Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Journal of Business Economics 1/2020

08.03.2019 | Original Paper

Parity codetermination at the board level and labor investment efficiency: evidence on German listed firms

verfasst von: Kerstin Lopatta, Katarina Böttcher, Sumit K. Lodhia, Sebastian A. Tideman

Erschienen in: Journal of Business Economics | Ausgabe 1/2020

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This study examines whether parity codetermination at German supervisory boards improves labor investment efficiency at firm level. We focus on labor, as it is an important production factor. Labor investment decisions are not easily reversible in the short term, given that hiring and firing costs are usually quite high due to labor regulation in Germany. As labor representatives are legally entitled to 50% voting rights at the supervisory board level (parity codetermination), we expect them to contribute insider knowledge to the supervisory board. As they have access to internal documents, we also expect them to reduce information asymmetry and potential agency conflicts between management on the one hand and outsiders such as investors or capital suppliers on the other. Both smaller information asymmetries and reduced agency conflicts, in turn, ought to increase a firm’s labor investment efficiency. Labor investment proxies for deviations from a firm’s optimal level of investment in labor in the form of over- and underinvestment, defined as hiring fewer employees than required to run profitable projects (underhiring) or retaining employees who are occupied with non-profitable projects (overhiring). We measure labor investment efficiency using such a net hiring optimum for a sample of German listed firms between 1995 and 2015. The results indicate that parity codetermination causes a lower deviation from the net hiring optimum. Our results are interesting for various stakeholders, especially for policymakers, managers, shareholders and employees who may not be aware of the importance of codetermination for firm efficiency, as well as for firms that are considering circumventing German legislation.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Journal of Business Economics

From January 2013, the Zeitschrift für Betriebswirtschaft (ZfB) is published in English under the title Journal of Business Economics (JBE). The Journal of Business Economics (JBE) aims at encouraging theoretical and applied research in the field of business economics and business administration, promoting the exchange of ideas between science and practice.

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
The German law on codetermination requires the firm to have 50% employee representatives on the supervisory board once the firm exceeds the threshold of 2000 domestic employees.
 
2
Hubbard (1998) and Stein (2003) provide surveys of this literature.
 
3
Studies on capital investment and market frictions are presented by Hubbard (1998) and Stein (2003).
 
4
There is evidence to suggest that information-sharing is positively related to the level of wages and benefits in both union and non-union businesses, but negatively related to profits and cash flows in non-union businesses (Kleiner and Bouillon 1988).
 
5
Employees or unions may increase unilateral advantages by, e.g., demanding higher wages and holding the level of employment constant, even if this endangers the firm’s economic position (Lazear and Freeman 1995).
 
6
To proxy for stock price informativeness, Ben-Nasr and Alshwer (2016) use the Probability of Information-based Trading (PIN) derived from Easley et al. (1996) market microstructure model.
 
7
Future research should seek to broaden our understanding of the determinants and effects of labor investment efficiency for multinational and non-U.S. samples.
 
8
For an overview of existing or non-existing codetermination at board level rights please refer to European Trade Union Institute’s website (ETUI 2014) or to Lopatta et al. (2018).
 
9
Some studies even suggest that one third participation is not strictly enforced in German firms (Boneberg 2009, 2010, 2016; Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung 2016). This may be because one-third participation applies only to smaller firms, which are often family-owned. These owners may refrain from sharing their powers with people outside their family (e.g., employee representatives) even if this jeopardizes firm performance (Cucculelli and Micucci 2008). To the contrary, other researchers argue that the share of firms with 500–2000 employees without one-third codetermination may also be partly due to reasons other than enforcement (for a discussion of these reasons see Dilger (2009)). Non-compliance with the legislation is therefore more likely to be detected for parity codetermination than for one-third codetermination. In order to reduce the risk of self-selection bias, we focus on parity codetermination, which we know from hand-collection, is enforced without a considerable delay.
 
10
In case no majority is achieved, labor representatives elect the deputy chair while shareholder representatives elect the chair (Section 27 (2) of the law on codetermination).
 
11
Employees who serve on the supervisory board can elect the members of the management board for at most 5 years, with the possibility of re-election [Section 84 (1) of the Stock Corporation Act (Aktiengesetz or AktG)].
 
