Skip to main content

2017 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

3. Public Procurement of Public Goods as Innovation Policy: The Cloud of New Technologies Around Military Product Development

verfasst von : Gunnar Eliasson

Erschienen in: Visible Costs and Invisible Benefits

Verlag: Springer International Publishing

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Advanced industrial production is always surrounded by a cloud of new technology, available to each and all in proportion to the ability of local entrepreneurs to pick up and commercialize its content – receiver competence. We talk about technological spillovers or positive externalities, a concept originally invented and used by the nineteenth-century British economists Henry Sidgwick, Arthur Pigou, and Alfred Marshall (1890). Marshall introduced the theoretical concept to overcome the shortcomings of the then dominant static economic model that I will have reason to return to in the theoretical Chap. 13. Most of this document is however devoted to measuring the economy-wide long-term consequences of technologies created during military product development.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
It may therefore require a separate explanation. See Sect. 5.​4.​1. The Gripen of Sect. 4 was not originally planned for exports. The exports of Gripens, for instance, to South Africa and Brazil net of modification work for those markets and costs for manufacturing the aircraft will therefore appear as “spillovers.” The A26 submarine (in Chap. 9) is a more complicated case, in that the original price charged to FMV was based on some submarines being exported. If not so, the contract was to be negotiated.
 
2
The internal profit targeting practice I met with in large US firms, where CHQ staff could not fully assess the capacity of divisions or profit centers to deliver, was to demand the “same as before” and a little more (see case on page 50f in Eliasson 1976a). If division management was unwilling or not capable of delivering an improvement, they had to credibly explain why, or management change was likely to be enacted. Maintain or improve profits, the MIP principle, was a commonly used targeting principle (Eliasson 1976a:159, 236ff, 1991a, 2005b). The MIP principle can be shown to approximate a short-term ex ante profit maximization ambition of the firm and is so implemented in the micro to macro model presented in Sect. 13.​6.
 
3
The Swedish military procurement agency FMV could draw on previous (before Gripen) industrial experience from having itself coordinated development work on manufacturing and assembly of military aircraft over specialist subcontractors. Saab was then a subcontractor to FMV. With the Gripen this systems coordination and integration task became overwhelming for FMV, and it gradually migrated over to Saab.
 
4
We have a terminology problem of sorts here, since traditional econometric literature refers to estimated spillovers as externalities, without recognizing the intermediary and very resource demanding commercialization process (see Sect. 12.​3 and Chap. 13).
 
5
In the industrial subsidy study referred to earlier (Carlsson 1983a,b; also see Sect. 14.​6), the micro to macro model was used, and wages were endogenously determined and thus also opportunity costs.
 
6
Between 1950 and 1996, the share of Swedish manufacturing industry in GNP had decreased from 30 to 23 percent according to the national accounts but had not decreased at all but rather stayed constant, between 45 and 50 percent the entire period, when corrected for outsourced engineering-related service production to reach 56 percent in 1996 (Eliasson & Johansson, 1999).
 
7
Burenstam Linder (1961) made that last point but referred to it as a “comparative advantage” of static international trade theory.
 
8
An externality (positive or negative) is a phenomenon that is observed, but that cannot be explained within the existing economic model. The term was first used by British economists in the nineteenth century, among them by Alfred Marshall (1890), in his attempts to deal with the deficiencies of the static Walrasian model. The so-called “new growth theory” attempts to endogenize (“explain”) spillovers within the static neoclassical model.
 
9
Or more precisely, as they write, constant returns to scale “together with the necessary conditions for producer equilibrium.”
 
10
Positive spillovers “insert” a positive wedge between the private and the social rate of return on R&D. The spillover multiplier is the ratio between the estimated social values created net of opportunity costs and the R&D investment that has created them. The difference between social and private rates of return is roughly proportional to the spillover multiplier and, as well, to the estimated underinvestment in R&D (see Eliasson 2010a: Supplement II, Sect. 5.​4 and Chap. 13). That underinvestment will go away as diminishing returns set in when private R&D is expanded. Whether or when diminishing returns set in is an empirical question in new growth theory.
 
