Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Fire Technology 6/2018

Open Access 11.07.2018

The J-Value and Its Role in Evaluating Investments in Fire Safety Schemes

verfasst von: Danny Hopkin, Michael Spearpoint, Ruben Van Coile

Erschienen in: Fire Technology | Ausgabe 6/2018

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Fire safety engineers endeavour to ensure that a design achieves an adequate level of fire safety. For uncommon buildings, adequate safety cannot be based on precedent and an explicit evaluation of the adequacy of proposed safety features may be required. Commonly, this requires demonstration that the residual risk associated with the design is as low as is reasonably practicable. In those situations, a measure for a safety scheme’s benefit relative to its cost is required, as more efficient safety schemes should be preferred over less efficient ones to maximize the number of lives saved under societal resource constraints. To this end, the J-value has been introduced in other engineering fields as a decision support indicator for assessing the efficacy of safety features. The J-value has been derived from societal welfare considerations (the Life Quality Index) and is adopted in the current paper for applications in fire safety engineering. It is demonstrated herein how the J-value can inform decisions on fire safety, and how it can provide a basis for assessing whether or not a proposed fire safety scheme should be implemented. Future work will focus on its implementation as a tool for assessing the benefit of real life fire safety scheme implementations, such as sprinkler installations.
Hinweise

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

1 Introduction

1.1 Background

In developing fire safety designs, engineers endeavour to propose solutions that are cognisant of project goals and are delivered within often competing constraints [1]. The most fundamental of these goals is ensuring that an adequate level of safety is achieved. Defining what is adequate under differing circumstances is not straightforward. The ability to articulate and quantify this most fundamental goal is often the crudest facet of the fire safety design process [2].
For common buildings, for which experience of performance in real fires is comparatively plentiful, attainment of adequate safety can often be assumed to be achieved through the adoption of traditional deterministic evaluations. The sphere of deterministic evaluations in this context includes guidance, such as that in Approved Document B [3], BS 9991 [4], BS 9999 [5] (and other comparable international guidance documents/codes), alongside deterministic performance based evaluations where performance in well-defined and well-understood situations is demonstrated through calculation methods. It is, however, critical to note that whilst adequate safety is assumed to be attained, the level of safety is not explicitly quantified. The basis of acceptance is experience [6] and an apparent acceptance with respect to the mortality rates that manifest over time [7].
For uncommon buildings, where there is comparatively limited experience of performance in real fires, adequate safety cannot be assumed to be attained on the basis of reliance on determinism [6]. In this context, an uncommon building might be differentiated as one that has atypical failure consequences, makes use of innovative materials/forms, or combines both. In such cases, the profession has not had an opportunity to learn from experience and converge upon methods, guidance, and tools that align with a society’s expectation for how uncommon cases should perform in the event of a fire. In these cases, an evaluation of the uncertainties associated with a given design problem are necessary to arrive at an adequate safety level and to inform what levels of investment in a safety scheme are justified. This can often only be achieved through probabilistic risk assessment (PRA).
The above distinction in how safety is (or should) be demonstrated for traditional fire-engineering designs and exceptional designs is illustrated in Fig. 1 through the ‘safe design triangle’. All sides of the safe-design triangle need to be properly considered in order to obtain a safe design, but while for traditional designs the entire triangle is supported by a basis or ‘safety foundation’ of the collective experience of the profession, this is not the case for exceptional designs and new (innovative) applications. In those situations, the combination of the different sides of the triangle can only be considered to result in an adequately safe design through an explicit evaluation of the safety level (i.e. quantified safety foundation).

1.2 PRA in Fire Safety Engineering

Fire, by its very nature, is an uncertain phenomenon, both in terms of the factors influencing its occurrence, and also subsequently how it manifests and behaves. Whilst PRA may be seen as an ongoing area of research in fire safety engineering [8], it is apparent that it is fundamental to the fire safety discipline’s progression and maturity. Allied to this, the need for objective cost–benefit analysis (CBA) tools to inform fire safety investments is clear in the current climate, where wide ranging legislative changes are currently under consideration.
Guidance relating to the application of PRA in the UK can be found in the form of PD 7974-7 which is currently subject to revision [9], and in associated textbooks [10]. Much of this guidance relates to the familiar principle of ALARP which is a means through which adequate performance of a safety scheme might be shown by demonstrating that the residual risk is reduced ‘as far as is reasonably practicable’, ALARP (Fig. 2). For a risk to be ALARP, it must be possible to demonstrate that the cost involved in reducing the risk further would be grossly disproportionate to the benefit gained [11]. That is, ALARP requires in some manifestation, a cost–benefit analysis. Note that the ALARP concept has specific legal meaning in particular countries but in the discussion here the ALARP principle relates to the generally applicable realisation (as in ISO2394:2015 [12]) that societal resources for safety investments are limited, and consequently, that a reasonable (efficiency-informed) decision must be made when deciding on which safety schemes to implement.
It is, of course, plausible to make a safety scheme so conservative that it is acceptable without the need to demonstrate ALARP (i.e. within the de minimis region of Fig. 2). However, this prospect must be considered in the context of the finite time, effort and money that can reasonably be expended to converge on something close to zero residual risk. That is, in most cases, demonstrating ALARP would be necessary.
In the process of demonstrating ALARP, it will be necessary to objectively compare the benefits realised from a safety scheme, relative to the investments associated with its implementation. In the following, the ability of a fire safety scheme to contribute to fulfilling the ALARP principle is evaluated based upon a cost–benefit analysis, leading to a cost–benefit scalar defined as the judgement value or J-value.
The process involved in arriving at a fire safety variant of the J-value is discussed in the sections that follow and has been developed from literature published by the originators of the J-value concept [13].