12
The rather long-term orientation of employee representatives and the rather fixed compensation of employees may partly explain why not all previous studies have found a beneficial effect of labor representation. In line with Lin et al. (2018), we argue that employees have a different utility function than management and shareholders. Whereas management and shareholders rather symmetrically benefit from performance increases and decreases, employees merely benefit from performance increases and suffer directly from performance decreases due to job losses and restructuring programs. Hence, whereas management and shareholders would initiate most if not all projects with a positive net present value (also high-risk projects, as the expected returns are correspondingly high), it is plausible that employee representatives are not willing to initiate all positive (high-risk) net present value projects. At worse, this could harm firm value (and consequently firm performance, e.g., through negative market returns), as projects with positive net present value would potentially not be initiated. Given these considerations, we believe it is plausible to assume that the heterogeneity in the results on firm performance are rather due to different risk-return functions (symmetric vs. asymmetric relation) of managers and shareholders versus employees. In our setting, these varying risk-return considerations should not affect our results as we implicitly look at the effect of co-determination on labor investment efficiency for given performance levels (see Sect. 3).
 
13
This may be beneficial to the extent that firms in highly unionized industries are characterized by higher levels of information asymmetry and greater bargaining power on the part of unions (Frost 2000; Kleiner and Bouillon 1988; Scott 1994).
 
14
Both parity and one-third codetermination should have an effect on a firm’s information environment. However, we focus in our empirical setting only on parity codetermination and do not estimate effects for one-third codetermination as the latter would potentially cause severe methodological issues. The adaption of parity codetermination is an external effect that triggers the voice of labor due to legislation, which enables us to reduce the risk of self-selection bias. One may argue that missing enforcement sanctions are an issue. However, after hand-collection, we know that firms in our sample change to parity codetermination without a considerable delay. We believe that this is mainly reputation/attention-driven: larger and especially listed firms are more often in the spotlight of the media and the public. Non-compliance with the legislation is therefore more likely to be detected for parity codetermination than for one-third codetermination. Yet, the enforcement of the one-third codetermination around the threshold of 500 domestic employees is somehow questionable due to other issues that have been detected in prior research (see Sect. 2.2). Such non-compliance with codetermination legislation would ultimately result in a self-selection bias. Hence, by focusing on parity codetermination we test for the effect of firms switching from no or one-third codetermination to parity codetermination. We assume that the beneficial effect of parity codetermination should be more pronounced for firms switching from no to parity codetermination. However, we also believe that that the beneficial effects of a labor voice at board level (e.g., reduced agency conflicts and lower information asymmetries) should still exist for firms switching from one-third to parity codetermination, albeit be less pronounced. One beneficial effect of a switch from one-third to parity codetermination could be that the employees’ voice becomes stronger in boards discussions as they no longer constitute a minority. By contrast, focusing only on firms that switch from none to parity codetermination is not feasible due to a very small sample size. Given these arguments, we follow prior studies that also focus on parity codetermination and the related threshold of 2000 employees (Lin et al. 2018; Lopatta et al. 2018).
 
15
For instance, if labor resources are scarce (and hence more expensive) in a given year and industry, firms would be expected to hire fewer new employees as a reaction to sales growth.
 
16
For more details about why our control variables are expected to affect our dependent variable, we refer to Pinnuck and Lillis (2007), p. 1040. As an additional sensitivity test, we also include profit bins.
 
17
We test whether the loss bins are jointly significant. The (untabulated) results are similar.
 
18
Like U.S. firms, German firms are not required to publicly disclose any information about the union membership of their employees. In contrast to U.S. studies, Germany does not provide ratings about the unionization level per industry. However, using variables from the ASSET4 database allows us to control for firms’ union relations policies, which shows whether the management promotes a relationship between trade unions and employees.
 
19
The Hans Boeckler Foundation was established in 1954 and is located in Düsseldorf. It deals with co-determination and labor research and, on behalf of the Confederation of German Trade Unions, supports students (Hans-Böckler-Stiftung 2017).
 
20
To ensure correctness, we checked whether the firms actually (do not) comply with parity codetermination requirements for a random sample of 100 firm-years and did not find any false information.
 
21
The firms are assigned to the main Fama–French industry code (12 industries) according to their primary activities. We assign these industries using the industry indicators provided in COMPUSTAT GLOBAL.
 
22
For sensitivity, we rerun our regression Eq. (1) without SALES_GROWTHit and ROAit in time t. The effect of size is negative and significant at the 5% level, indicating firms that increase in SIZE have a lower percentage change in employees
 
23
Based on the expected values of net hire, we have split the sample into positive and negative deviations from the optimal value (zero). As we do not interpret values close to zero as over- or underinvestment, we do not include values close to zero to any of the two subsamples (defined as the absolute values lower than 1% of the median of our first-stage residuals).
 
24
For a more detailed overview of the German setting, refer to Sect. 2.2.
 
25
We do not control for the presence of works councils in our empirical model, as we did not find any sample firms without a works council, which is in line with the data used in similar studies (Lin et al. 2018).
 
26
We hand-collect data on the existence of collective bargaining agreements between unions and firms (hereafter labor agreements (German: “Tarifverträge”) and the name of the union from annual reports.
 
