Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Review of Industrial Organization 3/2018

23.07.2018

Relative Performance Prizes and Dynamic Incentives in Best-of-N Contests

verfasst von: Xiandeng Jiang

Erschienen in: Review of Industrial Organization | Ausgabe 3/2018

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper introduces a relative performance prize scheme to best-of-N contests. I develop a theoretical model of the best-of-N contest with intermediate prizes that are distributed based on the players’ relative performance. The model predicts that a relative performance prize scheme both increases the players’ level of effort in certain conditions and decreases the performance differential between the winner and the loser in the contest. Empirically, I investigate these theoretical predictions by employing a natural experiment in the group-stage matches of the FIVB (Fédération Internationale de Volleyball) World League and the FIVB World Grand Prix. The results indicate that the introduction of a relative performance prize scheme induces contest participants to intensify their efforts in certain conditions. However, this prize scheme may ultimately result in teams playing fewer sets in matches.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
In 2016, the Cleveland Cavaliers became the first team to win the championship after facing a 3-to-1 deficit.
 
2
Lazear and Rosen (1981) analyze and compare the efficiency of a relative performance compensation scheme in rank-order tournaments and other types of tournaments. Chan et al. (2009) study a linear relative performance prize scheme in a two-period contest. They find that the players continue exerting efforts in the second period regardless of the score differential at the end of the first period.
 
3
For instance, Formula 1 car races and the Tour de France reward their participants based on their relative performance; many public firms evaluate their CEOs based on relative performance (Jenter and Kanaan 2015). Moreover, lesser prizes for runner-up outcomes are common in: golf; tennis; marathons; and the Olympics (gold-silver-bronze).
 
4
This paper is related to other studies of dynamic contests that are theoretical (e.g., Clark and Riis 1998; Krishna and Morgan 1998; Moldovanu and Sela 2001; Lai and Matros 2006; Fu and Lu 2012; Schweinzer and Segev 2012) and empirical (e.g., McFall et al. 2009; Apesteguia and Palacios-Huerta 2010; Kocher et al. 2012; Neugart and Richiardi 2013).
 
5
Klumpp and Polborn (2006) apply this analysis to the US presidential nomination campaigns.
 
6
Irfanoglu et al. (2010) and Mago and Sheremeta (2017) test these theoretical predictions.
 
7
The authors employ the Tullock contest success function to determine the participants’ winning probability in each round. In this type of success function, the discriminatory power basically measures the degree to which each player’s effort input affects his or her winning probability. A higher (lower) discriminatory power implies that a player’s effort plays a greater (smaller) role in his or her final chance of winning.
 
8
In this case, since Player i, the winner of Set 1, has already received an intermediate prize s, he will take the entire prize budget of v.
 
9
Each men’s team plays four matches against every opposing team in the group; each women’s team plays each opposing team in the group three times.
 
10
The team receives a monetary prize based on their final ranking. The allocation rules for the prize are not disclosed by the FIVB. However, the change in the number of monetary prizes over the sample period can be partially captured by the time trend variable.
 
11
According to the FIVB Official Volleyball Rules (http://​www.​fivb.​org/​EN/​Refereeing-Rules), in the first four sets, in the case of a 24–24 tie play is continued until a two-point lead is achieved; in the fifth set, in the case of a 14–14 tie play is continued until a two-point lead is achieved.
 
12
The winning team wins the entire budget regardless of the final set score.
 
13
In this case, each team is given an intermediate prize s and the winning team wins the final prize \(\frac{1}{3}\).
 
14
Under the winner-take-all scheme, \(v=1\) and \(s=0\); under the relative performance prize scheme, \(v=\frac{1}{3}\) and \(s=\frac{1}{3}\).
 
15
The final prize under the old rule is 1; the final prize under the new rule is \(\frac{1}{3}\).
 
16
This sample includes 394 men’s matches and 286 women’s matches before the rule change, and 432 men’s matches and 252 women’s matches after the rule change.
 
