Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 1-2/2018

02.03.2018

Protest and property crime: political use of police resources and the deterrence of crime

verfasst von: Jaewook Byeon, Iljoong Kim, Dongwon Lee

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 1-2/2018

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This article investigates the claim that the political use of police resources promotes crime. Using a panel of South Korean metropolitan areas, we show that (1) the reallocation of police resources toward the control of political protests reduces arrest rates for crime and (2) the resulting reduction in criminal arrests significantly increases the incidence of crime. Overall, the impact of the reallocation of police resources works mainly through tradeoffs with arrest rates. Our findings imply that it is not the size of the police per se, but the allocation of police resources toward crime control that deters crime.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
The tradeoff in the allocation of police resources between drug enforcement and non-drug crime is not unique to the United States. See, for instance, Mendes (2000) and Miron (2001).
 
2
Some research, however, has maintained that drug users are no more likely to commit non-drug-related crimes than are non-drug users (e.g., Benson et al. 1992).
 
3
Note that political protests could also be endogenous to Index I crimes. In the United States, for instance, political protests often are accompanied by theft, arson, and even vandalism. In Korean culture, however, those kinds of behaviors are not significant because people engaging in political protests generally are not members of crime-prone groups. If political protests are indeed positively associated with Index I crimes in South Korea, then the tradeoff effect may be even larger than the results of our study indicate.
 
4
As an anecdote, the Seoul Metropolitan Police Agency temporarily reassigned police forces from public security (e.g., protest control) to public safety (e.g., patrolling and criminal investigations) between December 2014 and January 2015. As a consequence, the incidences of five types of serious crimes (homicide, robbery, rape and sexual harassment, theft and violence) fell by 34.4% compared to the same period the previous year. In particular, the reduction in property crimes, such as larceny-theft and burglary, was substantial because, for instance, police patrols in residential areas were reinforced. That anecdote suggests that even the temporary reallocation of police forces seems to deter crime, potentially because police forces are effective across different functions (e.g., across public security and public safety).
 
5
Similarly, prosecutors pursue their (bureaucratic) self-interests in prosecuting cases. For instance, they may prefer cases that either require less time to prepare for trial or benefit their future career prospects (e.g., Boylan 2005; Gordon and Huber 2009).
 
6
These police forces typically belong to the public security bureau (located in each metropolitan area or local police agency). Data were obtained from the Police Statistical Yearbook, published by the Korean National Police Agency.
 
7
The policies range from the decision to send troops to Iraq (2004) and the importation of US beef (2008) to the Miryang transmission tower projects (2014). Other major incidences include one on the Yangju highway (2002), in which a US armored military vehicle struck and killed two teenage schoolgirls; the impeachment of President Roh Moo-hyun (2004); the Yongsan incident (2009); meddling in the presidential election by the National Intelligence Service (2012); the Seoul City Employee Spy case (2013); the Sewol ferry disaster (2014); and the impeachment of President Park Geun-hye (2016–2017).
 
8
The Korea National Police Agency (central agency) and the 17 local agencies are subordinate to the Minister of the Interior.
 
9
This sometimes results in disproportionately large police forces mobilized for certain protests. For instance, Arnold Fang of Amnesty International said, “The force used by police at the Miryang protest was disproportionate and in breach of international standards.” Note that the Miryang protest (2014) took place in the second year of President Park’s administration.
 
10
The share of police officers in security control relative to police officers in crime investigation increased from 45.2% in 2001 to 54.1% in 2015. During the same period, the probability of arrest for conventional crimes (including property and violent crimes) fell from 78.2 to 74.9%. The reduction in arrest rates may explain why conventional crimes rose at an annual rate of 1.9% during the same period. These data were obtained from the Police Statistical Yearbook, published by the Korean National Police Agency, and the Annual Crime Reports, published by the Supreme Prosecutors’ Office of Korea.
 
11
All crime data and deterrence variables were obtained from the Annual Crime Reports. Demographic and socioeconomic variables were obtained from Statistics Korea (http://​kosis.​kr).
 