27
We also control for union strength as we expect larger unions to have a stronger negotiation position due to greater expertise and a stronger threat-potential. We posit that the strength of a union is positively correlated with size.
 
28
For further details, refer to the variable definition of STRONG_UNIONit in Appendix.
 
29
In another test, we also include STRONG_UNIONit and LABOR_AGREEMENTit in Eq. (1) and use the residuals of the adjusted equation for the measurement of labor investment efficiency. When rerunning Eq. (2), the results remain significant and similar to our previous tests (results untabulated). For comprehensiveness, we do not include all tables for our sensitivity analyses in this paper. However, the untabulated results of all modifications listed in this section are available upon request.
 
30
First, we exclude SALES_GROWTHit. This mitigates the risk that our significant results are biased by redundant control variables for sales growth, size and the growth effect in Eq. (1). In a second regression analysis, we include variables that control for the firms’ size in terms of the number of employees, namely LABOR_INTENSITYit and EMP_SIZEit in Eq. (1). Third, for taking the risk that our size variable drives the results in Eq. (2) into account, we replace SIZEit with various alternative measurements such as percentile ranks of SIZEit (hereafter: SIZE_Rit), or/and EMP_SIZEit as well as SALES_GROWTHit.
 
31
We modify the matching procedure in two ways. First, we extend the covariates by variables that reflect the firms’ average growth in sales and labor intensity. Second, we also include the third last year before the treatment effect. The results remain not only robust, but also very similar in terms of coefficients’ magnitudes and significances (untabulated).
 
32
In line with Lopatta et al. (2018), our matching approach ensures that each treated firm is paired with the nearest neighbor in the control group. Technically, we sort the list of control firms (Control Group I) in descending order by distance (in the propensity score) to the treated firm’s outcome in the propensity score that is based on the last 2 years’ average of LEVit, ROAit, SIZEit. We keep only the first two firm-year observations to form the final matching pair.
 
33
For instance, larger firms may have more difficulties to find their optimal net hire level as their business operations may be more complex than those of smaller firms.
 
