Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination 3/2018

08.03.2017 | Regular Article

Revisiting the issue of survivability and market efficiency with the Santa Fe Artificial Stock Market

verfasst von: Chueh-Yung Tsao, Ya-Chi Huang

Erschienen in: Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination | Ausgabe 3/2018

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The relevance of risk preference and forecasting accuracy for investor survival has recently been the focus of a series of theoretical and simulation studies. At one extreme, it has been proven that risk preference can be entirely irrelevant (Sandroni in Econometrica 68:1303–1341, 2000; Blume and Easley in Econometrica 74(4):929–966, 2006). However, the agent-based computational approach indicates that risk preference matters and can be more relevant for survivability than forecasting accuracy (Chen and Huang in Advances in natural computation, Springer, Berlin, 2005; J Econ Behav Organ 67(3):702–717, 2008; Huang in J Econ Interact Coord, 2015). Chen and Huang (Inf Sci 177(5):1222–1229, 2007, 2008) further explained that it is the saving behavior of traders that determines their survivability. However, institutional investors do not have to consider saving decisions that are the most influential investors in modern financial markets. Additionally, traders in the above series of theoretical and simulation studies have learned to forecast the stochastic process that determines which asset will pay dividends, not the market prices and dividends. To relate the research on survivability to issues with respect to the efficient markets hypothesis, it is better to endow agents with the ability to forecast market prices and dividends. With the Santa Fe Artificial Stock Market, where traders do not have to consider saving decisions and can learn to forecast both asset prices and dividends, we revisit the issue of survivability and market efficiency. We find that the main finding of Chen and Huang (2008) that risk preference is much more relevant for survivability than forecasting accuracy still holds for a wide range of market conditions but can fail when the baseline dividend becomes very small. Moreover, the advantage of traders who are less averse to risk is revealed in the market where saving decisions are not taken into account. Finally, Huang’s (2015) argument regarding the degree of market inefficiency is confirmed.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Chen and Huang (2005) find that traders with RRA coefficients close to 0 suffer from extremely unstable saving behavior, which causes their wealth to evaporate. Chen and Huang (2007) indicate that agents with higher RRAs will end up with greater wealth shares, which results from their higher saving rates. Chen and Huang (2008) find that, among their seven types of agents, the log-utility agents with a constant RRA of one exhibited the most stable saving behavior, and hence, they ultimately dominated the market.
 
2
The description of the SFASM can also be found in Arthur et al. (1997), Ehrentreich (2003, 2006), Huang and Tsao (2017), Joshi et al. (2000), LeBaron et al. (1999), and LeBaron (2002, 2006).
 
3
The formation of agent i’s expectations at time \(t,E_{i,t} ({p_{t+1} +d_{t+1}})\) and \(\hat{{\sigma }}_{i,t,p+d}^2 \), will be specified in Sect. 2.2, and the former will be a function of \(p_t \) when agent i’s desired holding \(X_{i,t} \) is passed to the specialist. \(X_{i,t} \) of Eq. (3) is therefore also a function of \(p_t \).
 
4
Excess demand or supply within 0.1 is allowed by the price-clearing mechanism.
 
5
Agent i’s wealth is updated as \(W_{i,t} =X_{i,t-1} \left( {p_t +d_t} \right) +\left( {W_{i,t-1} -p_{t-1} \cdot X_{i,t-1}} \right) \left( {1+r} \right) \).
 
6
The weighted average of the squared forecast error of agent i’s predictor j activated at time \(t-1\), \(v_{t,i,j}^2 \), is calculated as \(v_{t,i,j}^2 =(1-\frac{1}{\theta })v_{t-1,i,j}^2 +\frac{1}{\theta }\left[ {\left( {p_t +d_t} \right) -E_{i,t-1} \left( {p_t +d_t} \right) } \right] ^{2}\).
 
7
Bits 11 and 12 are two useless bits in the form of an always on bit and an always off bit. These are intended to be zero information bits. They were compared with the others by the researchers who built the SFASM to assess if the number of rules using the real information was larger than that using the useless information.
 
8
Therefore, a rule’s fitness is negatively related to its weighted average of squared forecast error and the number of non-ignored bits. This penalizing rule specificity is to ensure that each bit is actually serving a useful purpose in terms of a forecasting rule. Moreover, to calculate the fitness of initial rules, a dividend history of 500 periods before formal trading is generated following Eq. (1), and an associated history of fundamental prices is generated.
 
9
It is operated by drawing a value s from the uniform distribution U(0,1). If \(\hbox {s}<0.9\), a new predictor is generated by mutation and by crossover otherwise.
 
10
With probability 0.03, each bit in the string undergoes the following changes. \(0 \rightarrow \) # with probability 2/3. \(1 \rightarrow \) # with probability 2/3. # \(\rightarrow 0\) with probability 1/3. Other changes are as expected, i.e., \(0\rightarrow 1\) with probability 1/3. On average, this preserves the “specificity”, or fraction, of #’s of a rule (LeBaron et al. 1999).
 