2 Development of the J-Value

2.1 Cost Optimisation in Cost–Benefit Analysis

As is discussed above, the ALARP condition requires cognisance of the safety investment, and the associated benefits. The cost–benefit formulation can be conceptually represented by Eq. 1, based upon comparable structural engineering applications by Rackwitz [14] such that
$$ \Delta Z\left( p \right) = D_{0} \left( p \right) - C\left( p \right) - D_{1} \left( p \right) $$
(1)
where ΔZ is the change in total (lifetime) utility as a result of the proposed safety scheme (and denominated in the same currency as D0, C and D1), D0 is the baseline failure costs prior to the investment in the scheme, C is the cost of the safety scheme, and D1 is the failure cost post implementation [15]. All parameters are a function of a decision parameter, p. The formulation in Eq. 1 starts from the consideration that the investigated building will be built, and that an assessment must be made regarding the efficiency of additional safety features. This formulation conforms with current fire safety engineering practice, where the need for fire safety features is investigated given design constraints, and has the advantage that the utility of a building’s existence must not be assessed as part of the equation.
For a safety investment to be viable, the change in utility must be positive. Considering the above, Eq. 1 can be recast as
$$ CBI\left( p \right) = \frac{C\left( p \right)}{{D_{0} \left( p \right) - D_{1} \left( p \right)}} = \frac{C\left( p \right)}{\Delta D\left( p \right)} $$
(2)
where, \( CBI\left( p \right) \) (the investment cost-to-benefit indicator in function of the safety decision parameter) is simply a measure of the investment costs relative to the benefits (i.e. failure cost reduction) realised and \( \Delta D\left( p \right) \) is the net benefit of the safety scheme. If \( CBI\left( p \right) \) < 1.0, the safety investment has a net benefit to society and, thus, should be considered. To the contrary, \( CBI\left( p \right) \) > 1.0 would infer the safety investment leads to a net dis-benefit as the investment costs outweigh the fire safety benefits. If the \( CBI\left( p \right) \) equals unity (i.e. effectively cost-neutral), there should still be an expectation to invest in the safety scheme.
The constituents in Eqs. 1 and 2 would typically be associated with uncertainty, i.e. both D0 and D1 are dependent upon the frequency associated with fire occurrence, and also the consequences of fire occurrence which can manifest in a number of different ways.

2.2 The Life Quality Index (LQI)

The derivations above have introduced the J-value decision indicator in general terms (via the CBI), considering uncertain future fire-induced losses. The valuation of the benefit derived from investing in fire safety measures is however not without sensitivity. The intended benefit of implementing a safety measure is typically, at a minimum, improving life expectancy. In the literature, numerous difficulties are documented with respect to the valuation of a preventable fatality (VPF) [16, 17]. Thomas and Waddington [16] suggest that the value of healthy life can be determined through people´s revealed preferences. For example, through surplus pay paid to workers facing specific risks. Sunstein [17], however, emphasises the large variations in ‘observed’ VPF with respect to gender, race and social status. Arguably, these kinds of discrepancies cannot readily be used as a basis for societal decision-making on safety, and it can be questioned to which extent revealed preferences are determined by the available information and the bounded rationality of normal people [17] as opposed to perfectly rational economic actors.
In situations without revealed preferences, refuge has been sought with ‘stated preferences’ [16], but also this methodology faces specific difficulties such that the stated preferences cannot be considered independent from the specific scenarios used in the preference survey. Consequently, it is not possible to apply the obtained ‘stated’ VPF for risk-based decision-making in other fields [17].
Most importantly, real designs have safety features which benefit all of its users and thus aggregate (societal) VPF are needed. In other words, the question is how much society is willing (or capable) to spend to prevent the fatality of an undefined member of society.
However, considering a goal of society-wide decision making on risk reduction measures, Nathwani et al. [18] point at the superfluous nature of the explicit discussion of the ‘value’ of a preventable fatality. While lives cannot be exchanged for a monetary value, risk reduction measures can, and society regularly engages in the activity of buying risk reduction measures. Consequently, it is the reduction in society-wide risk to life that should be compared with society´s reduction in available resources for evaluating Eq. 2. Acknowledging the trade-off between wealth and risk to life (i.e. life expectancy) for undefined members of society, Nathwani et al. [18] introduced the LQI as a means of quantifying the utility associated with different decision options. The LQI is now a widely applied tool for decisions on life safety investments, as recognised by its inclusion in the recent international standard ISO2394:2015 [12].
The LQI (Q), as proposed in Nathwani et al. [18], is expressed as
$$ Q = G^{q} X $$
(3)
where G is the societal wealth, as measured by GDP per capita, and X is the (discounted) life expectancy. The exponent q represents work-life balance. After its initial introduction from conceptual considerations, the life quality index has been re-derived from economic principles by Pandey et al. [19]. Considering this derivation, the exponent q is described by Eq. 4, with β the Cobb–Douglas elasticity constant and w the (optimum) fraction of time spent working in an average person’s lifetime
$$ q = \beta \frac{w}{1 - w} $$
(4)
It is assumed that developed societies have, over time, converged to a close-to-optimal work-leisure balance w. Thus, w in Eq. 4 is generally evaluated from observed values. Based on this assumption, Pandey et al. [19] specify q as approximately 0.16 in a western European context and 0.20 in a northern American context. Similar studies specific to the UK by Thomas et al. [20] recommended q as 0.183 in 2010. Decision results are in general not sensitive to the precise value of q and therefore changes of q over time do not need to be taken into account explicitly [19]. A recent study [21] validating the J-value approach, however, highlights the importance of a thorough assessment, indicating higher than previously considered monetary valuations for life safety risk reductions. The implications of the recent study will be investigated in future work. Figure 3 compares LQI values by nation according to [22].