34
Similar patterns emerge for a second-order polynomial fit (quadratic function) and bin sizes of 100 employees.
 
35
Given that parity codetermination is strictly regulated in Germany, we assume that non-compliance with the parity codetermination rules by firms with more than 2000 employees is rather unlikely. We find no anecdotal or empirical evidence either in the academic literature or in the business press that firms voluntarily apply parity codetermination. However, we find very few observations where the firm has fewer than 2000 domestic employees and applies parity codetermination, which may be, for instance, due to time delays in the data provided. In these instances, our indicator variable for parity codetermination equals 1. Given these few exceptions, we cannot completely rule out that self-selection affects our results significantly although we believe it is rather unlikely. To exercise a high level of caution, we also run RDDs with a dummy if a firm is above the threshold of 2000 and polynomials of up to four dimensions. The results remain qualitatively unchanged.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Amihud Y, Mendelson H (1986) Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread. J Financ Econ 17(2):223–249 Amihud Y, Mendelson H (1986) Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread. J Financ Econ 17(2):223–249
Zurück zum Zitat Baker M, Stein JC, Wurgler J (2003) When does the market matter? Stock prices and the investment of equity-dependent firms. Q J Econ 118(3):969–1005 Baker M, Stein JC, Wurgler J (2003) When does the market matter? Stock prices and the investment of equity-dependent firms. Q J Econ 118(3):969–1005
Zurück zum Zitat Benmelech E, Bergman NK, Seru A (2011) Financing labor. National Bureau of Economic Research. Working Paper, (No. w17144) Benmelech E, Bergman NK, Seru A (2011) Financing labor. National Bureau of Economic Research. Working Paper, (No. w17144)
Zurück zum Zitat Ben-Nasr H, Alshwer AA (2016) Does stock price informativeness affect labor investment efficiency? J Corp Finance 38:249–271 Ben-Nasr H, Alshwer AA (2016) Does stock price informativeness affect labor investment efficiency? J Corp Finance 38:249–271
Zurück zum Zitat Bermig A, Frick B (2011) Mitbestimmung und Unternehmensperformance. Betriebswirtschaft 71(3):281 Bermig A, Frick B (2011) Mitbestimmung und Unternehmensperformance. Betriebswirtschaft 71(3):281
Zurück zum Zitat Bertrand M, Mullainathan S (2003) Enjoying the quiet life? Corporate governance and managerial preferences. J Polit Econ 111(5):1043–1075 Bertrand M, Mullainathan S (2003) Enjoying the quiet life? Corporate governance and managerial preferences. J Polit Econ 111(5):1043–1075
Zurück zum Zitat Biddle GC, Hilary G, Verdi RS (2009) How does financial reporting quality relate to investment efficiency? J Account Econ 48(2):112–131 Biddle GC, Hilary G, Verdi RS (2009) How does financial reporting quality relate to investment efficiency? J Account Econ 48(2):112–131
Zurück zum Zitat Boneberg F (2009) Die Aufsichtsratslücke im Dienstleistungssektor: Ausmaß und Bestimmungsgründe. Industrielle Beziehungen 16(4):349–367 Boneberg F (2009) Die Aufsichtsratslücke im Dienstleistungssektor: Ausmaß und Bestimmungsgründe. Industrielle Beziehungen 16(4):349–367
Zurück zum Zitat Boneberg F (2010) Die gegen das Drittelbeteiligungsgesetz verstoßende Aufsichtsratslücke im Dienstleistungssektor existiert: Replik zu Das Fehlen eines Aufsichtsrates muss nicht rechtswidrig sein von Alexander Dilger, erschienen in Industrielle Beziehungen, 4/2009. University of Lüneburg Working Paper Series in Economics, No. 158 Boneberg F (2010) Die gegen das Drittelbeteiligungsgesetz verstoßende Aufsichtsratslücke im Dienstleistungssektor existiert: Replik zu Das Fehlen eines Aufsichtsrates muss nicht rechtswidrig sein von Alexander Dilger, erschienen in Industrielle Beziehungen, 4/2009. University of Lüneburg Working Paper Series in Economics, No. 158
Zurück zum Zitat Bronars SG, Deere DR (1991) The threat of unionization, the use of debt, and the preservation of shareholder wealth. Q J Econ 106:231–254 Bronars SG, Deere DR (1991) The threat of unionization, the use of debt, and the preservation of shareholder wealth. Q J Econ 106:231–254
Zurück zum Zitat Burgstahler DC, Hail L, Leuz C (2006) The importance of reporting incentives: earnings management in European private and public firms. Account Rev 81(5):983–1016 Burgstahler DC, Hail L, Leuz C (2006) The importance of reporting incentives: earnings management in European private and public firms. Account Rev 81(5):983–1016
Zurück zum Zitat Campello M, Graham JR, Harvey CR (2010) The real effects of financial constraints: evidence from a financial crisis. J Financ Econ 97(3):470–487 Campello M, Graham JR, Harvey CR (2010) The real effects of financial constraints: evidence from a financial crisis. J Financ Econ 97(3):470–487