11
More details can be found in Appendix A of Arthur et al. (1997).
 
12
LeBaron et al. (1999) solve for a homogeneous linear REE by conjecturing a linear function mapping the current state into a price
$$\begin{aligned} p_t =fd_t+e. \end{aligned}$$
The authors find that \(f=\frac{\rho }{1+r-\rho }, e=\frac{\bar{{d}}\left( {f+1} \right) \left( {1-\rho } \right) -\lambda \sigma _{p+d}^2}{r} \). According to the parameter values in Table 2, \(f=6.3333\) and \(e=16.688\).
 
13
The explanations can be found in Huang and Tsao (2017).
 
14
The average correlation coefficient over all the runs between the lifetime-averaged forecasting error and the final wealth is −0.013, for which the absolute value is also much smaller than that of the average correlation coefficient between the ARA coefficient and the final wealth.
 
15
We also compute the average holding shares for 10 types of agents with different ARA. For each single run, we take an average of holding shares in all periods for each agent. Then, the lifetime average holding share for each agent is further averaged over three agents of each type to obtain 10 amounts of average holding shares for 10 types of agents with different ARA. The average holding shares over all runs, each of which is obtained by further averaging over the entire 50 simulation runs, of agents with ARA coefficients 0.01, 0.3, 0.7, 1.0, 1.3, 1.7, 2.0, 2.3, 2.7 and 3.0 are 8.93229, 0.44321, 0.21670, 0.14870, 0.10626, 0.04116, 0.03459, 0.02949, 0.02485, and 0.02275, respectively. This result clearly indicates that agents with lower ARA hold more shares on average.
 
16
Additionally, refer to Eq. (3) and Footnote 5.
 
17
From Eq. (3) and Footnote 5, more risk-averse agents seem to be able to gain advantages if the risk-free interest rate is large enough. However, it is not very likely to observe interest rates higher than 10%. Therefore, we stress that in a “normal” interest rate range, the previous result that risk preference is much more relevant for survivability than forecasting accuracy holds.
 
18
We find that the average standard deviation of asset prices over all runs from the original experiment is 5.98, which is higher than that from the control experiment, 4.20. Violent price fluctuations in the original experiment may also hurt the efficiency of the market.
 