17
I only keep the matches played since the third round of each season in order to capture a relative accurate ability for each team. I explain the reason in following paragraphs.
 
18
The number of sets played variable equals to three if the final set score is 3–0; it is four if the final set score is 3–1; and it is five if the final set score is 3–2.
 
19
This dummy variable takes 1 if the higher ability team plays on its home field and 0 otherwise.
 
20
The dummy variable takes 1 if the higher ability team is ahead before the set and 0 otherwise.
 
21
The dummy variable takes 1 if the set score is 2–0 after Set 2 and 0 otherwise.
 
22
I use the numerical value of each season year as the trend variable. For example, the trend variable for all the knockout-stage matches equals to 2008 in the year of 2008.
 
23
Please refer to Hahn et al. (2001), Guido and Lemieux (2008), and Lee and Lemieuxa (2010) for details of regression discontinuity design.
 
24
Gelman and Imbens (2014) suggest that using high-order polynomials of f(season) could lead to misleading results. Thus, I will also estimate the model using a linear function of f(season) in this paper.
 
25
The cutoff season is 2009 in the men’s league and 2010 in the women’s league.
 
26
I test the same hypothesis using the RDD setup with a season quartic polynomial and the results are still robust.
 
27
These estimates remain similar when the quartic polynomial of season is included.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Apesteguia, J., & Palacios-Huerta, I. (2010). Psychological pressure in competitive environments: Evidence from a randomized natural experiment. American Economic Review, 100, 2548–2564.CrossRef Apesteguia, J., & Palacios-Huerta, I. (2010). Psychological pressure in competitive environments: Evidence from a randomized natural experiment. American Economic Review, 100, 2548–2564.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Baker, G., Gibbs, M., & Holmstrom, B. (1994a). The internal economics of the firm: Evidence from personnel data. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 881–919.CrossRef Baker, G., Gibbs, M., & Holmstrom, B. (1994a). The internal economics of the firm: Evidence from personnel data. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 881–919.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Baker, G., Gibbs, M., & Holmstrom, B. (1994b). The wage policy of a firm. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 921–955.CrossRef Baker, G., Gibbs, M., & Holmstrom, B. (1994b). The wage policy of a firm. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 921–955.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chan, W., Courty, P., & Hao, L. (2009). Suspense: Dynamic incentives in sports contests. The Economic Journal, 119, 24–46.CrossRef Chan, W., Courty, P., & Hao, L. (2009). Suspense: Dynamic incentives in sports contests. The Economic Journal, 119, 24–46.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Clark, D. J., & Riis, C. (1998). Influence and the discretionary allocation of several prizes. European Journal of Political Economy, 14, 605–625.CrossRef Clark, D. J., & Riis, C. (1998). Influence and the discretionary allocation of several prizes.​ European Journal of Political Economy, 14, 605–625.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dorsey-Palmateer, R., & Smith, G. (2004). Bowlers’ hot hands. The American Statistician, 58, 38–45. CrossRef Dorsey-Palmateer, R., & Smith, G. (2004). Bowlers’ hot hands. The American Statistician, 58, 38–45. CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Feng, X., & Lu, J. (2018). How to split the pie: Optimal rewards in dynamic multi-battle competitions. Journal of Public Econoimcs, 160, 82–95.CrossRef Feng, X., & Lu, J. (2018). How to split the pie: Optimal rewards in dynamic multi-battle competitions. Journal of Public Econoimcs, 160, 82–95.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fu, Q., & Lu, J. (2012). The optimal multi-stage contest. Economic Theory, 51, 351–382.CrossRef Fu, Q., & Lu, J. (2012). The optimal multi-stage contest. Economic Theory, 51, 351–382.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fudenberg, D., Gilbert, R., Stiglitz, J., & Tirole, J. (1983). Preemption, leapfrogging and competition in patent races. European Economic Review, 22, 3–31.CrossRef Fudenberg, D., Gilbert, R., Stiglitz, J., & Tirole, J. (1983). Preemption, leapfrogging and competition in patent races. European Economic Review, 22, 3–31.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gelman, A., & Imbens, G. (2014). Why high-order polynomials should not be used in regression discontinuity designs. NBER Working Papers 20405 Gelman, A., & Imbens, G. (2014). Why high-order polynomials should not be used in regression discontinuity designs. NBER Working Papers 20405