Zurück zum Zitat Cantor R (1990) Effects of leverage on corporate investment and hiring decisions. Fed Reserve Bank New York Q Rev 15(2):31–41 Cantor R (1990) Effects of leverage on corporate investment and hiring decisions. Fed Reserve Bank New York Q Rev 15(2):31–41
Zurück zum Zitat Cella C (2009) Institutional investors and corporate investment. Working Paper Cella C (2009) Institutional investors and corporate investment. Working Paper
Zurück zum Zitat Chen F, Hope O-K, Li Q, Wang X (2011a) Financial reporting quality and investment efficiency of private firms in emerging markets. Account Rev 86(4):1255–1288 Chen F, Hope O-K, Li Q, Wang X (2011a) Financial reporting quality and investment efficiency of private firms in emerging markets. Account Rev 86(4):1255–1288
Zurück zum Zitat Chen HJ, Kacperczyk M, Ortiz-Molina H (2011b) Labor unions, operating flexibility, and the cost of equity. J Financ Quant Anal 46(1):25–58 Chen HJ, Kacperczyk M, Ortiz-Molina H (2011b) Labor unions, operating flexibility, and the cost of equity. J Financ Quant Anal 46(1):25–58
Zurück zum Zitat Conchon A (2011) Board-level employee representation rights in Europe: facts and trends. ETUI, European Trade Union Institute, Brussels Conchon A (2011) Board-level employee representation rights in Europe: facts and trends. ETUI, European Trade Union Institute, Brussels
Zurück zum Zitat Datar SM, Feltham GA, Hughes JS (1991) The role of audits and audit quality in valuing new issues. J Account Econ 14(1):3–49 Datar SM, Feltham GA, Hughes JS (1991) The role of audits and audit quality in valuing new issues. J Account Econ 14(1):3–49
Zurück zum Zitat Dehaan E, Hodge F, Shevlin T (2013) Does voluntary adoption of a clawback provision improve financial reporting quality? Contemp Account Res 30(3):1027–1062 Dehaan E, Hodge F, Shevlin T (2013) Does voluntary adoption of a clawback provision improve financial reporting quality? Contemp Account Res 30(3):1027–1062
Zurück zum Zitat Denis DK, McConnell JJ (2003) International corporate governance. J Financ Quant Anal 38(01):1–36 Denis DK, McConnell JJ (2003) International corporate governance. J Financ Quant Anal 38(01):1–36
Zurück zum Zitat Dilger A (2009) Das Fehlen eines Aufsichtsrats muss nicht rechtswidrig sein. Kritische Anmerkungen zu “Die Aufsichtsratslücke im Dienstleistungssektor: Ausmaß und Bestimmungsgründe” von Franziska Boneberg. Industrielle Beziehungen/German J Ind Relat 16:367–375 Dilger A (2009) Das Fehlen eines Aufsichtsrats muss nicht rechtswidrig sein. Kritische Anmerkungen zu “Die Aufsichtsratslücke im Dienstleistungssektor: Ausmaß und Bestimmungsgründe” von Franziska Boneberg. Industrielle Beziehungen/German J Ind Relat 16:367–375
Zurück zum Zitat Dixit A (1997) Investment and employment dynamics in the short run and the long run. Oxf Econ Pap 49(1):1–20 Dixit A (1997) Investment and employment dynamics in the short run and the long run. Oxf Econ Pap 49(1):1–20
Zurück zum Zitat Easley D, Kiefer NM, O’hara M, Paperman JB (1996) Liquidity, information, and infrequently traded stocks. J Finance 51(4):1405–1436 Easley D, Kiefer NM, O’hara M, Paperman JB (1996) Liquidity, information, and infrequently traded stocks. J Finance 51(4):1405–1436
Zurück zum Zitat Faleye O, Mehrotra V, Morck R (2006) When labor has a voice in corporate governance. J Financ Quant Anal 41(03):489–510 Faleye O, Mehrotra V, Morck R (2006) When labor has a voice in corporate governance. J Financ Quant Anal 41(03):489–510
Zurück zum Zitat Fama EF, French KR (1997a) Industry costs of equity. J Financ Econ 43:153–193 Fama EF, French KR (1997a) Industry costs of equity. J Financ Econ 43:153–193
Zurück zum Zitat Fama EF, French KR (1997b) Industry costs of equity. J Financ Econ 43(2):153–193 Fama EF, French KR (1997b) Industry costs of equity. J Financ Econ 43(2):153–193
Zurück zum Zitat Farmer RE (1985) Implicit contracts with asymmetric information and bankruptcy: the effect of interest rates on layoffs. Rev Econ Stud 52(3):427–442 Farmer RE (1985) Implicit contracts with asymmetric information and bankruptcy: the effect of interest rates on layoffs. Rev Econ Stud 52(3):427–442
Zurück zum Zitat Fauver L, Fuerst ME (2006) Does good corporate governance include employee representation? Evidence from German corporate boards. J Financ Econ 82(3):673–710 Fauver L, Fuerst ME (2006) Does good corporate governance include employee representation? Evidence from German corporate boards. J Financ Econ 82(3):673–710
Zurück zum Zitat Fazzari SM, Hubbard RG, Petersen BC, Blinder AS, Poterba JM (1988) Financing constraints and corporate investment. Brook Pap Econ Act 1988(1):141–206 Fazzari SM, Hubbard RG, Petersen BC, Blinder AS, Poterba JM (1988) Financing constraints and corporate investment. Brook Pap Econ Act 1988(1):141–206
