Skip to main content

2021 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

Regulating Innovation

verfasst von : Markus Schreiber

Erschienen in: Law and Economics of Regulation

Verlag: Springer International Publishing

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Innovation is one of the main drivers of economic growth. It is therefore no surprise that governments are increasingly trying to promote innovation through legal instruments. For this reason, the contribution analyses the interplay of law and economics in the regulation of innovation. The author examines the economic rationale behind such regulation. He assesses in which cases governments have legitimate reasons to interfere in the market economy in order to promote innovation. Furthermore, the legal possibilities and limits of influencing innovation are examined. In addition, the discussion includes the problems and economic consequences of legislators’ attempts to promote innovation. Finally, the contribution attempts to identify “best practices” for the furtherance of innovation through regulatory means.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Many attempts have been made in a variety of academic fields to properly define the term “innovation”. See Swann (2009), p. 25: “a bewildering variety of definitions”. A proper discussion is beyond the scope of this contribution. See Schreiber (2019), pp. 12 et seq.
 
2
Furman et al. (2002), p. 900; Swann (2009), pp. 234 et seq.; Verspagen (2011), p. 487; OECD (2015), p. 17.
 
3
Porter (1990b), pp. 318, 321 et seq.
 
4
Which has established, inter alia, the State Secretariat for Education, Research and Innovation.
 
5
For early English-language research on the subject matter, see OTA (1979), p. 45; Stewart (1981); Ashford et al. (1985).
 
6
Also cf. the general importance of government action and legal frameworks for economic activity described by Drezner (2008), pp. 33 et seq.
 
7
Cf. Stewart (1981), p. 1263; Veljanovski (2010), p. 20.
 
8
OECD (2015), p. 27. Also cf. Swann (2009), pp. 257 et seq.; Edler and Georghiou (2007), pp. 956 et seq.; Lundvall and Borrás (2011), p. 613; Schreiber (2019), p. 111.
 
9
Encyclopædia Britannica, “Market Failure”, available at www.​britannica.​com/​topic/​market-failure.
 
10
A market is Pareto-efficient when the resources and goods could not be redistributed without deteriorating at least one market participant’s position, Swann (2009), p. 257.
 
11
A market is Kaldor-Hicks-efficient when no redistribution is possible in which the market participants that gain an advantage from the redistribution could (at least in theory) compensate those that suffer from it, and the redistribution would still be (net) advantageous. See Hicks (1939), p. 706.
 
12
Also cf. Schreiber (2019), pp. 111 et seq.
 
13
Cf. Swann (2009), p. 260; Veljanovski (2010), p. 21.
 
14
De Mesquita (2016), p. 100.
 
15
De Mesquita (2016), p. 100.
 
16
For example, when carbon emissions from a German energy utility may have effects on villages in Peru due to their climate change impact, see the ongoing case of Saúl Lliuya v. RWE, Superior Court (Oberlandesgericht) Hamm, case no. 5 U 15/17.
 
17
This is also called a “temporal spillover”, see Huber (2017). Also cf. the discussion of the rights of future generations at Gruber (2011) and Mathis (2011).
 
18
Ewers (1990), p. 150.
 
19
Cf. Fritsch (2018), p. 164, however, also cf. the differentiated analysis; Fritsch (2018), pp. 195 et seq.; Wieddekind (2002), pp. 155 et seq.; Veljanovski (2010), p. 21.
 
20
For example, this has been one of the stated goals of the European Union’s harmonization policy towards a liberalized, regulated electricity market, cf. Directive (EU) 2019/944 recital 9, OJ 2019 L 158/125.
 
21
These often include an easy-to-read colour scheme and a grade system, e.g. from G (worst efficiency) through A (best efficiency). See, for example, the European Union’s labelling system as implemented under Regulation (EU) 2017/1369, OJ 2017 L 198/1.
 
22
Cf. OECD (2015), pp. 26 et seq.
 
23
OECD (2015), p. 26, describes this as “inertia”.
 
24
Stack and Gartland (2003), A well-known, albeit controversial, example is the QWERTY computer keyboard layout, cf. David (1985) and the criticism at Liebowitz and Margolis (1990). While there is now considerable evidence that the QWERTY layout is actually a poor example of path dependencies, it may still serve as a simple way to illustrate the problem, as readers will immediately think of the many adjustments in keyboard production, software adaptation, user training etc. necessary to switch to a new standard.
 
25
This is the term used at OECD (2015), p. 26, to denote those market circumstances that do not constitute neo-classical “market failures”.
 
26
Cf. Feintuck (2010); Schreiber (2019), p. 122.
 
27
See the Swiss Federal Government’s masterplan to strengthen biomedical research and technology, BAG (2013), pp. 76 et seq. Also cf. the discussion of innovation BAG (2013), pp. 31 et seq.
 
28
Such as in Switzerland under Articles 15 et seq. Energy Act (Energiegesetz, SR 730.0).
 
29
For a discussion of different monetary and non-monetary incentives for electric vehicles, see Gong et al. (2020). However, one may argue that the lack of a charging infrastructure and the fact the existing infrastructure has been optimised for internal combustion engines constitute a path dependency and thus a “market imperfection” in the sense described above.
 
30
Gentechnikgesetz, SR 814.91.
 
31
Such as under Art. 27 of the Swiss Federal Constitution (Bundesverfassung, SR 101).
 
32
See the discussion in Sect. 3.4 below.
 
33
For the example of genome editing, Swiss constitutional law specifically demands that humans and the environment are to be protected from abuses of genome editing, Art. 120 Swiss Federal Constitution. Also cf. Schreiber (2019), pp. 120 et seq.
 
34
Cf. Luhmann (2005), pp. 151 et seq. and 155 et seq.
 
35
For the Swiss Federal Council, see Art. 182 para. 1 Swiss Federal Constitution.
 
36
For the Swiss electricity sector, see Art. 3 para. 2 Electricity Supply Act (Stromversorgungsgesetz, SR 734.7).
 
37
Cf. Dingwerth (2005), pp. 71 et seq.
 
38
Cf. Jones (1989), pp. 413 et seq.; Maggetti (2010), pp. 2 et seq.
 
39
In Switzerland, by the Swiss Agency for Therapeutic Products swissmedic.
 
40
In Switzerland, by the Federal Electricity Commission ElCom.
 
41
For an exhaustive treatment of the subject, see Luhmann (2005); Also cf. Hirschi (2018), pp. 229 et seq.
 
42
E.g., Art. 29 Swiss Federal Constitution, Art. 6 European Convention on Human Rights, SR 0.101.
 
43
This is a problem with norms introduced by certain industry associations that, for example, do not include the consumers’ perspective. Cf. Schreiber (2019), pp. 273 et seq.
 
44
Hoffmann-Riem and Schneider (1998), pp. 396 et seq.; For an overview of this research area, see the volumes of the series Schriften zur rechtswissenschaftlichen Innovationsforschung. Nomos, Baden-Baden.
 