Zurück zum Zitat Guido, W. I., & Lemieux, T. (2008). Regression discontinuity designs: A guide to practice. Journal of Econometrics, 142, 615–635.CrossRef Guido, W. I., & Lemieux, T. (2008). Regression discontinuity designs: A guide to practice. Journal of Econometrics, 142, 615–635.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hahn, J., Todd, P., & Van der Klaauw, W. (2001). Identification and estimation of treatment effects with a regression-discontinuity design. Econometrica, 69, 201–209.CrossRef Hahn, J., Todd, P., & Van der Klaauw, W. (2001). Identification and estimation of treatment effects with a regression-discontinuity design. Econometrica, 69, 201–209.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harris, C., & Vickers, J. (1987). Racing with uncertainty. Review of Economic Studies, 54, 1–21.CrossRef Harris, C., & Vickers, J. (1987). Racing with uncertainty. Review of Economic Studies, 54, 1–21.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Irfanoglu, Z., Mago, S., & Sheremeta, R. (2010). Sequential versus simultaneous election contests: An experimental study. Working paper. Irfanoglu, Z., Mago, S., & Sheremeta, R. (2010). Sequential versus simultaneous election contests: An experimental study. Working paper.
Zurück zum Zitat Jenter, D., & Kanaan, F. (2015). CEO turnover and relative performance evaluation. Journal of Finance, 70, 2155–2184.CrossRef Jenter, D., & Kanaan, F. (2015). CEO turnover and relative performance evaluation. Journal of Finance, 70, 2155–2184.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kerick, S., Iso-Ahola, S., & Hatfield, B. (2000). Psychological momentum in target shooting: Cortical, cognitive-affective, and behavioral responses. Journal of Sport & Exercise Psychology, 22, 1–20.CrossRef Kerick, S., Iso-Ahola, S., & Hatfield, B. (2000). Psychological momentum in target shooting: Cortical, cognitive-affective, and behavioral responses. Journal of Sport & Exercise Psychology, 22, 1–20.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Klumpp, T., & Polborn, M. (2006). Primaries and the New Hampshire effect. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 1073–1114.CrossRef Klumpp, T., & Polborn, M. (2006). Primaries and the New Hampshire effect. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 1073–1114.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kocher, M., Lenz, V., & Sutter, M. (2012). Psychological pressure in competitive environments: New evidence from a randomized natural experiment. Management Science, 58, 1585–1591.CrossRef Kocher, M., Lenz, V., & Sutter, M. (2012). Psychological pressure in competitive environments: New evidence from a randomized natural experiment. Management Science, 58, 1585–1591.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Konrad, K. A., & Kovenock, D. (2009). Multi-battle contests. Game and Economic Behavior, 66, 256–274.CrossRef Konrad, K. A., & Kovenock, D. (2009). Multi-battle contests. Game and Economic Behavior, 66, 256–274.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Krishna, V., & Morgan, J. (1998). The winner-take-all principle in small tournaments. Advances in applied microeconomics, 7, 61–74. Krishna, V., & Morgan, J. (1998). The winner-take-all principle in small tournaments. Advances in applied microeconomics, 7, 61–74.
Zurück zum Zitat Lai, E., & Matros, A. (2006). Contest architecture with performance revelation. Working paper. Lai, E., & Matros, A. (2006). Contest architecture with performance revelation. Working paper.