Zurück zum Zitat Ferreira D, Ferreira MA, Raposo CC (2011) Board structure and price informativeness. J Financ Econ 99(3):523–545 Ferreira D, Ferreira MA, Raposo CC (2011) Board structure and price informativeness. J Financ Econ 99(3):523–545
Zurück zum Zitat FitzRoy FR, Kraft K (1993) Economic effects of codetermination. Scand J Econ 95:365–375 FitzRoy FR, Kraft K (1993) Economic effects of codetermination. Scand J Econ 95:365–375
Zurück zum Zitat FitzRoy F, Kraft K (2005) Co-determination, efficiency and productivity. Br J Ind Relat 43(2):233–247 FitzRoy F, Kraft K (2005) Co-determination, efficiency and productivity. Br J Ind Relat 43(2):233–247
Zurück zum Zitat Frost AC (2000) Explaining variation in workplace restructuring: The role of local union capabilities. ILR Rev 53(4):559–578 Frost AC (2000) Explaining variation in workplace restructuring: The role of local union capabilities. ILR Rev 53(4):559–578
Zurück zum Zitat Garcia JM, García B, Penalva F (2010) Accounting conservatism and firm investment efficiency. Working Paper Garcia JM, García B, Penalva F (2010) Accounting conservatism and firm investment efficiency. Working Paper
Zurück zum Zitat Ghaly M, Dang VA, Stathopoulos K (2015) Institutional investment horizons and labor investment efficiency. Working Paper Ghaly M, Dang VA, Stathopoulos K (2015) Institutional investment horizons and labor investment efficiency. Working Paper
Zurück zum Zitat Gorton G, Schmid FA (2000) Universal banking and the performance of German firms. J Financ Econ 58(1):29–80 Gorton G, Schmid FA (2000) Universal banking and the performance of German firms. J Financ Econ 58(1):29–80
Zurück zum Zitat Gorton G, Schmid FA (2004) Capital, labor, and the firm: a study of German codetermination. J Eur Econ Assoc 2(5):863–905 Gorton G, Schmid FA (2004) Capital, labor, and the firm: a study of German codetermination. J Eur Econ Assoc 2(5):863–905
Zurück zum Zitat Greenwald B, Stiglitz JE (1988) Imperfect information, finance constraints, and business fluctuations. In: Kohn M, Tsaing S (eds) Finance constraints, expectations, and macroeconomics. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 103–140 Greenwald B, Stiglitz JE (1988) Imperfect information, finance constraints, and business fluctuations. In: Kohn M, Tsaing S (eds) Finance constraints, expectations, and macroeconomics. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 103–140
Zurück zum Zitat Gurdon MA, Rai A (1990) Codetermination and enterprise performance: empirical evidence from west Germany. J Econ Bus 42(4):289–302 Gurdon MA, Rai A (1990) Codetermination and enterprise performance: empirical evidence from west Germany. J Econ Bus 42(4):289–302
Zurück zum Zitat Hamermesh D (1993) Labor demand. Princeton University Press, Princeton Hamermesh D (1993) Labor demand. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Zurück zum Zitat Hart OD (1983) Optimal labour contracts under asymmetric information: An introduction. Rev Econ Stud 50(1):3–35 Hart OD (1983) Optimal labour contracts under asymmetric information: An introduction. Rev Econ Stud 50(1):3–35
Zurück zum Zitat Herzberg F, Mausner B (1959) The motivation to work. Wiley, New York Herzberg F, Mausner B (1959) The motivation to work. Wiley, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Holmström B, Tirole J (1993) Market liquidity and performance monitoring. J Polit Econ 101(4):678–709 Holmström B, Tirole J (1993) Market liquidity and performance monitoring. J Polit Econ 101(4):678–709
Zurück zum Zitat Hovakimian A, Hovakimian G (2009) Cash flow sensitivity of investment. Eur Financ Manag 15(1):47–65 Hovakimian A, Hovakimian G (2009) Cash flow sensitivity of investment. Eur Financ Manag 15(1):47–65
Zurück zum Zitat Hubbard RG (1998) Capital-market imperfections and investment. J Econ Lit. 36(1):193–225 Hubbard RG (1998) Capital-market imperfections and investment. J Econ Lit. 36(1):193–225
Zurück zum Zitat Jensen MC, Meckling WH (1976) Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. J Financ Econ 3(4):305–360 Jensen MC, Meckling WH (1976) Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. J Financ Econ 3(4):305–360
Zurück zum Zitat Jensen MC, Meckling WH (1979) Rights and production functions: An application to labor-managed firms and codetermination. J Bus 52(4):469–506 Jensen MC, Meckling WH (1979) Rights and production functions: An application to labor-managed firms and codetermination. J Bus 52(4):469–506
Zurück zum Zitat Jung B, Lee W-J, Weber DP (2014) Financial reporting quality and labor investment efficiency. Contemp Account Res 31(4):1047–1076 Jung B, Lee W-J, Weber DP (2014) Financial reporting quality and labor investment efficiency. Contemp Account Res 31(4):1047–1076
Zurück zum Zitat Kim EH, Maug E, Schneider C (2018) Labor representation in governance as an insurance mechanism. Rev Finance 22(4):1251–1289 Kim EH, Maug E, Schneider C (2018) Labor representation in governance as an insurance mechanism. Rev Finance 22(4):1251–1289