45
This amended categorization has been published in Schreiber (2019), pp. 89 et seq.
 
46
For example, any provision that serves an enabling or stimulating function will conflict with any provisions that serve a limiting function, Schreiber (2002), p. 235; Schreiber (2019), p. 90.
 
47
By the Nuclear Energy Act, SR 732.1.
 
48
Schreiber (2019), p. 91.
 
49
See Hofstetter et al. (2014), p. 42.
 
50
Hoffmann-Riem and Schneider (1998), pp. 396 et seq.; Schreiber (2002), p. 235; Cf. Schreiber (2019), p. 91.
 
51
Cf. Schreiber (2002), p. 242; Hoffmann-Riem and Schneider (1998), p. 396; Also cf. Ashford and Hall (2011), p. 272.
 
52
Cf. Hoffmann-Riem and Schneider (1998), p. 396; Schreiber (2002), p. 242.
 
53
See Annex II of Regulation (EG) Nr. 1275/2008, OJ 2008 L 339/45, as amended by Regulation (EU) Nr. 801/2013, OJ 2013 L 225/1.
 
54
In Switzerland, the Cantonal model laws on energy (Mustervorschriften der Kantone im Energiebereich, MuKEn) include such provisions. See, for example, Art. 1.17 para. 2, Art. 1.29 MuKEn 2014 (available at www.​endk.​ch/​de/​energiepolitik-der-kantone/​muken). However, the model laws are not directly applicable laws, but only valid to the extent that a Canton incorporates them into its respective law.
 
55
Schreiber (2019), pp. 92 et seq.
 
56
See Schreiber (2019), pp. 93 et seq.
 
57
For a discussion of such new businesses, see Katz (2015) and Tremblay-Huet (2018).
 
58
In Switzerland, this is prohibited by constitutional law, Art. 119 para. 2 lit. a Swiss Federal Constitution.
 
59
The Protocol for the Prohibition of the Use in War of Asphyxiating, Poisonous or other Gases, and of Bacteriological Methods of Warfare (Geneva Protocol), SR 0.515.105, was signed on 17 June 1925.
 
60
Schreiber (2019), pp. 96 et seq.
 
61
Bundesgesetz betreffend die Erstellung von Telegraphen- und Telephonlinien, AS 11 251.
 
62
Wyssling (1946), pp. 120 and 276.
 
63
Schreiber (2019), p. 99.
 
64
Schreiber (2019), p. 99.
 
65
Hoffmann-Riem and Schneider (1998), p. 397.
 
66
For example, the German legislator has introduced a conflict resolution entity for conflicts resulting from the legislation on renewable energy, the Clearingstelle EEG/KWKG, www.​clearingstelle-eeg-kwkg.​de/​.
 
67
See Wüstenhagen et al. (2007).
 
68
Schreiber (2019), p. 99.
 
69
Schreiber (2019), pp. 126 et seq.
 
70
In Switzerland, this is implemented inter alia in the Federal Act on certification services in the area of the electronic signature and other digital certificate applications (Bundesgesetz über die elektronische Signatur, SR 943.03).
 
71
For a thorough discussion of the innovation-related effects of digital signature regulation (in German), see Schreiber (2002). In Switzerland, the use of digital signatures is governed by the different procedural laws, see AS 2016 4651, pp. 4661 et seq.
 
72
Schreiber (2019), pp. 127 et seq.
 
73
The word has also been discussed in English-language innovation research, see Kuusi and Meyer (2002).
 
74
This term itself has been in academic use since at least the early 1980s, and the underlying ideas may date back to at least the 1960s, see Herschler and Slany (1982).
 
75
A society in which the average annual per capita energy consumption is 2000 Watt or less. This Leitbild has first been formulated at the Swiss Federal Technical Institute (Eidgenössische Technische Hochschule) Zurich in the late 1990s, see www.​local-energy.​swiss/​ueber-uns/​geschichte.​html#/​.
 
76
Art. 2ter para. 2 Gemeindeordnung der Stadt Zürich, AS 101.100; Art. 2 para. 2, Art. 3 Energiereglement Stadt Luzern, sRSL 7.3.1.1.1.
 
77
For a discussion of US innovation clusters, see Baily and Montalbano (2018).
 
79
The seminal publication on this is Thaler and Sunstein (2008). For a discussion in this Springer series, see Mathis and Tor (2016).
 
80
See note 104 supra.
 
81
Cf. Stewart (1981), pp. 1322 et seq.; OECD (2015), pp. 122 et seq.; Schreiber (2019), p. 137.
 
82
See, for example, the Swiss Federal Act on the Promotion of Research and Innovation, SR 420.1.
 
83
Scott (2010).
 
84
Cf. Swann (2009), pp. 82 et seq.
 
85
Schreiber (2019), p. 138.
 
86
See Noel et al. (2019) and Xu et al. (2020).
 
87
Cf. Mandel (2005).
 
88
However, also see the highly relevant discussion of an alternative, morality-based justification for intellectual property at Merges (2019), pp. 84 et seq.
 
89
Cf. Swann (2009), pp. 104 and 107 et seq.
 
90
For an overview of the discussion, see Merges (2019) as well as the other contributions in the same volume.
 
91
See, despite the criticism they voice with regard to patent protection, Shavell and van Ypersele (2001), p. 527; Also cf. Horowitz and Lai (1996); for innovation to combat climate change, Kim (2011).
 
92
Hoffmann-Riem (2016), p. 434; Schreiber (2019), p. 140.
 
93
Oppenländer (1977), pp. 369 et seq.; Also cf. Swann (2009), pp. 109 et seq.; Schreiber (2019), p. 140.
 
94
Schreiber (2019), p. 140.
 
95
Sections 2.2.3 and 2.2.5 supra.
 
96
Cf. the critical analysis by Teece and Coleman (1998).
 
97
Wieddekind (2002), p. 162.
 
98
Ashford et al. (1985), pp. 443 et seq.; also cf. Stewart (1981), pp. 1307 et seq. In the United States, a less traditional example are the State Innovation Waivers under section 1332 of the Affordable Care Act.
 
99
Further examples can be found at Schreiber (2019), p. 142.
 
100
Niederspannungs-Installationsverordnung, SR 734.27.
 
101
“[…] erweisen sie sich für die technische Entwicklung als hinderlich […]”.
 
102
Bankenverordnung, SR 952.02.
 
103
Regarding the former version of the provision (that included a para. 3), see Schreiber (2019), p. 143, with further references.
 
104
Cf. Schreiber (2019), pp. 143 et seq. As an early historical example; Lundvall and Borrás (2011), p. 600, mention the investments by King Henry VIII in iron cannons.
 
105
Bundesgesetz über die öffentliche Beschaffung, AS 2020 641. The current version can be found under SR 172.056.1.
 
106
“Innovationsgehalt”.
 