20
On one hand, many studies, such as De Long et al. (1990), have proposed that the expected returns of those who are courageous in investing are higher. On the other hand, many papers, such as Chen and Huang (2007) and Brandouy et al. (2012), have suggested that traders with higher RRA coefficients will end up with more wealth.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Anufriev M, Dindo P (2010) Wealth-driven selection in a financial market with heterogeneous agents. J Econ Behav Organ 73(3):327–358CrossRef Anufriev M, Dindo P (2010) Wealth-driven selection in a financial market with heterogeneous agents. J Econ Behav Organ 73(3):327–358CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Arthur WB, Holland J, LeBaron B, Palmer R, Tayler P (1997) Asset pricing under endogenous expectations in an artificial stock market. In: Arthur WB, Durlauf S, Lane D (eds) The economy as an evolving complex system II. Addison-Wesley, Reading, pp 15–44 Arthur WB, Holland J, LeBaron B, Palmer R, Tayler P (1997) Asset pricing under endogenous expectations in an artificial stock market. In: Arthur WB, Durlauf S, Lane D (eds) The economy as an evolving complex system II. Addison-Wesley, Reading, pp 15–44
Zurück zum Zitat Babcock BA, Choi KE, Freinerman E (1993) Risk and probability premiums for CARA utility functions. J Agr Resour Econ 18:17–24 Babcock BA, Choi KE, Freinerman E (1993) Risk and probability premiums for CARA utility functions. J Agr Resour Econ 18:17–24
Zurück zum Zitat Badegruber T (2003) Agent-based computational economics: new aspects in learning speed and convergence in the Santa Fe Artificial Stock Market. Ph.D. thesis, Universitat Graz, Graz Badegruber T (2003) Agent-based computational economics: new aspects in learning speed and convergence in the Santa Fe Artificial Stock Market. Ph.D. thesis, Universitat Graz, Graz
Zurück zum Zitat Barucci E, Casna M (2014) On the market selection hypothesis in a mean reverting environment. Comput Econ 44(1):101–126CrossRef Barucci E, Casna M (2014) On the market selection hypothesis in a mean reverting environment. Comput Econ 44(1):101–126CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blume L, Easley D (1992) Evolution and market behavior. J Econ Theory 58:9–40CrossRef Blume L, Easley D (1992) Evolution and market behavior. J Econ Theory 58:9–40CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blume L, Easley D (2006) If you’re so smart, why aren’t you rich? Belief selection in complete and incomplete markets. Econometrica 74(4):929–966CrossRef Blume L, Easley D (2006) If you’re so smart, why aren’t you rich? Belief selection in complete and incomplete markets. Econometrica 74(4):929–966CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blume L, Easley D (2010) Heterogeneity, selection, and wealth dynamics. Annu Rev Econ 2:425–450CrossRef Blume L, Easley D (2010) Heterogeneity, selection, and wealth dynamics. Annu Rev Econ 2:425–450CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bossaerts P, Zame W (2008) Risk aversion in laboratory asset market. In: Cox JC, Harrison GW (eds) Risk aversion in experiments. Elsevier, Amsterdam Bossaerts P, Zame W (2008) Risk aversion in laboratory asset market. In: Cox JC, Harrison GW (eds) Risk aversion in experiments. Elsevier, Amsterdam
Zurück zum Zitat Bottazzi G, Dindo P (2013) Selection in asset markets: the good, the bad, and the unknown. J Evol Econ 23(3):641–661CrossRef Bottazzi G, Dindo P (2013) Selection in asset markets: the good, the bad, and the unknown. J Evol Econ 23(3):641–661CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brandouy O, Mathieu P, Veryzhenko I (2012) Risk aversion impact on investment strategy performance: a multi agent-based analysis. In: Teglio A, Alfarano S, Camacho-Cuena E, Ginés-Vilar M (eds) Managing market complexity. Lecture notes in economics and mathematical systems, vol 662. Springer, Berlin, pp 91–102 Brandouy O, Mathieu P, Veryzhenko I (2012) Risk aversion impact on investment strategy performance: a multi agent-based analysis. In: Teglio A, Alfarano S, Camacho-Cuena E, Ginés-Vilar M (eds) Managing market complexity. Lecture notes in economics and mathematical systems, vol 662. Springer, Berlin, pp 91–102
Zurück zum Zitat Cacho O, Simmons P (1999) A genetic algorithm approach to farm investment. Aust J Agric Res Econ 43(3):305–322CrossRef Cacho O, Simmons P (1999) A genetic algorithm approach to farm investment. Aust J Agric Res Econ 43(3):305–322CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chen S-H, Huang Y-C (2005) On the role of risk preference in survivability. In: Wang L, Chen K, Ong YS (eds) Advances in natural computation. Lecture notes in computer science, vol 3612. Springer, Berlin, pp 612–621CrossRef Chen S-H, Huang Y-C (2005) On the role of risk preference in survivability. In: Wang L, Chen K, Ong YS (eds) Advances in natural computation. Lecture notes in computer science, vol 3612. Springer, Berlin, pp 612–621CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chen S-H, Huang Y-C (2007) Relative risk aversion and wealth dynamics. Inf Sci 177(5):1222–1229CrossRef Chen S-H, Huang Y-C (2007) Relative risk aversion and wealth dynamics. Inf Sci 177(5):1222–1229CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chen S-H, Huang Y-C (2008) Risk preference, forecasting accuracy and survival dynamics: simulations based on a multi-asset agent-based artificial stock market. J Econ Behav Organ 67(3):702–717CrossRef Chen S-H, Huang Y-C (2008) Risk preference, forecasting accuracy and survival dynamics: simulations based on a multi-asset agent-based artificial stock market. J Econ Behav Organ 67(3):702–717CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Condie S (2008) Living with ambiguity: prices and survival when investors have heterogeneous preferences for ambiguity. J Econ Theory 36(1):81–108CrossRef Condie S (2008) Living with ambiguity: prices and survival when investors have heterogeneous preferences for ambiguity. J Econ Theory 36(1):81–108CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Coury T, Sciubba E (2012) Belief heterogeneity and