12
First, theft in Korea includes larceny and motor-vehicle theft, which constitute about 80% of property crimes in the United States (Uniform Crime Reports 2013). Second, theft also includes part of the burglary category in the United States.
 
13
Other categories of property crimes include fraud, embezzlement and vandalism. See Kim and Kim (2015) for detailed accounts of these subcategories.
 
14
All data on protests and police deployment were obtained from the Police Statistical Yearbook by the National Police Agency. Some of the missing values were collected through the Open Information System (www.​open.​co.​kr) and interviews with local police agencies. The Korean National Police Agency classifies six types of police mobilization for security purposes: protests, guard/security, emergency guard, congestion, disasters and elections. We focus on protests and guard/security mobilizations because those two types of deployment are most likely to be politically relevant in Korea. For instance, we do not include police security deployments for elections because major elections take place only every two to four years, and elections in Korea usually are peaceful events that require limited police presences.
 
15
A local police agency consists of various departments working in cooperation, including officers assigned to the public security, criminal and special investigation, national security and narcotics units.
 
16
Although the decision to reallocate police resources is made at the local level, the central agency has some influence on the actions of local police agencies. That influence opens up the possibility that the central agency may allocate more police resources to areas where political opposition is greater if protests are frequent. Another possibility is that more police resources could be allocated to locations where the regime is supported strongly (to strengthen that support). If so, the tradeoff effect will not exclusively be local because the other areas from which police are drawn should have less crime control regardless of political protests in those areas. However, reallocation of police resources across cities and regions is not common.
 
17
President Park Geun-hye was impeached on March 10, 2017.
 
18
Since the data are not available for the first 2 years of Kim’s administration (1998 and 1999), EARLY is 1 for 2003–2004, 2008–2009, and 2013–2014; 0 otherwise. We do not include pre-2000 data because crime statistics before and after 2000 are not consistent owing to major changes in data compiling and crime categorization.
 
19
We first collected the number of prosecutors from all 58 district prosecutors’ offices. We then grouped them into 13 metropolitan areas to calculate the probability of prosecution.
 
20
Since the early 1970s, many studies have found a positive effect on crimes of certain age groups in a predominantly male population (Freeman 1996).
 
21
The recent literature has focused on unemployment rates among certain crime-prone groups, such as young people, because the aggregate unemployment rate may not identify the marginal criminal (Raphael and Winter-Ebmer 2001; Gould et al. 2002; Lin 2008; Mustard 2010).
 
22
Previous studies have emphasized that alcohol consumption is an important predictor of violent crimes (e.g., Saridakis 2004).
 
23
We thank an anonymous reviewer for suggesting the IV approach.
 
24
We do not include time dummies because of multicollinearity with EARLY t . We also included both linear and quadratic time trends (not reported). The results did not affect our main results.
 
25
The impact of PROTEST on CR is potentially endogenous, however. For instance, a lack of crime control (i.e., higher CR) and more political protests may both reflect social instability. Another possibility is that if political protests are about the government’s handling of crime, a potential endogeneity problem could arise. However, most political protests arose over government policies involving sending troops overseas, international trade, infrastructure projects and impeachment of the president. Very few, if any, protests were about the handling of crime during our sample period. In any case, excluding PROTEST1 and PROTEST2 did not change the main results (not reported).
 