107
Veljanovski (2010), p. 32; also cf. Stewart (1981), p. 1310; Schreiber (2019), p. 147.
 
108
CO2-Gesetz, SR 641.71. Under the CO2 Act, the term “Brennstoff” (thermal fuel) includes fossil fuels used for the generation of heat, the production of light, the production of electricity in thermal facilities or the operation of combined heat and power plants, but not motor fuels, Art. 2 para. 1, para. 2 CO2-Act. However, producers and importers of motor vehicles may be subject to the sanction payments under Art. 10 et seq., Art. 13 CO2 Act.
 
109
E.g. § 19ter Ordinance on Taxes and Fees for Motor Vehicles, Bicycles and Ships (Verordnung über Steuern und Gebühren für Motorfahrzeuge, Fahrräder und Schiffe) of the Canton of Solothurn, BGS 614.62, which exempts “electric vehicles and solar vehicles” from the tax.
 
110
Cf. Veljanovski (2010), p. 31; Stewart (1981), pp. 1373 et seq.; Schreiber (2019), p. 148.
 
111
Cf. with regards to the debate in the USA Jaffe et al. (1995), pp. 153 et seq.
 
112
After Porter (1990a), p. 88; for Switzerland in particular, see Porter (1990b), p. 323; also cf. Ashford and Hall (2011), pp. 276 et seq.; OECD (2011), pp. 54 and 60; Schreiber (2019), pp. 150 et seq.
 
113
Schreiber (2019), p. 154; also cf. Hettich (2015).
 
114
Cf. Stewart (1981), pp. 1267 et seq. A similar approach forcing the use of existing, but not yet widely used technology, is sometimes called “action forcing”, see Miller (1995), p. 65.
 
115
Stewart (1981), pp. 1267 et seq.
 
116
While the use of cables is commonplace in low-voltage applications, their use in high-voltage distribution lines is still innovative.
 
117
Art. 15c Electricity Act (Elektrizitätsgesetz, SR 734.0).
 
118
Cf. Schreiber (2019), pp. 158 et seq.; Stewart (1981), pp. 1264 et seq., 1269.
 
119
Also see Sect. 4.1.
 
120
This has been extensively described by German-speaking legal scholars as “regulierte Selbstregulierung”, see Hettich (2014), pp. 269 et seq.; Hoffmann-Riem (2006).
 
121
Cf. the “negotiated standard setting” described by Stewart (1981), pp. 1341 et seq.
 
122
As established in Switzerland, for example, by Art. 15 Nuclear Energy Liability Act (Kernenergiehaftpflichtgesetz, SR 732.44).
 
123
For example, Art. 3 para. 1 lit. a of the Swiss Stem Cell Research Act (Stammzellenforschungsgesetz, SR 810.31) prohibits the production of embryos for the purpose of stem cell research.
 
124
For example, no patent protection is granted for processes regarding the cloning of humans under Art. 2 para. 1 lit. a of the Swiss Patents Act (Patentgesetz, SR 232.14).
 
125
See note 149 supra.
 
126
Art. 12 Energy Act.
 
127
For a discussion of this new provision, see Gerber (2019).
 
128
Schreiber (2019), pp. 99 et seq. with further references.
 
129
In Switzerland, for example, this is stipulated in Art. 5 para. 1 Federal Constitution.
 
130
For the principle of clarity in the United States, see Re (2019). For the Swiss equivalent, see Schindler (2014), n. 33 et seq.
 
131
Schreiber (2019), p. 102.
 
132
Schreiber (2019), p. 102.
 
133
For Swiss law, see Schindler (2014), n. 36 et seq.
 
134
For Swiss law, cf. Tschannen et al. (2014), p. 142; Schreiber (2019), p. 103.
 
135
Schreiber (2019), pp. 107 et seq.
 
136
As provided for by Art. 27 Federal Constitution.
 
137
Art. 94 Federal Constitution.
 
138
BGE 136 I 1 E. 5.5.2; BGE 125 I 182 E. 5c.
 
139
See the regulatory rationales in Sect. 2 supra.
 
140
Art. 36 Federal Constitution.
 
141
For the concept of competitive neutrality, see Lanneau (2017).
 
142
In Switzerland, state-owned enterprises may not substantially affect the economic freedom of private enterprises, and they must be exposed to the same competitive conditions as private enterprises, BGE 138 I 378 E. 6.3.2; Hangartner (2002), p. 55.
 
143
Schreiber (2019), p. 75 with further references; also cf. Stewart (1981), p. 1275; Hettich (2014), pp. 213 et seq.
 
144
Cf. Rustad and Koenig (2003), even though the study contained therein pertains to case law.
 
145
This will be discussed further below in Sect. 4.2.
 
146
Stewart (1981), pp. 1354 et seq.
 
147
Bayerischer Landtag (2013), p. 23.
 
148
Cf. Hartman (2013).
 
149
The complexity of trying to assess innovation incentives is exemplified by Mungan (2013).
 
150
Coase (1960), p. 18: “[…] [T]he governmental administrative machine is not itself costless. It can, in fact, on occasion be extremely costly”.
 
151
This term is not yet widely used in the English language. For the German equivalent (Interventionskosten), see Eidenmüller (2015), pp. 106 et seq., who also notes the absence of a corresponding discussion in the (primarily American) literature; also cf. Schreiber (2019), pp. 80 et seq.
 
152
Eidenmüller (2015), pp. 109 et seq.
 
153
Sacksofsky (2012), pp. 1635 et seq.; Schreiber (2019), p. 81.
 
154
When measured in MWh of electricity produced per Euro/Swiss Franc invested in support schemes, see the numbers at Schreiber (2019), pp. 81 et seq.
 
155
Schreiber (2019), p. 82.
 
156
Cf. the call for a “predictable, legally secure system” for pharmaceutical innovations at Kraus (2014), p. 380; Regarding Kraus’ example of the TRIPS agreement, also cf. Drezner (2008), pp. 176 et seq.
 
157
See Sect. 4.1 above.
 
158
See Sect. 4.1 above.
 
159
This term seems to be used mostly in the German-speaking literature. For a use in English (albeit by native German speakers), see Bergmann et al. (1998), p. 168.
 
160
Schreiber (2019), p. 84. For example, the former Swiss Energy Ordinance grew from 22 pages in 1998 to 186 pages in 2015 (Hettich 2015, p. 575), and 206 pages in 2017 (Schreiber 2019, p. 84 n. 545).
 
161
Cf. the—controversial—example of the QWERTY computer keyboard layout, note 107 supra.
 
162
Markusson (2012), p. 389.
 
163
Kline (2001), p. 103.
 
164
See Stack and Gartland (2010), p. 117; van Calster (2008), p. 91.
 
165
Schreiber (2019), p. 85.
 
167
See, for example, Art. 1.30 para. 2 lit. b, Art. 1.51 para. 2, Art. 1.52 para. 1 of the Cantonal Model Laws in the Energy Sector (Mustervorschriften der Kantone im Energiebereich, MuKEn) 2014, available at www.​endk.​ch/​de/​energiepolitik-der-kantone/​muken. These Model Laws are not directly applicable law, but only valid to the extent that the respective Canton actually implements them into its own law.
 