survival in incomplete markets. J Econ Theory 49(1):37–58CrossRef Coury T, Sciubba E (2012) Belief heterogeneity and survival in incomplete markets. J Econ Theory 49(1):37–58CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat De Long JB, Shleifer A, Summers L, Waldman R (1990) Noise trader risk in financial markets. J Polit Econ 98:703–738CrossRef De Long JB, Shleifer A, Summers L, Waldman R (1990) Noise trader risk in financial markets. J Polit Econ 98:703–738CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Easley D, Yang L (2015) Loss aversion, survival and asset prices. J Econ Theory 160:494–516CrossRef Easley D, Yang L (2015) Loss aversion, survival and asset prices. J Econ Theory 160:494–516CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ehrentreich N (2003) A corrected version of the Santa Fe Institute artificial stock market model. In: Complexity 2003: second workshop of the society for computational economics Ehrentreich N (2003) A corrected version of the Santa Fe Institute artificial stock market model. In: Complexity 2003: second workshop of the society for computational economics
Zurück zum Zitat Guiso L, Paiella M (2008) Risk aversion, wealth, and background risk. J Eur Econ Assoc 6:1109–1150CrossRef Guiso L, Paiella M (2008) Risk aversion, wealth, and background risk. J Eur Econ Assoc 6:1109–1150CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hommes CH (2006) Heterogeneous agent models in economics and finance. In: Tesfatsion L, Judd KL (eds) Handbook of computational economics, chapter 23, vol 2. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1109–1186 Hommes CH (2006) Heterogeneous agent models in economics and finance. In: Tesfatsion L, Judd KL (eds) Handbook of computational economics, chapter 23, vol 2. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1109–1186
Zurück zum Zitat Huang Y-C, Tsao C-Y (2017) Evolutionary frequency and forecasting accuracy: simulations based on an agent-based artificial stock market. Comput Econ. doi:10.1007/s10614-017-9662-z Huang Y-C, Tsao C-Y (2017) Evolutionary frequency and forecasting accuracy: simulations based on an agent-based artificial stock market. Comput Econ. doi:10.​1007/​s10614-017-9662-z
Zurück zum Zitat Joshi S, Parker J, Bedau MA (2000) Technical trading creates a prisoner’s dilema: results from an agent-based model in computational finance 99. In: Abu-Mostafa Y, LeBaron B, Lo AW, Weigend AS (eds) Computational finance. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 465–479 Joshi S, Parker J, Bedau MA (2000) Technical trading creates a prisoner’s dilema: results from an agent-based model in computational finance 99. In: Abu-Mostafa Y, LeBaron B, Lo AW, Weigend AS (eds) Computational finance. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 465–479
Zurück zum Zitat LeBaron B (2002) Building the Santa Fe Artificial Stock Market. Brandeis University, Working paper LeBaron B (2002) Building the Santa Fe Artificial Stock Market. Brandeis University, Working paper
Zurück zum Zitat LeBaron B (2006) Agent-based computational finance. In: Tesfatsion L, Judd KL (eds) Handbook of computational economics, chapter 24, vol 2. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1187–1233 LeBaron B (2006) Agent-based computational finance. In: Tesfatsion L, Judd KL (eds) Handbook of computational economics, chapter 24, vol 2. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1187–1233
Zurück zum Zitat LeBaron B, Arthur WB, Palmer R (1999) Time series properties of an artificial stock market. J Econ Dyn Control 23:1487–1516CrossRef LeBaron B, Arthur WB, Palmer R (1999) Time series properties of an artificial stock market. J Econ Dyn Control 23:1487–1516CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lettau M (1997) Explaining the facts with adaptive agents: the case of mutual fund flows. J Econ Dyn Control 21:1117–1147CrossRef Lettau M (1997) Explaining the facts with adaptive agents: the case of mutual fund flows. J Econ Dyn Control 21:1117–1147CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Marinescu D, Marin D (2009) The influence of the absolute risk aversion coefficient on choosing the optimal portfolio. Econ Comput Econ Cybern Stud Res 43(4):43 Marinescu D, Marin D (2009) The influence of the absolute risk aversion coefficient on choosing the optimal portfolio. Econ Comput Econ Cybern Stud Res 43(4):43
Zurück zum Zitat Marks RE (2015) Searching for agents’ best risk profiles. In: Proceedings of the 18th Asia Pacific symposium on intelligent and evolutionary systems, vol 1. pp 297–309 Marks RE (2015) Searching for agents’ best risk profiles. In: Proceedings of the 18th Asia Pacific symposium on intelligent and evolutionary systems, vol 1. pp 297–309
Zurück zum Zitat Polhill JG, Izquierdo LR, Gotts NM (2004) The ghost in the model (and other effects of floating point arithmetic). J Artif Soc Soc Simul 8(1):5 Polhill JG, Izquierdo LR, Gotts NM (2004) The ghost in the model (and other effects of floating point arithmetic). J Artif Soc Soc Simul 8(1):5
Zurück zum Zitat Sandroni A (2000) Do markets favor agents able to make accurate predictions? Econometrica 68:1303–1341CrossRef Sandroni A (2000) Do markets favor agents able to make accurate predictions? Econometrica 68:1303–1341CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sciubba E (2006) The evolution of portfolio rules and the capital asset pricing model. J Econ Theory 29(1):123–150CrossRef Sciubba E (2006) The evolution of portfolio rules and the capital asset pricing model. J Econ Theory 29(1):123–150CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Revisiting the issue of survivability and market efficiency with the Santa Fe Artificial Stock Market
verfasst von
Chueh-Yung Tsao
Ya-Chi Huang
Publikationsdatum
08.03.2017
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination / Ausgabe 3/2018
Print ISSN: 1860-711X
Elektronische ISSN: 1860-7128
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11403-017-0192-5

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3/2018

Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination 3/2018 Zur Ausgabe