26
For brevity, we only report the results for POLIT1. Using POLIT2 does not change the main results (available upon request to the authors).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Almer, C., & Goeschl, T. (2011). The political economy of the environmental criminal justice system: A production function spproach. Public Choice, 148(3), 611–630.CrossRef Almer, C., & Goeschl, T. (2011). The political economy of the environmental criminal justice system: A production function spproach. Public Choice, 148(3), 611–630.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat National Assembly. (2014). Illegal protests and demonstrates. Seoul: Inspect of the Government Offices in South Korea. National Assembly. (2014). Illegal protests and demonstrates. Seoul: Inspect of the Government Offices in South Korea.
Zurück zum Zitat Becker, G. S. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76(2), 169–217.CrossRef Becker, G. S. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76(2), 169–217.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. L. (2010). The allocation of police. In B. L. Benson & P. R. Zimmerman (Eds.), Handbook on the economics of crime (pp. 184–217). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRef Benson, B. L. (2010). The allocation of police. In B. L. Benson & P. R. Zimmerman (Eds.), Handbook on the economics of crime (pp. 184–217). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. L., Kim, I., & Rasmussen, D. W. (1994). Estimating deterrence effects: A public choice perspective on the economics of crime literature. Southern Economic Journal, 61(1), 161–168.CrossRef Benson, B. L., Kim, I., & Rasmussen, D. W. (1994). Estimating deterrence effects: A public choice perspective on the economics of crime literature. Southern Economic Journal, 61(1), 161–168.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. L., Kim, I., Rasmussen, D. W., & Zuehlke, T. W. (1992). Is property crime caused by drug use or drug enforcement policy? Applied Economics, 24(7), 679–692.CrossRef Benson, B. L., Kim, I., Rasmussen, D. W., & Zuehlke, T. W. (1992). Is property crime caused by drug use or drug enforcement policy? Applied Economics, 24(7), 679–692.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. L., & Rasmussen, D. W. (1991). Relationship between illicit drug enforcement policy and property crimes. Contemporary Policy Issues, 9(4), 106–115.CrossRef Benson, B. L., & Rasmussen, D. W. (1991). Relationship between illicit drug enforcement policy and property crimes. Contemporary Policy Issues, 9(4), 106–115.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. L., Rasmussen, D. W., & Kim, I. (1998). Deterrence and public police: Trade-offs in the allocation of police resources. International Review of Law and Economics, 18(1), 77–100.CrossRef Benson, B. L., Rasmussen, D. W., & Kim, I. (1998). Deterrence and public police: Trade-offs in the allocation of police resources. International Review of Law and Economics, 18(1), 77–100.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. L., Rasmussen, D. W., & Sollars, D. L. (1995). Police bureaucrats, their incentives, and the war on drugs. Public Choice, 83(1), 21–45.CrossRef Benson, B. L., Rasmussen, D. W., & Sollars, D. L. (1995). Police bureaucrats, their incentives, and the war on drugs. Public Choice, 83(1), 21–45.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Boylan, R. T. (2005). What do prosecutors maximize? Evidence from the careers of U.S. attorneys. American Law and Economics Review, 7(2), 379–402.CrossRef Boylan, R. T. (2005). What do prosecutors maximize? Evidence from the careers of U.S. attorneys. American Law and Economics Review, 7(2), 379–402.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Buonanno, P., & Montolio, D. (2008). Identifying the socio-economic and demographic determinants of crime across Spanish provinces. International Review of Law and Economics, 28(2), 89–97.CrossRef Buonanno, P., & Montolio, D. (2008). Identifying the socio-economic and demographic determinants of crime across Spanish provinces. International Review of Law and Economics, 28(2), 89–97.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chandrasekher, A. C. (2016). The effect of police slowdowns on crime. American Law and Economic Review, 18(2), 385–437.CrossRef Chandrasekher, A. C. (2016). The effect of police slowdowns on crime. American Law and Economic Review, 18(2), 385–437.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cook, P., & Moore, M. (1993). Violence reduction through restrictions on alcohol availability. Alcohol Health and Research World, 17(2), 151–156. Cook, P., & Moore, M. (1993). Violence reduction through restrictions on alcohol availability. Alcohol Health and Research World, 17(2), 151–156.