168
Schreiber (2019), p. 40.
 
169
This distinction can be traced back to Schumpeter (1947), p. 152, who seems to distinguish between the invention and the innovation process. The exact terminology and number of steps in the process varies. For an overview, see Godin (2006). Also cf. Stewart (1981), p. 1282.
 
170
The most detailed treatment of the diffusion process is Rogers (2003).
 
171
Cf. the legal instruments described in Sect. 3.3 supra.
 
172
Schreiber (2019), pp. 441 et seq.
 
173
Cf. Kernighan (2017), p. 142, who describes the Internet as “[…] a free-for-all compared to the controlled environments of traditional phone companies […]” but who also mentions that in recent years, it “[…] is becoming less free-wheeling and more constrained”.
 
174
See, for example, Dunne (1994).
 
175
For example, my analysis in Schreiber (2019) has shown that the definition of a “final consumer” in the electricity market is currently the legal provision that most severely hinders the implementation of innovative energy storage technology.
 
176
Schreiber (2019), pp. 441 et seq.
 
177
See Sect. 3.4 supra.
 
178
See Sect. 3.3.3 supra.
 
179
For Switzerland, see Steiner (2014), p. 162; Schreiber (2019), p. 145; also cf. Edler and Georghiou (2007), pp. 959 et seq.
 
180
Schreiber (2019), p. 391.
 
181
In Switzerland, Art. 8 para. 1 Federal Constitution.
 
182
In Switzerland, Art. 27 and Art. 94 Federal Constitution.
 
183
For an overview of energy storage technologies, see EASAC (2017), pp. 11 et seq.
 
184
See § 111 para. 3 of the Austrian Electricity Act 2010 (Elektrizitätswirtschafts- und Organisationsgesetz 2010, Federal Law Gazette I No. 110/2010, as amended by Federal Law Gazette I No. 174/2013), which temporarily exempted these two technologies from the duty to pay electricity grid usage fees. For a discussion of energy storage regulation in the German-speaking countries, see Schreiber (2020).
 
185
Schreiber (2019), p. 448.
 
186
In Switzerland, an important example are the SIA norms of the Swiss Society of Engineers and Architects (Schweizerischer Ingenieur- und Architektenverein). The norms are available at www.​sia.​ch/​en/​services/​sia-norm.
 
187
The latter is problematic since this essentially passes legislative power to the industry association.
 
188
Regarding experimental law, see Müller and Uhlmann (2013), pp. 177 et seq.; for a more general treatment of temporary law, see Fagan (2013).
 
189
Cf. Müller and Uhlmann (2013), p. 181.
 
190
SINTEG-Verordnung, BGBl. 2017 I 1653, as amended by BGBl. 2019 I 706.
 
191
§§ 6–9 SINTEG-ordinance. See Schreiber (2019), p. 449.
 
192
For an empirical study on how regulation and deregulation affect innovation, see Polemis and Tselekounis (2019).
 
193
Also cf. Schreiber (2019), p. 463.
 
194
See note 195 supra.
 
195
Schreiber (2019), pp. 449 et seq.
 
196
However, many industry associations are still critical of such a move. See, for example, the statement by the UK’s Society of motor manufacturers and traders cited in a report by the BBC from 4 February 2020, “Petrol and diesel car sales ban brought forward to 2035”, available at www.​bbc.​com/​news/​science-environment-51366123.
 
197
Under Art. 12a Nuclear Energy Act (Kernenergiegesetz, SR 732.1), no new general licenses for the construction of nuclear power plants may be granted. Plants already in operation may continue to run as long as the safety requirements under the law are observed (which, under Swiss law, includes the operators’ duty to follow technological developments and, if necessary, upgrade their plants, see Art. 22 para. 2 lit. g and h Nuclear Energy Act).
 