11
Bentzel (1980), using a macro model, came to roughly the same conclusion for Sweden for the years 1870–1975.
 
12
While the Gunnarsson et al. (2004) conclusion draws on Griliches (1969) proposition of a technical complementarity between R&D and human capital, the commercialization is the downstream production activity of turning technically defined innovations into a business through entrepreneurship and industrially competent venture finance (Eliasson 2003, and Table 1.​3).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Bentzel, R. (1980). Svensk ekonomisk tilväxt 1870–1975 (Swedish economic growth 1870–1975). In E. Dahmén & G. Eliasson (Eds.). Bentzel, R. (1980). Svensk ekonomisk tilväxt 1870–1975 (Swedish economic growth 1870–1975). In E. Dahmén & G. Eliasson (Eds.).
Zurück zum Zitat Burenstam-Linder, S. (1961). An essay on trade and transformation. Uppsala: Wiley. Burenstam-Linder, S. (1961). An essay on trade and transformation. Uppsala: Wiley.
Zurück zum Zitat Caballero, R. I., & Jaffe, A. B. (1993, May). How high are the giants’ shoulders? – An empirical assessment of knowledge spillovers and creative destruction in a model of economic growth NBER Working Paper No. 4370. Cambridge, MA. Caballero, R. I., & Jaffe, A. B. (1993, May). How high are the giants’ shoulders? – An empirical assessment of knowledge spillovers and creative destruction in a model of economic growth NBER Working Paper No. 4370. Cambridge, MA.
Zurück zum Zitat Carlsson, B. (1983a). Industrial subsidies in Sweden: Macro-economic effects and an international comparison. Journal of Industrial Economics, XXXII(1), 9–14. Carlsson, B. (1983a). Industrial subsidies in Sweden: Macro-economic effects and an international comparison. Journal of Industrial Economics, XXXII(1), 9–14.
Zurück zum Zitat Carlsson, B. (1983b). Industrial subsidies in Sweden: Simulations on a micro-to-macro model. In Microeconometrics, IUI yearbook 1982–1983. IUI: Stockholm. Carlsson, B. (1983b). Industrial subsidies in Sweden: Simulations on a micro-to-macro model. In Microeconometrics, IUI yearbook 1982–1983. IUI: Stockholm.
Zurück zum Zitat Davies, A., Ergas, H., & Thomson, M. (2012). Should Australia build warships? An economic and strategic analysis. Paper presented at the RAN Seapower conference, Sydney 1 February 2012, Australian Strategic Policy Institute (ASPI). Davies, A., Ergas, H., & Thomson, M. (2012). Should Australia build warships? An economic and strategic analysis. Paper presented at the RAN Seapower conference, Sydney 1 February 2012, Australian Strategic Policy Institute (ASPI).
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (1976a). Business economic planning – Theory, practice and comparison. London, etc.: Wiley. Eliasson, G. (1976a). Business economic planning – Theory, practice and comparison. London, etc.: Wiley.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (1990b). Chapter I: The knowledge-based information economy. In G. Eliasson et al. (Eds.), The knowledge based information economy. Stockholm: IUI. Eliasson, G. (1990b). Chapter I: The knowledge-based information economy. In G. Eliasson et al. (Eds.), The knowledge based information economy. Stockholm: IUI.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (1991a). Deregulation, innovative entry and structural diversity as a source of stable and rapid economic growth. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 1, 49–63.CrossRef Eliasson, G. (1991a). Deregulation, innovative entry and structural diversity as a source of stable and rapid economic growth. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 1, 49–63.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (1992a). Business competence, organizational learning and economic growth – Establishing the Smith-Schumpeter-Wicksell connection. In F. M. Scherer & M. Perlman (Eds.), Entrepreneurship, technological innovation, and economic growth: Studies in the Schumpeterian tradition. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Eliasson, G. (1992a). Business competence, organizational learning and economic growth – Establishing the Smith-Schumpeter-Wicksell connection. In F. M. Scherer & M. Perlman (Eds.), Entrepreneurship, technological innovation, and economic growth: Studies in the Schumpeterian tradition. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (1992b) Arbetet – dess betydelse, dess innehåll, dess kvalitet och dess ersättning (Work – Its significance, content, quality and compensation). Stockholm: IUI. Eliasson, G. (1992b) Arbetet – dess betydelse, dess innehåll, dess kvalitet och dess ersättning (Work – Its significance, content, quality and compensation). Stockholm: IUI.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (1994c). Educational efficiency and the market for competence. European Journal of Vocational Training, 2(94), 5–11. Eliasson, G. (1994c). Educational efficiency and the market for competence. European Journal of Vocational Training, 2(94), 5–11.