Zurück zum Zitat Kleiner MM, Bouillon ML (1988) Providing business information to production workers: correlates of compensation and profitability. ILR Rev 41(4):605–617 Kleiner MM, Bouillon ML (1988) Providing business information to production workers: correlates of compensation and profitability. ILR Rev 41(4):605–617
Zurück zum Zitat Kraft K, Ugarkovic M (2006) Gesetzliche Mitbestimmung und Kapitalrendite. J Econ Stat (Jahrbuecher Fuer Nationaloekonomie Und Statistik) 226(5):588–604 Kraft K, Ugarkovic M (2006) Gesetzliche Mitbestimmung und Kapitalrendite. J Econ Stat (Jahrbuecher Fuer Nationaloekonomie Und Statistik) 226(5):588–604
Zurück zum Zitat Kraft K, Stank J, Dewenter R (2011) Co-determination and innovation. Camb J Econ 35(1):145–172 Kraft K, Stank J, Dewenter R (2011) Co-determination and innovation. Camb J Econ 35(1):145–172
Zurück zum Zitat LaFond R, Watts RL (2008) The information role of conservatism. Account Rev 83(2):447–478 LaFond R, Watts RL (2008) The information role of conservatism. Account Rev 83(2):447–478
Zurück zum Zitat Lazear EP, Freeman R (1995) An economic analysis of works councils. In: Rogers J, Streek W (eds) Works councils: consultations, representation and cooperation in industrial relations. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 27–52 Lazear EP, Freeman R (1995) An economic analysis of works councils. In: Rogers J, Streek W (eds) Works councils: consultations, representation and cooperation in industrial relations. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 27–52
Zurück zum Zitat Levine DI, Tyson LD (1990) Participation, productivity, and the firm’s environment. Paying for productivity. Washington DCS, pp 183–243 Levine DI, Tyson LD (1990) Participation, productivity, and the firm’s environment. Paying for productivity. Washington DCS, pp 183–243
Zurück zum Zitat Li F (2011) Earnings quality based on corporate investment decisions. J Account Res 49(3):721–752 Li F (2011) Earnings quality based on corporate investment decisions. J Account Res 49(3):721–752
Zurück zum Zitat Lopatta K, Buchholz F, Kaspereit T (2016) Asymmetric information and corporate social responsibility. Bus Soc 55(3):458–488 Lopatta K, Buchholz F, Kaspereit T (2016) Asymmetric information and corporate social responsibility. Bus Soc 55(3):458–488
Zurück zum Zitat Lopatta K, Böttcher K, Jaeschke R (2018) When labor representatives join supervisory boards: empirical evidence of the relationship between the change to parity codetermination and working capital and operating cash flows. J Bus Econ 88(1):1–39 Lopatta K, Böttcher K, Jaeschke R (2018) When labor representatives join supervisory boards: empirical evidence of the relationship between the change to parity codetermination and working capital and operating cash flows. J Bus Econ 88(1):1–39
Zurück zum Zitat Machin S, Wood S (2005) Human resource management as a substitute for trade unions in British workplaces. Ind Labor Relat Rev 58(2):201–218 Machin S, Wood S (2005) Human resource management as a substitute for trade unions in British workplaces. Ind Labor Relat Rev 58(2):201–218
Zurück zum Zitat Maslow AH (1943) A theory of human motivation. Psychol Rev 50(4):370–396 Maslow AH (1943) A theory of human motivation. Psychol Rev 50(4):370–396
Zurück zum Zitat Matsa DA (2010) Capital structure as a strategic variable: evidence from collective bargaining. J Finance 65(3):1197–1232 Matsa DA (2010) Capital structure as a strategic variable: evidence from collective bargaining. J Finance 65(3):1197–1232
Zurück zum Zitat Modigliani F, Miller MH (1958) The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. Am Econ Rev 48(3):261–297 Modigliani F, Miller MH (1958) The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. Am Econ Rev 48(3):261–297
Zurück zum Zitat Myers SC, Majluf NS (1984) Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. J Financ Econ 13(2):187–221 Myers SC, Majluf NS (1984) Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. J Financ Econ 13(2):187–221
Zurück zum Zitat Nickell SJ (1978) Fixed costs, employment and labour demand over the cycle. Economica 45(180):329–345 Nickell SJ (1978) Fixed costs, employment and labour demand over the cycle. Economica 45(180):329–345
Zurück zum Zitat Nickell S, Nicolitsas D (1999) How does financial pressure affect firms? Eur Econ Rev 43(8):1435–1456 Nickell S, Nicolitsas D (1999) How does financial pressure affect firms? Eur Econ Rev 43(8):1435–1456
Zurück zum Zitat Oi WY (1962) Labor as a quasi-fixed factor. J Polit Econ 70(6):538–555 Oi WY (1962) Labor as a quasi-fixed factor. J Polit Econ 70(6):538–555
Zurück zum Zitat Perotti EC, Spier KE (1993) Capital structure as a bargaining tool: The role of leverage in contract renegotiation. Am Econ Rev 83(5):1131–1141 Perotti EC, Spier KE (1993) Capital structure as a bargaining tool: The role of leverage in contract renegotiation. Am Econ Rev 83(5):1131–1141