198
Cf. Locatelli et al. (2013).
 
199
Schreiber (2019), p. 450.
 
200
Schreiber (2019), p. 450.
 
201
It must be noted, however, that the most innovative solar modules are available in a variety of colors, prints and shapes, which helps to blend them into the environment.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Ashford NA, Hall RP (2011) The importance of regulation-induced innovation for sustainable development. Sustainability 3:270–292CrossRef Ashford NA, Hall RP (2011) The importance of regulation-induced innovation for sustainable development. Sustainability 3:270–292CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ashford NA, Ayers C, Stone RF (1985) Using regulation to change the market for innovation. Harv Environ Law Rev 9:419–466 Ashford NA, Ayers C, Stone RF (1985) Using regulation to change the market for innovation. Harv Environ Law Rev 9:419–466
Zurück zum Zitat Baily MN, Montalbano N (2018) Clusters and innovation districts: lessons from the United States experience. The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C. Baily MN, Montalbano N (2018) Clusters and innovation districts: lessons from the United States experience. The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C.
Zurück zum Zitat Bayerischer Landtag (2013) Abschlussbericht der Kommission zur parlamentarischen Begleitung der Energiewende in Bayern. Drucksache 16/17500, Munich Bayerischer Landtag (2013) Abschlussbericht der Kommission zur parlamentarischen Begleitung der Energiewende in Bayern. Drucksache 16/17500, Munich
Zurück zum Zitat Bergmann H, Brockmann KL, Rennings K (1998) An economic approach to environmental agreements. Experiences from Germany. In co-operative environmental governance. In: Glasbergen P (ed) Public-private agreements as a policy strategy. Springer, Dordrecht, pp 157–178 Bergmann H, Brockmann KL, Rennings K (1998) An economic approach to environmental agreements. Experiences from Germany. In co-operative environmental governance. In: Glasbergen P (ed) Public-private agreements as a policy strategy. Springer, Dordrecht, pp 157–178
Zurück zum Zitat Bundesamt für Gesundheit (BAG) (2013) Massnahmen des Bundes zur Stärkung der biomedizinischen Forschung und Technologie. Bern Bundesamt für Gesundheit (BAG) (2013) Massnahmen des Bundes zur Stärkung der biomedizinischen Forschung und Technologie. Bern
Zurück zum Zitat David PA (1985) Clio and the economics of QWERTY. Am Econ Rev 75:332–337 David PA (1985) Clio and the economics of QWERTY. Am Econ Rev 75:332–337
Zurück zum Zitat De Mesquita EB (2016) Political economy for public policy. Princeton University Press, PrincetonCrossRef De Mesquita EB (2016) Political economy for public policy. Princeton University Press, PrincetonCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dingwerth K (2005) The democratic legitimacy of public-private rule making: what can we learn from the world commission on dams? Glob Gov 11:65–83CrossRef Dingwerth K (2005) The democratic legitimacy of public-private rule making: what can we learn from the world commission on dams? Glob Gov 11:65–83CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner DW (2008) All politics is global. Explaining international regulatory regimes. Princeton University Press, Princeton Drezner DW (2008) All politics is global. Explaining international regulatory regimes. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Zurück zum Zitat Dunne RL (1994) Deterring unauthorized access to computers: controlling behavior in cyberspace through a contract law paradigm. Jurimetrics 35:1–15 Dunne RL (1994) Deterring unauthorized access to computers: controlling behavior in cyberspace through a contract law paradigm. Jurimetrics 35:1–15
Zurück zum Zitat Edler J, Georghiou L (2007) Public procurement and innovation – resurrecting the demand side. Res Policy 36:949–963CrossRef Edler J, Georghiou L (2007) Public procurement and innovation – resurrecting the demand side. Res Policy 36:949–963CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Eidenmüller H (2015) Effizienz als Rechtsprinzip. Möglichkeiten und Grenzen der ökonomischen Analyse des Rechts, 4th edn. Mohr Siebeck, Tuebingen Eidenmüller H (2015) Effizienz als Rechtsprinzip. Möglichkeiten und Grenzen der ökonomischen Analyse des Rechts, 4th edn. Mohr Siebeck, Tuebingen
Zurück zum Zitat European Academies Science Advisory Council (EASAC) (2017) Valuing dedicated storage in electricity grids. EASAC policy report 33. Halle and Brussels European Academies Science Advisory Council (EASAC) (2017) Valuing dedicated storage in electricity grids. EASAC policy report 33. Halle and Brussels
Zurück zum Zitat Ewers H-J (1990) Marktversagen und Politikversagen als Legitimation staatlicher Forschungs- und Technologiepolitik. In: Krupp H (ed) Technikpolitik angesichts der Umweltkatastrophe. Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg, pp 147–160CrossRef Ewers H-J (1990) Marktversagen und Politikversagen als Legitimation staatlicher Forschungs- und Technologiepolitik. In: Krupp H (ed) Technikpolitik angesichts der Umweltkatastrophe. Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg, pp 147–160CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fagan F (2013) Law and the limits of government. Temporary versus permanent legislation. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham Fagan F (2013) Law and the limits of government. Temporary versus permanent legislation. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham
Zurück zum Zitat Feintuck M (2010) Regulatory rationales beyond the economic: in search of the public interest. In: Baldwin R, Cave M, Lodge M (eds) The Oxford handbook of regulation. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 39–63 Feintuck M (2010) Regulatory rationales beyond the economic: in search of the public interest. In: Baldwin R, Cave M, Lodge M (eds) The Oxford handbook of regulation. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 39–63
Zurück zum Zitat Fritsch M (2018) Marktversagen und Wirtschaftspolitik – Mikroökonomische Grundlagen staatlichen Handelns, 10th edn. Vahlen, MünchenCrossRef Fritsch M (2018) Marktversagen und Wirtschaftspolitik – Mikroökonomische Grundlagen staatlichen Handelns, 10th edn. Vahlen, MünchenCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Furman JL, Porter ME, Stern S (2002) The determinants of national innovative capacity. Res Policy 31:899–933CrossRef Furman JL, Porter ME, Stern S (2002) The determinants of national innovative capacity. Res Policy 31:899–933CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gerber A (2019) Art. 12 Energiegesetz: Was ändert sich bei der Interessenabwägung (erneuerbare Energie vs. Natur-, Landschafts- und Umweltschutz)? In: Heselhaus S, Hänni J, Schreiber M (eds) Rechtsfragen der Energiewirtschaft. Dike Zurich, St. Gallen, pp 77–106 Gerber A (2019) Art. 12 Energiegesetz: Was ändert sich bei der Interessenabwägung (erneuerbare Energie vs. Natur-, Landschafts- und Umweltschutz)? In: Heselhaus S, Hänni J, Schreiber M (eds) Rechtsfragen der Energiewirtschaft. Dike Zurich, St. Gallen, pp 77–106