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (1995). En teknologigenerator eller ett nationellt prestigeprojekt? ─ svensk flygindustri (A technology generator or a national prestige project? ─ Swedish aircraft industry). Stockholm: City University Press. Eliasson, G. (1995). En teknologigenerator eller ett nationellt prestigeprojekt? svensk flygindustri (A technology generator or a national prestige project? Swedish aircraft industry). Stockholm: City University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (1996a). The firm, its objectives, its controls and its organization. Boston/Dordrecht/London: Kluwer Academic Publishers.CrossRef Eliasson, G. (1996a). The firm, its objectives, its controls and its organization. Boston/Dordrecht/London: Kluwer Academic Publishers.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (1996b). Spillovers, integrated production and the theory of the firm. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 6, 125–140.CrossRef Eliasson, G. (1996b). Spillovers, integrated production and the theory of the firm. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 6, 125–140.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (1996c). The use of highly educated people in production. TRITA – IEO R 1996-10, Stockholm: KTH. Eliasson, G. (1996c). The use of highly educated people in production. TRITA – IEO R 1996-10, Stockholm: KTH.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (2000e). Chapter III: A platform theory of cumulative learning – The dropout or fall off problem. In G. Eliasson (Ed.), Industrial change, life long learning and labor market performance. Stockholm: KTH TRITA-IEO-R 2000:14. Eliasson, G. (2000e). Chapter III: A platform theory of cumulative learning – The dropout or fall off problem. In G. Eliasson (Ed.), Industrial change, life long learning and labor market performance. Stockholm: KTH TRITA-IEO-R 2000:14.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (2003). The venture capitalist as a competent outsider. In K. Alho, J. Lassila, & P. Ylä-Anttila (Eds.), Economic research and decision making, ETLA-Taloustieto oy, Helsinki.; An earlier version was published under the same title by Stockholm: KTH, TRITA-IEO R 1997:06. Eliasson, G. (2003). The venture capitalist as a competent outsider. In K. Alho, J. Lassila, & P. Ylä-Anttila (Eds.), Economic research and decision making, ETLA-Taloustieto oy, Helsinki.; An earlier version was published under the same title by Stockholm: KTH, TRITA-IEO R 1997:06.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (Ed.). (2005a). The birth, the life and the death of firms – The role of entrepreneurship, creative destruction and conservative institutions in a growing and experimentally organized economy. Stockholm: The Ratio Institute. Eliasson, G. (Ed.). (2005a). The birth, the life and the death of firms – The role of entrepreneurship, creative destruction and conservative institutions in a growing and experimentally organized economy. Stockholm: The Ratio Institute.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (2005b). The nature of economic change and management in a new knowledge based information economy. Information Economics and Policy, 17, 428–456.CrossRef Eliasson, G. (2005b). The nature of economic change and management in a new knowledge based information economy. Information Economics and Policy, 17, 428–456.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (2010a). Advanced public procurement as industrial policy – Aircraft industry as a technical university. New York/Dordrecht/Heidelberg/London: Springer.CrossRef Eliasson, G. (2010a). Advanced public procurement as industrial policy – Aircraft industry as a technical university. New York/Dordrecht/Heidelberg/London: Springer.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (2010b). Synliga Kostnader, Osynliga Vinster – Offentlig upphandling som industripolitik (Visible costs, invisible benefits – Public procurment as industrial policy). Stockholm: SNS. Eliasson, G. (2010b). Synliga Kostnader, Osynliga Vinster – Offentlig upphandling som industripolitik (Visible costs, invisible benefits – Public procurment as industrial policy). Stockholm: SNS.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G. (2013a). The internet as a global production reorganizer: The old industry in the new economy. In A. Pyka (Ed.), Long term economic development, economic complexity and evolution. Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer. Eliasson, G. (2013a). The internet as a global production reorganizer: The old industry in the new economy. In A. Pyka (Ed.), Long term economic development, economic complexity and evolution. Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G., & Eliasson, U. (1997). Företagandets konst – om konstproduktionen i renässansens Florens (The art of enterprise – On the art production in renaissance Florence). Stockholm: City Universitetet. Eliasson, G., & Eliasson, U. (1997). Företagandets konst – om konstproduktionen i renässansens Florens (The art of enterprise – On the art production in renaissance Florence). Stockholm: City Universitetet.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G., & Eliasson, Å. (2005). The theory of the firm and the markets for strategic acquisitions. In U. Cantner, E. Dinopoulos, & R. F. Lanzilotti (Eds.), Entrepreneurship, the new economy and public policy. Berlin/Heidelberg/New York: Springer. Eliasson, G., & Eliasson, Å. (2005). The theory of the firm and the markets for strategic acquisitions. In U. Cantner, E. Dinopoulos, & R. F. Lanzilotti (Eds.), Entrepreneurship, the new economy and public policy. Berlin/Heidelberg/New York: Springer.
