Skip to main content

2021 | Buch

The Digital Economy and Competition Law in Asia

insite
SUCHEN

Über dieses Buch

The digital economy, broadly defined as the economy operating on the basis of interconnectivity between people and businesses, has gradually spread over the world. Although a global phenomenon, the digital economy plays out in local economic, political, and regulatory contexts. The problems thus created by the digital economy may be approached differently depending on the context. This edited collection brings together leading scholars based in Asia to detail how their respective jurisdictions respond to the competition law problems evolving out of the deployment of the digital economy. This book is timely, because it will show to what extent new competition law regimes or those with a history of lax enforcement can respond to these new developments in the economy. Academics in law and business strategies with an interest in competition law, both in Asia and more broadly, will find the insights in this edited collection invaluable. Further, this volume will be a key resource for scholars, practitioners and students.

Inhaltsverzeichnis

Frontmatter
The Digital Economy and Asian Competition Law: An Introduction
Abstract
Digital economy is a concept that has been around for nearly three decades. During this period, the concept has developed to include three dimensions. The core dimension of the digital economy surrounds information and communication technology. The narrow dimension of the digital economy embraces digital platforms and the businesses that are built on these platforms. The broad dimension of the digital economy deals with the digitization of the economy, of which artificial intelligence, sensors, cloud-based databases are the core. Several Asian countries, such as India, Indonesia, Japan, and Thailand, are moving towards the broad dimension of the digital economy. Despite this evolution, competition law literature is only recently embracing the concept of digital economy. The preference in the literature was to either refer to specific technological evolutions, use high technology, or bring up the concept of New Economy. It is only recently that digital economy is more and more used by the community of competition law scholars. Much of this literature deals with platforms, data and privacy, thus the narrow dimension of the digital economy. This book will follow this trend. However, the last part of this book will already relate to the broad dimension by discussing the use of artificial intelligence in price setting strategies.
Steven Van Uytsel

Platforms, Unilateral Conduct and Competition Law

Frontmatter
Competition Law Enforcement for Exploitative Abuse by Digital Platforms: The Japanese Approach in a Global Context
Abstract
The enforcement of competition law’s exploitative-abuse clause on digital platforms by competition agencies is aimed at abuse in two-sided markets intermediated by digital platforms: first, platform abuse of their trading-counterparts (suppliers); second, abuse of consumers (users). Abuse of suppliers needs to be identified mostly on procedural fairness; as long as contractual terms are negotiated transparently between platforms and their trading-counterparts, competition agencies are urged to refrain from intervening in substance of trading terms. Digital platforms which abuse consumers, exclusively concerns consumer data. In countries equipped with strong data protection rules, there exists no rationale for competition agencies to assume the role of data-protection agency. Yet, in those countries, where data protection rules and data protection agencies are lacking or weak, competition agencies might assume the role of data protection agency, as an interim measure.
Toshiaki Takigawa
Regulating Competition Between Digital Platforms: The Japan Fair Trade Commission’s Preference for Unfair Trade Practices
Abstract
The Japan Fair Trade Commission (JFTC) has shown an increasing interest in the digital economy. Since the JFTC’s Chairman, Kazuyuki Sugimoto, spoke about this topic in the New Year’s address in 2016, the JFTC publicized several studies on the digital economy. One important issue raised in some of the reports was the central role unfair trade practices could play to force the players in the platform economy to abide with the principles of the Japanese Act on Prohibition of Private Monopolization and Maintenance of Fair Trade (AMA). This conclusion runs parallel to the enforcement actions of the JFTC. In the only cease-and-desist order of the JFTC, a platform was ordered to comply with the AMA through an unfair trade practice. Various decisions to close an investigation on a suspected violation of the AMA, such as against Amazon, Airbnb, or Rakuten, also document the importance of the unfair trade practices as a tool to bring these firms in compliance with the AMA. The evolution to revert to unfair trade practices could be seen as positive. We argue that unfair trade practices allow the JFTC to balance two opposite views in the literature on the platform economy. On the one hand, there is a call for early market intervention to prevent a single platform from growing excessively. On the other hand, there is an argument against intervention because incumbent platforms are innovators and, if not careful, can be challenged on their existence. Unfair trade practices allow for both early intervention and meticulous intervention. Early intervention can be realized because market power is not an important criterion, if at all one, in the conceptualization of an unfair trade practice offence. Meticulous intervention can be guaranteed because unfair trade practices focus on the conduct of an online platform. Unfair trade practices do, in other words, not aim to tackle the ‘bigness’ of the online platforms and so trigger a change in the competitive structure of the market.
Steven Van Uytsel, Yoshiteru Uemura