Zurück zum Zitat Godin B (2006) The linear model of innovation. The historical construction of an analytical framework. Sci Technol Hum Values 31:639–667CrossRef Godin B (2006) The linear model of innovation. The historical construction of an analytical framework. Sci Technol Hum Values 31:639–667CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gong S, Ardeshiri A, Rashidi TH (2020) Impact of government incentives on the market penetration of electric vehicles in Australia. Transp Res Part D Transp Environ 83:102353CrossRef Gong S, Ardeshiri A, Rashidi TH (2020) Impact of government incentives on the market penetration of electric vehicles in Australia. Transp Res Part D Transp Environ 83:102353CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gruber M-C (2011) What is it like to be unborn? Our common fate with future generations. In: Klaus M (ed) Efficiency, sustainability, and justice to future generations. Springer, Dordrecht, pp 113–137 Gruber M-C (2011) What is it like to be unborn? Our common fate with future generations. In: Klaus M (ed) Efficiency, sustainability, and justice to future generations. Springer, Dordrecht, pp 113–137
Zurück zum Zitat Hangartner Y (2002) Das Grundrecht der Wirtschaftsfreiheit. Recht – Zeitschrift für juristische Weiterbildung und Praxis 2002:53–62 Hangartner Y (2002) Das Grundrecht der Wirtschaftsfreiheit. Recht – Zeitschrift für juristische Weiterbildung und Praxis 2002:53–62
Zurück zum Zitat Hartman BJ (2013) The renewable fuel standard: food versus fuel? Maine Law Rev 65:525–548 Hartman BJ (2013) The renewable fuel standard: food versus fuel? Maine Law Rev 65:525–548
Zurück zum Zitat Herschler DH, Slany WZ (1982) The “Paperless Office”: a case study of the state department’s foreign affairs information system. Am Arch 45:142–154 Herschler DH, Slany WZ (1982) The “Paperless Office”: a case study of the state department’s foreign affairs information system. Am Arch 45:142–154
Zurück zum Zitat Hettich P (2014) Kooperative Risikovorsorge. Regulierte Selbstregulierung im Recht der operationellen und technischen Risiken. Schulthess, Zurich Hettich P (2014) Kooperative Risikovorsorge. Regulierte Selbstregulierung im Recht der operationellen und technischen Risiken. Schulthess, Zurich
Zurück zum Zitat Hettich P (2015) Die Glühbirne – Lucifer neuer Zeiten. Schweizerisches Zentralblatt für Staats- und Verwaltungsrecht 116:567–588 Hettich P (2015) Die Glühbirne – Lucifer neuer Zeiten. Schweizerisches Zentralblatt für Staats- und Verwaltungsrecht 116:567–588
Zurück zum Zitat Hicks JR (1939) The foundations of welfare economics. Econ J 49:696–712CrossRef Hicks JR (1939) The foundations of welfare economics. Econ J 49:696–712CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hirschi C (2018) Regulation and transparency as rituals of distrust: reading Niklas Luhmann against the grain. In: Alloa E, Thomä D (eds) Transparency, society and subjectivity. Palgrave Macmillan and Springer, Cham Hirschi C (2018) Regulation and transparency as rituals of distrust: reading Niklas Luhmann against the grain. In: Alloa E, Thomä D (eds) Transparency, society and subjectivity. Palgrave Macmillan and Springer, Cham
Zurück zum Zitat Hoffmann-Riem W (2006) Gewährleistungsrecht und Gewährleistungsrechtsprechung am Beispiel regulierter Selbstregulierung. In: Bauer H, Schmidt R (eds) Wirtschaft im offenen Verfassungsstaat. Festschrift für Reiner Schmidt zum 70. Geburtstag. C.H. Beck, Munich, pp 447–466 Hoffmann-Riem W (2006) Gewährleistungsrecht und Gewährleistungsrechtsprechung am Beispiel regulierter Selbstregulierung. In: Bauer H, Schmidt R (eds) Wirtschaft im offenen Verfassungsstaat. Festschrift für Reiner Schmidt zum 70. Geburtstag. C.H. Beck, Munich, pp 447–466
Zurück zum Zitat Hoffmann-Riem W (2016) Innovation und Recht – Recht und Innovation. Recht im Ensemble seiner Kontexte. Mohr Siebeck, TuebingenCrossRef Hoffmann-Riem W (2016) Innovation und Recht – Recht und Innovation. Recht im Ensemble seiner Kontexte. Mohr Siebeck, TuebingenCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hoffmann-Riem W, Schneider J-P (1998) Zur Eigenständigkeit rechtswissenschaftlicher Innovationsforschung. In: Hoffmann-Riem W, Schneider J-S (eds) Rechtswissenschaftliche Innovationsforschung. Grundlagen, Forschungsansätze, Gegenstandsbereiche. Nomos, Baden-Baden, pp 389–412 Hoffmann-Riem W, Schneider J-P (1998) Zur Eigenständigkeit rechtswissenschaftlicher Innovationsforschung. In: Hoffmann-Riem W, Schneider J-S (eds) Rechtswissenschaftliche Innovationsforschung. Grundlagen, Forschungsansätze, Gegenstandsbereiche. Nomos, Baden-Baden, pp 389–412
Zurück zum Zitat Hofstetter D, Battke B, Cox B, Hughes J (2014) Power-to-gas in Switzerland – demand, regulation, economics, technical potential. Electrochaea, Zürich Hofstetter D, Battke B, Cox B, Hughes J (2014) Power-to-gas in Switzerland – demand, regulation, economics, technical potential. Electrochaea, Zürich
Zurück zum Zitat Horowitz AW, Lai EL-C (1996) Patent length and the rate of innovation. Int Econ Rev 37:785–801CrossRef Horowitz AW, Lai EL-C (1996) Patent length and the rate of innovation. Int Econ Rev 37:785–801CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Huber BR (2017) Temporal spillovers. In: Mathis K, Huber BR (eds) Environmental law and economics. Springer, Cham, pp 43–57CrossRef Huber BR (2017) Temporal spillovers. In: Mathis K, Huber BR (eds) Environmental law and economics. Springer, Cham, pp 43–57CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jaffe AB, Peterson SR, Portney PR (1995) Environmental regulation and the competitiveness of U.S. manufacturing: what does the evidence tell us? J Econ Lit 33:132–163 Jaffe AB, Peterson SR, Portney PR (1995) Environmental regulation and the competitiveness of U.S. manufacturing: what does the evidence tell us? J Econ Lit 33:132–163
Zurück zum Zitat Jones TH (1989) Administrative law, regulation, and legitimacy. J Law Soc 16:410–425CrossRef Jones TH (1989) Administrative law, regulation, and legitimacy. J Law Soc 16:410–425CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Katz V (2015) Regulating the sharing economy. Berkeley Technol Law J 30:1067–1126 Katz V (2015) Regulating the sharing economy. Berkeley Technol Law J 30:1067–1126
Zurück zum Zitat Kernighan BW (2017) Understanding the digital world. What you need to know about computers, the internet, privacy, and security. Princeton University Press, Princeton Kernighan BW (2017) Understanding the digital world. What you need to know about computers, the internet, privacy, and security. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Zurück zum Zitat Kim H-E (2011) The role of the patent system in stimulating innovation and technology transfer for climate change. Including aspects of licensing and competition law. Nomos, Baden-Baden Kim H-E (2011) The role of the patent system in stimulating innovation and technology transfer for climate change. Including aspects of licensing and competition law. Nomos, Baden-Baden
Zurück zum Zitat Kline D (2001) Positive feedback, lock-in, and environmental policy. Policy Sci 34:95–107CrossRef Kline D (2001) Positive feedback, lock-in, and environmental policy. Policy Sci 34:95–107CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kraus D (2014) Is TRIPS innovative enough? How to reconcile IP, innovation and health. In: Cremona M, Hilpold P, Lavranos N et al (eds) Reflections on the constitutionalization of international economic law, Liber amicorum for Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann. Martinus Nijhoff, Leiden Kraus D (2014) Is TRIPS innovative enough? How to reconcile IP, innovation and health. In: Cremona M, Hilpold P, Lavranos N et al (eds) Reflections on the constitutionalization of international economic law, Liber amicorum for Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann. Martinus Nijhoff, Leiden