Zurück zum Zitat Cornwell, C., & Trumbull, W. N. (1994). Estimating the economic model of crime with panel data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 76, 360–366.CrossRef Cornwell, C., & Trumbull, W. N. (1994). Estimating the economic model of crime with panel data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 76, 360–366.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Doyle, J., Ahmed, E., & Horn, R. (1999). The effects of labor markets and income inequality on crime: Evidence from panel data. Southern Economic Journal, 65(4), 717–738.CrossRef Doyle, J., Ahmed, E., & Horn, R. (1999). The effects of labor markets and income inequality on crime: Evidence from panel data. Southern Economic Journal, 65(4), 717–738.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Drago, F., Galbiati, R., & Vertova, P. (2009). The deterrent effects of prison: Evidence from a natural experiment. Journal of Political Economy, 117(2), 257–280.CrossRef Drago, F., Galbiati, R., & Vertova, P. (2009). The deterrent effects of prison: Evidence from a natural experiment. Journal of Political Economy, 117(2), 257–280.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dušek, L. (2012). Crime, deterrence, and democracy. German Economic Review, 13(4), 447–469.CrossRef Dušek, L. (2012). Crime, deterrence, and democracy. German Economic Review, 13(4), 447–469.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ehrlich, I. (1996). Crime, punishment, and the market for offenses. Journal of Economic Perspective, 10(1), 43–67.CrossRef Ehrlich, I. (1996). Crime, punishment, and the market for offenses. Journal of Economic Perspective, 10(1), 43–67.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Entorf, H., & Spengler, H. (2015). Crime, prosecutors, and the certainty of conviction. European Journal of Law and Economics, 39(1), 167–201.CrossRef Entorf, H., & Spengler, H. (2015). Crime, prosecutors, and the certainty of conviction. European Journal of Law and Economics, 39(1), 167–201.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Entorf, H., & Winker, P. (2008). Investigating the drugs-crime channel in economics of crime models: Empirical evidence from panel data of the German states. International Review of Law and Economics, 28(1), 8–22.CrossRef Entorf, H., & Winker, P. (2008). Investigating the drugs-crime channel in economics of crime models: Empirical evidence from panel data of the German states. International Review of Law and Economics, 28(1), 8–22.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Epstein, L., & Knight, J. (1996). On the struggle for judicial supremacy. Law and Society Review, 30(1), 87–120.CrossRef Epstein, L., & Knight, J. (1996). On the struggle for judicial supremacy. Law and Society Review, 30(1), 87–120.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ferejohn, J. A., & Weingast, B. (1992). A positive theory of statutory interpretation. International Review of Law and Economics, 12(2), 263–279.CrossRef Ferejohn, J. A., & Weingast, B. (1992). A positive theory of statutory interpretation. International Review of Law and Economics, 12(2), 263–279.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fougère, D., Kramarz, F., & Pouget, J. (2009). Youth unemployment and crime in France. Journal of European Economic Association, 7(5), 909–938.CrossRef Fougère, D., Kramarz, F., & Pouget, J. (2009). Youth unemployment and crime in France. Journal of European Economic Association, 7(5), 909–938.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Freeman, R. B. (1996). Why do so many young American men commit crimes and what might we do about it? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(1), 25–42.CrossRef Freeman, R. B. (1996). Why do so many young American men commit crimes and what might we do about it? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(1), 25–42.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goldstein, P. J., Brownstein, H. H., & Ryan, P. J. (1992). Drug-related homicides in New York: 1984 and 1988. Crime and Delinquency, 38(4), 459–476.CrossRef Goldstein, P. J., Brownstein, H. H., & Ryan, P. J. (1992). Drug-related homicides in New York: 1984 and 1988. Crime and Delinquency, 38(4), 459–476.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gordon, S. C., & Huber, G. A. (2009). The political economy of prosecution. Annual Review of Law and Social Science, 5, 135–156.CrossRef Gordon, S. C., & Huber, G. A. (2009). The political economy of prosecution. Annual Review of Law and Social Science, 5, 135–156.