Zurück zum Zitat Eliasson, G., & Johansson, D. (1999). Den C&C användande Industrin. In G. Eliasson & D. Johansson (Eds.),. Dynamik och flexibilitet i svensk IT-industry (Dynamics and Flexibility in Swedish IT-industry) (pp. 199–217). Stockholm: City University Press. Eliasson, G., & Johansson, D. (1999). Den C&C användande Industrin. In G. Eliasson & D. Johansson (Eds.),. Dynamik och flexibilitet i svensk IT-industry (Dynamics and Flexibility in Swedish IT-industry) (pp. 199–217). Stockholm: City University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Griliches, Z. (1969). Capital – Skill complementarity. Review of Economics and Statistics, LI, 465–468.CrossRef Griliches, Z. (1969). Capital – Skill complementarity. Review of Economics and Statistics, LI, 465–468.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Griliches, Z. (1979). Issues in assessing the contribution of R&D to productivity growth. Bell Journal of Economics (Spring), 10(1), 92–116.CrossRef Griliches, Z. (1979). Issues in assessing the contribution of R&D to productivity growth. Bell Journal of Economics (Spring), 10(1), 92–116.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gunnarsson, G., Mellander, E., & Savvidou, E. (2004). Human capital is the key to the IT productivity paradox. IFAU Working paper 2004:13, Uppsala. Gunnarsson, G., Mellander, E., & Savvidou, E. (2004). Human capital is the key to the IT productivity paradox. IFAU Working paper 2004:13, Uppsala.
Zurück zum Zitat Heum, P., Yla-Antilla, P., Braunerhjelm, P., & Thomsen, S. (1992). Firm dynamics in a Nordic perspective – Large corporations and industrial transformation. Helsingfors: ETLA. Heum, P., Yla-Antilla, P., Braunerhjelm, P., & Thomsen, S. (1992). Firm dynamics in a Nordic perspective – Large corporations and industrial transformation. Helsingfors: ETLA.
Zurück zum Zitat Jones, C.,. I., & Williams, J. C. (1998). Measuring the Social Returns to R&D. The Quartery Journal of Economics, 113(4), 1119–1135.CrossRef Jones, C.,. I., & Williams, J. C. (1998). Measuring the Social Returns to R&D. The Quartery Journal of Economics, 113(4), 1119–1135.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jones, C. & Williams, J. C. (1999, August). Too much of a good thing? The economics of investment in R&D (NBER Working Paper Nr 7283). Cambridge, MA: NBER. Jones, C. & Williams, J. C. (1999, August). Too much of a good thing? The economics of investment in R&D (NBER Working Paper Nr 7283). Cambridge, MA: NBER.
Zurück zum Zitat Jorgenson, D. W., & Griliches, Z. (1967). The explanation of productivity change. Review of Economic Studies, XXXIV(3), 249–282.CrossRef Jorgenson, D. W., & Griliches, Z. (1967). The explanation of productivity change. Review of Economic Studies, XXXIV(3), 249–282.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Knight, F. H. (1944). Diminishing returns from investment. Journal of Political Economy, LII, 26–47.CrossRef Knight, F. H. (1944). Diminishing returns from investment. Journal of Political Economy, LII, 26–47.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of economics. London: Macmillan & Company. Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of economics. London: Macmillan & Company.
Zurück zum Zitat McKenzie, L. W. (1959). On the existence of general equilibrium for a competitive market. Econometrica, 27(1), 30–53.CrossRef McKenzie, L. W. (1959). On the existence of general equilibrium for a competitive market. Econometrica, 27(1), 30–53.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nadiri, I. (1978). A dynamic model of research and development expenditure. In B. Carlsson, G. Eliasson, & I. Nadiri (Eds.), The importance of technology and the permanence of structure in industrial growth. IUI Conference Reports, 1978:2, Stockholm. Nadiri, I. (1978). A dynamic model of research and development expenditure. In B. Carlsson, G. Eliasson, & I. Nadiri (Eds.), The importance of technology and the permanence of structure in industrial growth. IUI Conference Reports, 1978:2, Stockholm.
Zurück zum Zitat Nadiri, I. (1993). Innovations and technological spillovers. Working Paper No. 4423. Cambridge, MA; NBER. Nadiri, I. (1993). Innovations and technological spillovers. Working Paper No. 4423. Cambridge, MA; NBER.
Zurück zum Zitat Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1002–1037.CrossRef Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1002–1037.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Solow, R. L. (1987). We’d better watch out. New York Times Book Review, 12, 36. Solow, R. L. (1987). We’d better watch out. New York Times Book Review, 12, 36.
Metadaten
Titel
Public Procurement of Public Goods as Innovation Policy: The Cloud of New Technologies Around Military Product Development
verfasst von
Gunnar Eliasson
Copyright-Jahr
2017
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-66993-9_3

    Marktübersichten

    Die im Laufe eines Jahres in der „adhäsion“ veröffentlichten Marktübersichten helfen Anwendern verschiedenster Branchen, sich einen gezielten Überblick über Lieferantenangebote zu verschaffen.