Zurück zum Zitat Kuusi O, Meyer M (2002) Technological generalizations and leitbilder – the anticipation of technological opportunities. Technol Forecasting Soc Change 69:625–639CrossRef Kuusi O, Meyer M (2002) Technological generalizations and leitbilder – the anticipation of technological opportunities. Technol Forecasting Soc Change 69:625–639CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Liebowitz SJ, Margolis SE (1990) The fable of the keys. J Law Econ 33:1–25 Liebowitz SJ, Margolis SE (1990) The fable of the keys. J Law Econ 33:1–25
Zurück zum Zitat Locatelli G, Mancini M, Todeschini N (2013) Generation IV nuclear reactors: current status and future prospects. Energy Policy 61:1503–1520CrossRef Locatelli G, Mancini M, Todeschini N (2013) Generation IV nuclear reactors: current status and future prospects. Energy Policy 61:1503–1520CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Luhmann N (2005) Legitimation durch Verfahren, 6th edn. Suhrkamp, Frankfurt am Main Luhmann N (2005) Legitimation durch Verfahren, 6th edn. Suhrkamp, Frankfurt am Main
Zurück zum Zitat Lundvall B-Å, Borrás S (2011) Science, technology, and innovation policy. In: Fagerberg J, Mowery DC, Nelson RR (eds) The Oxford handbook of innovation. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 599–631 Lundvall B-Å, Borrás S (2011) Science, technology, and innovation policy. In: Fagerberg J, Mowery DC, Nelson RR (eds) The Oxford handbook of innovation. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 599–631
Zurück zum Zitat Maggetti M (2010) Legitimacy and accountability of independent regulatory agencies: a critical review. Living Rev Democr 2010:1–9 Maggetti M (2010) Legitimacy and accountability of independent regulatory agencies: a critical review. Living Rev Democr 2010:1–9
Zurück zum Zitat Mandel GN (2005) Promoting environmental innovation with intellectual property innovation: a new basis for patent rewards. Temple J Sci Technol Environ Law 24:51–70 Mandel GN (2005) Promoting environmental innovation with intellectual property innovation: a new basis for patent rewards. Temple J Sci Technol Environ Law 24:51–70
Zurück zum Zitat Markusson N (2012) Born again: the debate on lock-in and CCS. Energy Environ 23:389–394CrossRef Markusson N (2012) Born again: the debate on lock-in and CCS. Energy Environ 23:389–394CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mathis K (2011) Discounting the future? Cost-benefit analysis and sustainability. In: Mathis K (ed) Efficiency, sustainability, and justice to future generations. Springer, Dordrecht, pp 165–180 Mathis K (2011) Discounting the future? Cost-benefit analysis and sustainability. In: Mathis K (ed) Efficiency, sustainability, and justice to future generations. Springer, Dordrecht, pp 165–180
Zurück zum Zitat Mathis K, Tor A (eds) (2016) Nudging – possibilities, limitations and applications in European law and economics. Springer, Cham Mathis K, Tor A (eds) (2016) Nudging – possibilities, limitations and applications in European law and economics. Springer, Cham
Zurück zum Zitat Merges RP (2019) Philosophical foundations of IP law: the law and economics paradigm. In: Depoorter B, Menell PS (eds) Research handbook on the economics of intellectual property law, vol 1. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 72–97 Merges RP (2019) Philosophical foundations of IP law: the law and economics paradigm. In: Depoorter B, Menell PS (eds) Research handbook on the economics of intellectual property law, vol 1. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 72–97
Zurück zum Zitat Miller AS (1995) Environmental regulation, technological innovation, and technology-forcing. Nat Resour Environ 10:64–69 Miller AS (1995) Environmental regulation, technological innovation, and technology-forcing. Nat Resour Environ 10:64–69
Zurück zum Zitat Müller G, Uhlmann F (2013) Elemente einer Rechtssetzungslehre, 3rd edn. Schulthess, Zurich Müller G, Uhlmann F (2013) Elemente einer Rechtssetzungslehre, 3rd edn. Schulthess, Zurich
Zurück zum Zitat Mungan MC (2013) Reverse payments, perverse incentives. Harv J Law Technol 27:1–48 Mungan MC (2013) Reverse payments, perverse incentives. Harv J Law Technol 27:1–48
Zurück zum Zitat Noel L, de Rubens GZ, Sovacool BK, Kester J (2019) Fear and loathing of electric vehicles: the reactionary rhetoric of range anxiety. Energy Res Soc Sci 48:96–107CrossRef Noel L, de Rubens GZ, Sovacool BK, Kester J (2019) Fear and loathing of electric vehicles: the reactionary rhetoric of range anxiety. Energy Res Soc Sci 48:96–107CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Office of Technology Assessment (OTA) (1979) OTA priorities 1979. Washington, DC Office of Technology Assessment (OTA) (1979) OTA priorities 1979. Washington, DC
Zurück zum Zitat Oppenländer KH (1977) Die Wirkungen des Patentwesens im Innovationsprozess. Gewerblicher Rechtsschutz und Urheberrecht 79:362–370 Oppenländer KH (1977) Die Wirkungen des Patentwesens im Innovationsprozess. Gewerblicher Rechtsschutz und Urheberrecht 79:362–370
Zurück zum Zitat Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2011) Towards green growth. Paris Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2011) Towards green growth. Paris
Zurück zum Zitat Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2015) The innovation imperative. Contributing to productivity, growth and well-being. Paris Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2015) The innovation imperative. Contributing to productivity, growth and well-being. Paris
Zurück zum Zitat Porter ME (1990a) The competitive advantage of nations. Harv Bus Rev 90:73–91 Porter ME (1990a) The competitive advantage of nations. Harv Bus Rev 90:73–91
Zurück zum Zitat Porter ME (1990b) The competitive advantage of nations. Free Press, New YorkCrossRef Porter ME (1990b) The competitive advantage of nations. Free Press, New YorkCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Re RM (2019) Clarity doctrines. Univ Chic Law Rev 86:1497–1562 Re RM (2019) Clarity doctrines. Univ Chic Law Rev 86:1497–1562
Zurück zum Zitat Rogers EM (2003) Diffusion of innovations, 5th edn. Free Press, New York Rogers EM (2003) Diffusion of innovations, 5th edn. Free Press, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Rustad ML, Koenig TH (2003) Cybertorts and legal lag: an empirical analysis. South Calif Interdiscip Law J 13:77–140 Rustad ML, Koenig TH (2003) Cybertorts and legal lag: an empirical analysis. South Calif Interdiscip Law J 13:77–140
Zurück zum Zitat Sacksofsky U (2012) Anreize. In: Hoffmann-Riem W, Schmidt-Assmann E (eds) Grundlagen des Verwaltungsrechts. C.H. Beck, Munich Sacksofsky U (2012) Anreize. In: Hoffmann-Riem W, Schmidt-Assmann E (eds) Grundlagen des Verwaltungsrechts. C.H. Beck, Munich
Zurück zum Zitat Schindler B (2014) Art. 5. In: Ehrenzeller B, Schindler B, Schweizer RJ, Vallender KA (eds) Die Schweizerische Bundesverfassung, St. Galler Kommentar, 3rd edn. Schulthess, Zurich Schindler B (2014) Art. 5. In: Ehrenzeller B, Schindler B, Schweizer RJ, Vallender KA (eds) Die Schweizerische Bundesverfassung, St. Galler Kommentar, 3rd edn. Schulthess, Zurich
Zurück zum Zitat Schreiber L (2002) Innovationsgeeignetheit von Technikrecht am Beispiel der Signaturregulierung. In: Eifert M, Hoffmann-Riem W (eds) Innovation und rechtliche Regulierung. Schlüsselbegriffe und Anwendungsbeispiele rechtswissenschaftlicher Innovationsforschung. Nomos, Baden-Baden, pp 216–263 Schreiber L (2002) Innovationsgeeignetheit von Technikrecht am Beispiel der Signaturregulierung. In: Eifert M, Hoffmann-Riem W (eds) Innovation und rechtliche Regulierung. Schlüsselbegriffe und Anwendungsbeispiele rechtswissenschaftlicher Innovationsforschung. Nomos, Baden-Baden, pp 216–263