The Limits of Competition Law in the Digital Economy

Frontmatter
The Nexus Between Competition and Personal Data Protection Laws: Thailand’s Perspective
Abstract
This chapter argues that the data-driven economy needs to figure out how to apply both competition and personal data protection laws. The implementation has to aim at preventing the situation where a group of people disproportionately gains at the expense of another group of people, whose data have been processed by the former. Without proper enforcement of competition and personal data protection laws, we argue that the feedback loop of having more data, better performance and greater talents will eventually worsen the problem of inequality. Thailand serves as a good case study of how the problem exists, while the implementation of both laws is still in retard. We propose that the line separating between personal and public interests has to be drawn and the effective enforcement of competition and personal data protection laws is at the heart of it.
Peerapat Chokesuwattanaskul
Ride Hailings Apps Enter in Competition with Ojek: Indonesia’s Response to the Impact of Disruptive Innovation
Abstract
The Indonesian government has long been struggling with transportation. It has been conceded that Indonesia is lagging behind its neighbor ASEAN member states in providing modern mass transportation. Nevertheless, the demand for affordable, available and safe transportation is huge in a country with more than 250 million people. In response to this demand, drivers of motorcycles have gradually stepped up efforts to fill the gap. Being small and flexible, motorcycles proved to be the ultimate mode of transportation compared to cars, buses, or taxis. Motorcycle drivers started to provide, in an informal way, transport to the public. Often these drivers were unemployed people owning a motorcycle that was largely unused during daytime. As this kind of opportunity offered a source of income, this kind of offering transport became a reliable business opportunity for unemployed people. Informally offering transport to consumers is commonly referred to as Ojek. Ojek, however, is being challenged. Smartphone technology made it possible to start organizing the transportation provided by Ojek online. The advantage of moving Ojek online: increased consumer choice, security, tariff clarity, etc. One of the forerunners in this field is Go-Jek. As Go-Jek gradually increased its services, to include for example courier, food order, house cleaning and even massage services, the ability to attract consumers to the ride hailing app improved. The fast growing expansion of Go-Jek and the entry of companies offering similar online services has impacted Ojek, the conventional motorcycle transportation. The demand for their business declined. Moreover, the conventional taxi services also felt the negative impact of the ride hailing apps. Both identified ride hailing apps as a menace that can destroy the well-established practice of Ojek and the business of conventional taxi companies. This chapter details the friction, caused by disruptive innovation in the telecommunication sector, between Ojek and the drivers using ride hailing apps. This friction has several dimensions. Socially, the Ojek face economic hardship and even unemployment. This is partly due to Internet illiteracy, but also the lack of financial means to afford smartphones needed to make the shift from Ojek to an online one. Policy wise, the government has taken an ambiguous stance towards Ojek. While holding that Ojek does not fit within the category of public transport, the government has taken steps to regulate the use of ride hailing apps used by the conventional taxi business and so discriminate against the motorcycles offering transport. Businesswise, the companies offering ride hailing apps are able to cross-finance between different services and therefore offer promotions on their transportation services that are exclusionary towards Ojek and conventional taxi companies.
Ningrum Natasya Sirait, Mohammad Reza, Angayar Kanni Ramaiah, Aria Suyudi

Algorithms, Coordinated Price Setting, and Competition Law

Frontmatter
Algorithmic Collusion and Indian Competition Act: Suggestions to Tackle Inadequacies and Naivety
Abstract
The debate around algorithmic collusion has gained substantial momentum leading to divergent views amongst economists. While some have expressed serious concerns over the menace of algorithmic collusion and its adverse impact on the competition, others have disregarded it as an unlikely threat. The common scepticism that emanates in any discourse concerning the regulation of the unique forms of algorithmic collusion is the inadequacy of the anti-trust legal framework to effectively tackle issues of detection, investigation and evidence-collection that is incumbent in the process of proving such collusion. Much of these apprehensions are attributable to the inconsistencies in the Indian jurisprudence concerning the elements of ‘hub-and-spoke’, ‘tacit collusion’ and the acceptable ‘plus factors’ required to establish the same. Further, the restrictive approach adopted by the anti-trust authorities in pronouncing judicial decisions impede the scope of the Competition Act, 2002 to address the algorithm problem in its present form. The paper reconnoitres the rise of algorithmic collusion and expounds on how algorithms in disguise of maintaining competitive balance can destroy competition. It further expounds how traditional notions of tacit collusion and hub-and-spoke should be reconstrued in the context of digital markets to bring algorithmic collusion within the sweep of Section 3 of The Indian Competition Act. It further offers an array of reforms and recommendations to adapt the Competition Law and to better equip the Antitrust Authorities to suit the changing needs of the digital market.
Nikita Koradia, Kiran Manokaran, Zara Saeed
Algorithmic Hub-and-Spoke Cartels: A Japanese Perspective
Abstract
The debate on algorithmic collusion has put the hub-and-spoke cartel in the picture. In Japan, a hub-and-spoke cartel, a cartel in which there is a vertical facilitator of horizontal collusion, has long been in existence. Kansei dango, bid-rigging on public procurement projects, have been assisted by bureaucrats. The problem with this kind of cartel was that the Japanese Antimonopoly Act (AMA) is not designed to make the vertical facilitator accountable for its cooperation with the cartel. This resulted in a legislative initiative to deal with the bureaucrats participating in the cartel. A similar evolution has been noticeable in relation to trade associations. This triggers the question of how the AMA can respond to situations in which an algorithm enters the role of facilitator. This contribution argues that an easy answer cannot be given. If the implementation of the algorithm is the result of communication between the enterprises participating in the collusion, the unreasonable restraint provision of the AMA, the provision relevant to price fixing, may be applicable. The only caution that remains is whether the algorithm is implemented at enterprises competing with each other. When an algorithm is able to impose a price on enterprises at another level in the market, and there is thus no communication, even indirectly, between competing enterprises, the Japan Fair Trade Commission may shift to the unfair trade practices provision. More specifically, the unfair trade practice of conditional dealing may apply to a situation in which an algorithm fixes the prices of sellers using the algorithm.
Steven Van Uytsel
Backmatter
Metadaten
Titel
The Digital Economy and Competition Law in Asia
herausgegeben von
Assoc. Prof. Steven Van Uytsel
Copyright-Jahr
2021
Verlag
Springer Singapore
Electronic ISBN
978-981-16-0324-2
Print ISBN
978-981-16-0323-5
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-16-0324-2