, Athens: Sakkoulas Publications.
Metadaten
Titel
Non-Controlling Minority Shareholdings and Collusion
verfasst von
Samuel de Haas
Johannes Paha
Publikationsdatum
09.05.2020
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Review of Industrial Organization / Ausgabe 3/2021
Print ISSN: 0889-938X
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7160
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-020-09758-y

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3/2021

Review of Industrial Organization 3/2021 Zur Ausgabe