Zurück zum Zitat Schreiber M (2019) Rechtliche Innovationssteuerung am Beispiel der Power-to-Gas-Stromspeichertechnologie. Schulthess, Zurich Schreiber M (2019) Rechtliche Innovationssteuerung am Beispiel der Power-to-Gas-Stromspeichertechnologie. Schulthess, Zurich
Zurück zum Zitat Schreiber M (2020) Regulation of energy storage systems in the DACH countries. Eur Energy Environ Law Rev 29:168–176 Schreiber M (2020) Regulation of energy storage systems in the DACH countries. Eur Energy Environ Law Rev 29:168–176
Zurück zum Zitat Schumpeter JA (1947) The creative response in economic history. J Econ Hist 7:149–159CrossRef Schumpeter JA (1947) The creative response in economic history. J Econ Hist 7:149–159CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Scott C (2010) Standard-setting in regulatory regimes. In: Baldwin R, Cave M, Lodge M (eds) The Oxford handbook of regulation. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 104–119 Scott C (2010) Standard-setting in regulatory regimes. In: Baldwin R, Cave M, Lodge M (eds) The Oxford handbook of regulation. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 104–119
Zurück zum Zitat Shavell S, van Ypersele T (2001) Rewards versus intellectual property rights. J Law Econ 44:525–547CrossRef Shavell S, van Ypersele T (2001) Rewards versus intellectual property rights. J Law Econ 44:525–547CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stack M, Gartland MP (2003) Path creation, path dependency, and alternative theories of the firm. J Econ Issues 37:487–494CrossRef Stack M, Gartland MP (2003) Path creation, path dependency, and alternative theories of the firm. J Econ Issues 37:487–494CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stack M, Gartland MP (2010) Path dependence, modularity and the offshoring of (some) physician services. In: Sydow J, Schreyögg G (eds) The hidden dynamics of path dependence. Institutions and Organizations. Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp 113–128CrossRef Stack M, Gartland MP (2010) Path dependence, modularity and the offshoring of (some) physician services. In: Sydow J, Schreyögg G (eds) The hidden dynamics of path dependence. Institutions and Organizations. Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp 113–128CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Steiner M (2014) Nachhaltige öffentliche Beschaffung. Ein Blick auf das Vergaberecht des Bundes und die Perspektiven. In: Stöckli H, Zufferey J-B (eds) Aktuelles Vergaberecht 2014. Schulthess, Zurich, pp 149–176 Steiner M (2014) Nachhaltige öffentliche Beschaffung. Ein Blick auf das Vergaberecht des Bundes und die Perspektiven. In: Stöckli H, Zufferey J-B (eds) Aktuelles Vergaberecht 2014. Schulthess, Zurich, pp 149–176
Zurück zum Zitat Stewart RB (1981) Regulation, innovation, and administrative law: a conceptual framework. Calif Law Rev 69:1256–1377CrossRef Stewart RB (1981) Regulation, innovation, and administrative law: a conceptual framework. Calif Law Rev 69:1256–1377CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Swann PGM (2009) The economics of innovation. An introduction. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham Swann PGM (2009) The economics of innovation. An introduction. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham
Zurück zum Zitat Teece DJ, Coleman M (1998) The meaning of monopoly: antitrust analysis in high-technology industries. Antitrust Bull 43:801–857CrossRef Teece DJ, Coleman M (1998) The meaning of monopoly: antitrust analysis in high-technology industries. Antitrust Bull 43:801–857CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Thaler RH, Sunstein CR (2008) Nudge – improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. Yale University Press, New Haven Thaler RH, Sunstein CR (2008) Nudge – improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. Yale University Press, New Haven
Zurück zum Zitat Tremblay-Huet S (2018) Making sense of the public discourse on Airbnb and labour: what about labour rights? In: McKee D, Makela F, Scassa T (eds) Law and the “Sharing Economy”; regulating online market platforms. University of Ottawa Press, Ottawa, pp 393–420CrossRef Tremblay-Huet S (2018) Making sense of the public discourse on Airbnb and labour: what about labour rights? In: McKee D, Makela F, Scassa T (eds) Law and the “Sharing Economy”; regulating online market platforms. University of Ottawa Press, Ottawa, pp 393–420CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tschannen P, Zimmerli U, Müller M (2014) Allgemeines Verwaltungsrecht, 4th edn. Stämpfli, Bern Tschannen P, Zimmerli U, Müller M (2014) Allgemeines Verwaltungsrecht, 4th edn. Stämpfli, Bern
Zurück zum Zitat Van Calster G (2008) Against harmonization. regulatory competition in climate change law. Carbon Clim Law Rev 2:89–94 Van Calster G (2008) Against harmonization. regulatory competition in climate change law. Carbon Clim Law Rev 2:89–94
Zurück zum Zitat Veljanovski C (2010) Economic approaches to regulation. In: Baldwin R, Cave M, Lodge M (eds) The Oxford handbook of regulation. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 17–38 Veljanovski C (2010) Economic approaches to regulation. In: Baldwin R, Cave M, Lodge M (eds) The Oxford handbook of regulation. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 17–38
Zurück zum Zitat Verspagen B (2011) Innovation and economic growth. In: Fagerberg J, Mowery DC, Nelson RR (eds) The Oxford handbook of innovation. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 487–513 Verspagen B (2011) Innovation and economic growth. In: Fagerberg J, Mowery DC, Nelson RR (eds) The Oxford handbook of innovation. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 487–513
Zurück zum Zitat Wieddekind D (2002) Innovationsforschung, Wettbewerbstheorie und Kartellrecht. In: Eifert M, Hoffmann-Riem W (eds) Innovation und rechtliche Regulierung. Schlüsselbegriffe und Anwendungsbeispiele rechtswissenschaftlicher Innovationsforschung. Nomos, Baden-Baden, pp 134–170 Wieddekind D (2002) Innovationsforschung, Wettbewerbstheorie und Kartellrecht. In: Eifert M, Hoffmann-Riem W (eds) Innovation und rechtliche Regulierung. Schlüsselbegriffe und Anwendungsbeispiele rechtswissenschaftlicher Innovationsforschung. Nomos, Baden-Baden, pp 134–170
Zurück zum Zitat Wüstenhagen R, Wolsink M, Bürer MJ (2007) Social acceptance of renewable energy innovation. An introduction to the concept. Energy Policy 35:2683–2691CrossRef Wüstenhagen R, Wolsink M, Bürer MJ (2007) Social acceptance of renewable energy innovation. An introduction to the concept. Energy Policy 35:2683–2691CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wyssling W (1946) Die Entwicklung der schweizerischen Elektrizitätswerke und ihrer Bestandteile in den ersten 50 Jahren. Schweizerischer Elektrotechnischer Verein, Zurich Wyssling W (1946) Die Entwicklung der schweizerischen Elektrizitätswerke und ihrer Bestandteile in den ersten 50 Jahren. Schweizerischer Elektrotechnischer Verein, Zurich
Zurück zum Zitat Xu M, Yang H, Wang S (2020) Mitigate the range anxiety: siting battery charging stations for electric vehicle drivers. Transp Res Part C: Emerging Technol 114:164–188CrossRef Xu M, Yang H, Wang S (2020) Mitigate the range anxiety: siting battery charging stations for electric vehicle drivers. Transp Res Part C: Emerging Technol 114:164–188CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Regulating Innovation
verfasst von
Markus Schreiber
Copyright-Jahr
2021
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-70530-5_13