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gould, E., Weinberg, B., & Mustard, D. (2002). Crime rates and local labor market opportunities in the United States: 1979–1997. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(1), 45–61.CrossRef Gould, E., Weinberg, B., & Mustard, D. (2002). Crime rates and local labor market opportunities in the United States: 1979–1997. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(1), 45–61.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Helmke, G. (2002). The logic of strategic defection: Court-executive relations in Argentina under dictatorship and democracy. American Political Science Review, 96(2), 291–303.CrossRef Helmke, G. (2002). The logic of strategic defection: Court-executive relations in Argentina under dictatorship and democracy. American Political Science Review, 96(2), 291–303.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Johnson, R., & Raphael, S. (2012). How much crime reduction does the marginal prisoner buy? Journal of Law and Economics, 55(2), 275–310.CrossRef Johnson, R., & Raphael, S. (2012). How much crime reduction does the marginal prisoner buy? Journal of Law and Economics, 55(2), 275–310.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kim, I., Byeon, J., & Lee, D. (2017). Violent crime and female victimization: Evidence from metropolitan regions in South Korea. Applied Economics, 49(46), 4601–4616.CrossRef Kim, I., Byeon, J., & Lee, D. (2017). Violent crime and female victimization: Evidence from metropolitan regions in South Korea. Applied Economics, 49(46), 4601–4616.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kim, D., & Kim, I. (2015). Trade-offs in the allocation of prosecution resources: An opportunity cost of overcriminalization? Applied Economics, 47(16), 1652–1669.CrossRef Kim, D., & Kim, I. (2015). Trade-offs in the allocation of prosecution resources: An opportunity cost of overcriminalization? Applied Economics, 47(16), 1652–1669.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Korea Development Institute. (2006). A study on social and economic cost in illegal and violent protest. Seoul: Korea Development Institute. Korea Development Institute. (2006). A study on social and economic cost in illegal and violent protest. Seoul: Korea Development Institute.
Zurück zum Zitat Kuziemko, I., & Levitt, S. (2004). An empirical analysis of imprisoning drug offenders. Journal of Public Economics, 88(9–10), 2043–2066.CrossRef Kuziemko, I., & Levitt, S. (2004). An empirical analysis of imprisoning drug offenders. Journal of Public Economics, 88(9–10), 2043–2066.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Laspa, C. (2015). Do the economic factors affect criminality? Evidence from Greece, 1991–2010. European Journal of Law and Economics, 39(1), 107–118.CrossRef Laspa, C. (2015). Do the economic factors affect criminality? Evidence from Greece, 1991–2010. European Journal of Law and Economics, 39(1), 107–118.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Levitt, S. D. (1997). Using electoral cycles in police hiring to estimate the effect of police on crime. American Economic Review, 87(3), 270–290. Levitt, S. D. (1997). Using electoral cycles in police hiring to estimate the effect of police on crime. American Economic Review, 87(3), 270–290.
Zurück zum Zitat Lin, M. (2008). Does unemployment increase crime? Evidence from U.S. data 1974–2000. Journal of Human Resources, 43(2), 413–436.CrossRef Lin, M. (2008). Does unemployment increase crime? Evidence from U.S. data 1974–2000. Journal of Human Resources, 43(2), 413–436.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lin, M. (2009). More police, less crime: Evidence from US state data. International Review of Law and Economics, 29(2), 73–80.CrossRef Lin, M. (2009). More police, less crime: Evidence from US state data. International Review of Law and Economics, 29(2), 73–80.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Machin, S., & Marie, O. (2011). Crime and police resources: The street crime initiative. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(4), 678–701.CrossRef Machin, S., & Marie, O. (2011). Crime and police resources: The street crime initiative. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(4), 678–701.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mast, B. D., Benson, B. L., & Rasmussen, D. W. (2000). Entrepreneurial police and drug enforcement policy. Public Choice, 104(3), 285–308.CrossRef Mast, B. D., Benson, B. L., & Rasmussen, D. W. (2000). Entrepreneurial police and drug enforcement policy. Public Choice, 104(3), 285–308.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mendes, S. M. (2000). Property crime and drug enforcement in Portugal. Criminal Justice Policy Review, 11(3), 195–216.CrossRef Mendes, S. M. (2000). Property crime and drug enforcement in Portugal. Criminal Justice Policy Review, 11(3), 195–216.