Zurück zum Zitat Pinnuck M, Lillis AM (2007) Profits versus losses: does reporting an accounting loss act as a heuristic trigger to exercise the abandonment option and divest employees? Account Rev 82(4):1031–1053 Pinnuck M, Lillis AM (2007) Profits versus losses: does reporting an accounting loss act as a heuristic trigger to exercise the abandonment option and divest employees? Account Rev 82(4):1031–1053
Zurück zum Zitat Renaud S (2007) Dynamic efficiency of supervisory board codetermination in Germany. Labour 21(4–5):689–712 Renaud S (2007) Dynamic efficiency of supervisory board codetermination in Germany. Labour 21(4–5):689–712
Zurück zum Zitat Roodman D (2009) How to do xtabond2: an introduction to difference and system GMM in Stata. Stata J 9:86–136 Roodman D (2009) How to do xtabond2: an introduction to difference and system GMM in Stata. Stata J 9:86–136
Zurück zum Zitat Schmid FA, Seger F (1998) Arbeitnehmermitbestimmung, Allokation von Entscheidungsrechten und Shareholder Value. Zeitschrift Fur Betriebswirtschaft 68:453–474 Schmid FA, Seger F (1998) Arbeitnehmermitbestimmung, Allokation von Entscheidungsrechten und Shareholder Value. Zeitschrift Fur Betriebswirtschaft 68:453–474
Zurück zum Zitat Scott TW (1994) Incentives and disincentives for financial disclosure: voluntary disclosure of defined benefit pension plan information by Canadian firms. Account Rev 69(1):26–43 Scott TW (1994) Incentives and disincentives for financial disclosure: voluntary disclosure of defined benefit pension plan information by Canadian firms. Account Rev 69(1):26–43
Zurück zum Zitat Sharpe SA (1994) Financial market imperfections, firm leverage, and the cyclicality of employment. Am Econ Rev 84(4):1060–1074 Sharpe SA (1994) Financial market imperfections, firm leverage, and the cyclicality of employment. Am Econ Rev 84(4):1060–1074
Zurück zum Zitat Sick S, Pütz L (2011) Der deutschen Unternehmensmitbestimmung entzogen: Die Zahl der Unternehmen mit ausländischer Rechtsform wächst. WSI-Mitteilungen (FRG 104), 01, 34–40 Sick S, Pütz L (2011) Der deutschen Unternehmensmitbestimmung entzogen: Die Zahl der Unternehmen mit ausländischer Rechtsform wächst. WSI-Mitteilungen (FRG 104), 01, 34–40
Zurück zum Zitat Stein JC (2003) Agency, information and corporate investment. Handb Econ Finance 1:111–165 Stein JC (2003) Agency, information and corporate investment. Handb Econ Finance 1:111–165
Zurück zum Zitat Vitols S (2005) Prospects for trade unions in the evolving European system of corporate governance. Report 92 ETUI-REHS and HBS Vitols S (2005) Prospects for trade unions in the evolving European system of corporate governance. Report 92 ETUI-REHS and HBS
Zurück zum Zitat Vitols S (2006) Ökonomische Auswirkungen der paritätischen Mitbestimmung. Themenheft Mitbestimmung Und Unternehmenspolitik, Ed. DGB-Bundesvorstand, Berlin Vitols S (2006) Ökonomische Auswirkungen der paritätischen Mitbestimmung. Themenheft Mitbestimmung Und Unternehmenspolitik, Ed. DGB-Bundesvorstand, Berlin
Zurück zum Zitat Vitols S (2008) Beteiligung der Arbeitnehmervertreter in Aufsichtsratsausschüssen: Auswirkungen auf Unternehmensperformanz und Vorstandsvergütung. Hans-Böckler-Stiftung Vitols S (2008) Beteiligung der Arbeitnehmervertreter in Aufsichtsratsausschüssen: Auswirkungen auf Unternehmensperformanz und Vorstandsvergütung. Hans-Böckler-Stiftung
Zurück zum Zitat Wagner J (2011) One-third codetermination at company supervisory boards and firm performance in German manufacturing industries: first direct evidence from a new type of enterprise data. Schmollers Jahrbuch 131(1):91–106 Wagner J (2011) One-third codetermination at company supervisory boards and firm performance in German manufacturing industries: first direct evidence from a new type of enterprise data. Schmollers Jahrbuch 131(1):91–106
Zurück zum Zitat Werner J-R, Zimmermann J (2005) Unternehmerische Mitbestimmung in Deutschland: Eine empirische Analyse der Auswirkungen von Gewerkschaftsmacht in Aufsichtsräten. Industrielle Beziehungen/German J Ind Relat 12(3):339–354 Werner J-R, Zimmermann J (2005) Unternehmerische Mitbestimmung in Deutschland: Eine empirische Analyse der Auswirkungen von Gewerkschaftsmacht in Aufsichtsräten. Industrielle Beziehungen/German J Ind Relat 12(3):339–354
Metadaten
Titel
Parity codetermination at the board level and labor investment efficiency: evidence on German listed firms
verfasst von
Kerstin Lopatta
Katarina Böttcher
Sumit K. Lodhia
Sebastian A. Tideman
Publikationsdatum
08.03.2019
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Journal of Business Economics / Ausgabe 1/2020
Print ISSN: 0044-2372
Elektronische ISSN: 1861-8928
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11573-019-00930-9

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2020

Journal of Business Economics 1/2020 Zur Ausgabe