Zurück zum Zitat Lazear, E., & Rosen, S. (1981). Rank-order tournaments as optimum labor contracts. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 841–64.CrossRef Lazear, E., & Rosen, S. (1981). Rank-order tournaments as optimum labor contracts. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 841–64.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lee, D. S., & Lemieuxa, T. (2010). Regression discontinuity designs in economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 48, 281–355.CrossRef Lee, D. S., & Lemieuxa, T. (2010). Regression discontinuity designs in economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 48, 281–355.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mago, S., & Sheremeta, R. (2017). Multi-battle contests: An experimental study. Southern Economic Journal, 84, 407–425.CrossRef Mago, S., & Sheremeta, R. (2017). Multi-battle contests: An experimental study. Southern Economic Journal, 84, 407–425.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mago, S., Sheremeta, R., & Yates, A. (2013). Best-of-three contest experiments: Strategic versus psychological momentum. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 31, 287–296.CrossRef Mago, S., Sheremeta, R., & Yates, A. (2013). Best-of-three contest experiments: Strategic versus psychological momentum. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 31, 287–296.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Malueg, D., & Yates, A. (2010). Testing contest theory: Evidence from best-of-three tennis matches. Review of Economics and Statistics, 92, 689–692.CrossRef Malueg, D., & Yates, A. (2010). Testing contest theory: Evidence from best-of-three tennis matches. Review of Economics and Statistics, 92, 689–692.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McFall, T., Knoeber, C., & Thurman, W. (2009). Contests, grand prizes, and the hot hand. Journal of Sports Economics, 10, 236–255.CrossRef McFall, T., Knoeber, C., & Thurman, W. (2009). Contests, grand prizes, and the hot hand. Journal of Sports Economics, 10, 236–255.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Moldovanu, B., & Sela, A. (2001). The optimal allocation of prizes in contests. American Economic Review, 91, 542–558.CrossRef Moldovanu, B., & Sela, A. (2001). The optimal allocation of prizes in contests. American Economic Review, 91, 542–558.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Neugart, M., & Richiardi, M. (2013). Sequential teamwork in competitive environments: Theory and evidence from swimming data. European Economic Review, 63, 185–205.CrossRef Neugart, M., & Richiardi, M. (2013). Sequential teamwork in competitive environments: Theory and evidence from swimming data. European Economic Review, 63, 185–205.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schweinzer, P., & Segev, E. (2012). The optimal prize structure of symmetric Tullock contests. Public Choice, 153, 69–82.CrossRef Schweinzer, P., & Segev, E. (2012). The optimal prize structure of symmetric Tullock contests. Public Choice, 153, 69–82.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sela, A. (2011). Best-of-three all-pay auctions. Economics Letters, 112, 67–70.CrossRef Sela, A. (2011). Best-of-three all-pay auctions. Economics Letters, 112, 67–70.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Szymanski, S. (2003). The economic design of sporting contests. Journal of Economic Literature, 41, 1137–1187.CrossRef Szymanski, S. (2003). The economic design of sporting contests. Journal of Economic Literature, 41, 1137–1187.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent seeking. In James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, & Gordon Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 97–112). College Station, TX: Taxes A&M University Press. Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent seeking. In James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, & Gordon Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 97–112). College Station, TX: Taxes A&M University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Vallerand, R., Colavecchio, P., & Pelletier, L. (1988). Psychological momentum and performance inferences: A preliminary test of the antecedents-consequences psychological momentum model. Journal of Sport & Exercise Psychology, 10, 92–108.CrossRef Vallerand, R., Colavecchio, P., & Pelletier, L. (1988). Psychological momentum and performance inferences: A preliminary test of the antecedents-consequences psychological momentum model. Journal of Sport & Exercise Psychology, 10, 92–108.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Relative Performance Prizes and Dynamic Incentives in Best-of-N Contests
verfasst von
Xiandeng Jiang
Publikationsdatum
23.07.2018
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Review of Industrial Organization / Ausgabe 3/2018
Print ISSN: 0889-938X
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7160
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-018-9646-8

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3/2018

Review of Industrial Organization 3/2018 Zur Ausgabe