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Miron, J. A. (2001). Violence, guns, and drugs: A cross-country analysis. Journal of Law and Economics, 44(S2), 615–633.CrossRef Miron, J. A. (2001). Violence, guns, and drugs: A cross-country analysis. Journal of Law and Economics, 44(S2), 615–633.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mustard, D. B. (2010). Labor markets and crime: New evidence on an old puzzle. In B. L. Benson & P. R. Zimmerman (Eds.), Handbook on the economics of crime (pp. 342–358). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Mustard, D. B. (2010). Labor markets and crime: New evidence on an old puzzle. In B. L. Benson & P. R. Zimmerman (Eds.), Handbook on the economics of crime (pp. 342–358). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Zurück zum Zitat Ochsen, C. (2010). Crime and labor market policy in Europe. International Review of Law and Economics, 30(1), 52–61.CrossRef Ochsen, C. (2010). Crime and labor market policy in Europe. International Review of Law and Economics, 30(1), 52–61.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Raphael, S., & Winter-Ebmer, R. (2001). Identifying the effect of unemployment on crime. Journal of Law and Economics, 44(1), 259–283.CrossRef Raphael, S., & Winter-Ebmer, R. (2001). Identifying the effect of unemployment on crime. Journal of Law and Economics, 44(1), 259–283.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Saridakis, G. (2004). Violent crime in the United States of America: A time-series analysis between 1960–2000. European Journal of Law and Economics, 18(2), 203–221.CrossRef Saridakis, G. (2004). Violent crime in the United States of America: A time-series analysis between 1960–2000. European Journal of Law and Economics, 18(2), 203–221.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Saridakis, G., & Spengler, H. (2012). Crime, deterrence and unemployment in Greece: A panel data approach. Social Science Journal, 49(2), 167–174.CrossRef Saridakis, G., & Spengler, H. (2012). Crime, deterrence and unemployment in Greece: A panel data approach. Social Science Journal, 49(2), 167–174.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shepard, E., & Blackley, P. (2005). Drug enforcement and crime: Recent evidence from New York state. Social Science Quarterly, 86(2), 323–342.CrossRef Shepard, E., & Blackley, P. (2005). Drug enforcement and crime: Recent evidence from New York state. Social Science Quarterly, 86(2), 323–342.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shepherd, J. M. (2002). Police, prosecutors, criminals, and determinate sentencing: The truth about truth-in-sentencing laws. Journal of Law and Economics, 45(2), 509–533.CrossRef Shepherd, J. M. (2002). Police, prosecutors, criminals, and determinate sentencing: The truth about truth-in-sentencing laws. Journal of Law and Economics, 45(2), 509–533.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sherman, L. W. (2004). Fair and effective policing. In J. Q. Wilson & J. Petersillia (Eds.), Crime: Public policies for crime control (pp. 327–348). San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies Press. Sherman, L. W. (2004). Fair and effective policing. In J. Q. Wilson & J. Petersillia (Eds.), Crime: Public policies for crime control (pp. 327–348). San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Sherman, L. W., & Weisburd, D. (1995). General deterrent effects of police patrol in crime ‘hot spots’: A randomized, controlled trial. Justice Quarterly, 12(4), 625–648.CrossRef Sherman, L. W., & Weisburd, D. (1995). General deterrent effects of police patrol in crime ‘hot spots’: A randomized, controlled trial. Justice Quarterly, 12(4), 625–648.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sollars, D. L., Benson, B. L., & Rasmussen, D. W. (1994). Drug enforcement and the deterrence of property crime among local jurisdictions. Public Finance Quarterly, 22(1), 22–45.CrossRef Sollars, D. L., Benson, B. L., & Rasmussen, D. W. (1994). Drug enforcement and the deterrence of property crime among local jurisdictions. Public Finance Quarterly, 22(1), 22–45.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Protest and property crime: political use of police resources and the deterrence of crime
verfasst von
Jaewook Byeon
Iljoong Kim
Dongwon Lee
Publikationsdatum
02.03.2018
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 1-2/2018
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0525-5

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1-2/2018

Public Choice 1-2/2018 Zur Ausgabe