2.3 LQI and J-Value

2.3.1 Societal Willingness to Pay

Returning to Eq. 2, the costs of implementing a safety measure (C) are often reasonably well defined. However, the benefits, particularly in terms of improving the life expectancy of the scheme’s beneficiaries, can be more challenging to quantify. In this case, the LQI is adopted.
Considering the effect of a proposed safety scheme on the LQI, the implementation of the safety scheme results in a new value of the life quality index (Q′ = Q + ∆Q) as specified by Eq. 5, with ∆G the reduction in GDP per capita associated with the implementation of the safety scheme and ∆X the associated increase in life expectancy
$$ Q^{\prime} = Q + \Delta Q = \left( {G + \Delta G} \right)^{q} \left( {X + \Delta X} \right) $$
(5)
which may alternatively be expressed as
$$ Q^{\prime} = Q + \Delta Q = G^{q} \left( {1 + \frac{\Delta G}{G}} \right)^{q} \left( {X + \Delta X} \right) $$
(6)
which for small changes (i.e. ΔG and ΔX small) reduces to the already existing formulation [13]
$$ \frac{\Delta Q}{Q} = q\frac{\Delta G}{G} + \frac{\Delta X}{X} $$
(7)
For the safety measure to be viable, the change in LQI (\( \Delta Q/Q \)) must be positive. This requirement of Eq. 7 being positive is commonly referred to as the ‘LQI net benefit criterion’ [18].
Evaluating the maximum cost for which a given safety scheme is of benefit to society, ΔQ can be (in the limit) equal to zero, and Eq. 7 can be rewritten as in Eq. 8, where—δDf is the maximum per capita investment for a given safety scheme which results in a net benefit to society.
$$ q\frac{\Delta G}{G} + \frac{\Delta X}{X} = 0 \Rightarrow - \Delta G = \frac{1}{q}G\frac{\Delta X}{X} = - \delta D_{f} $$
(8)
Practically, estimating ∆X/X is difficult for a particular hazard. After Rackwitz [14] and Nathwani et al. [18] the change in life expectancy ∆X due to a safety regime can be estimated as being in proportion with the change of mortality rate dm with the proportionality constant Cx specific to a given demographic profile such that
$$ \frac{\Delta X}{X} \approx - C_{x} d_{m} = - C_{x} \frac{\Delta f}{N} $$
(9)
with ∆f the change in annual expected number of fatalities arising from the safety measure (per annum) for a population of size N affected by the particular hazard (the population N could be applied at a building or societal level, depending upon the nature of the problem investigated, e.g. a specific building design vs. regulatory change) that is sought to be mitigated. Thus combining Eqs. 8 and 9 yields
$$ - \delta D_{f} \approx - \frac{G}{q}\frac{{C_{x} \Delta f}}{N} $$
(10)
This is the maximum per capita investment in a given safety scheme to prevent risk to life that is in agreement with society’s capacity to pay. Considering the (expected) annual aversion of a single fatality (∆f = −1), and aggregating the per capita maximum investment to the total societal maximum investment by multiplication with N, results in a total societal willingness to pay (per annum) for a safety scheme that averts a single fatality (per annum). As the ‘per year’ valuations cancel each other, the above results in a life quality index-based valuation of a proportionality constant, societal willingness to pay (SWTP), to be used in the valuation of risk to life, as in [15]:
$$ SWTP \approx \frac{{GC_{x} }}{q} $$
(11)
Values for the SWTP for different discounting rates and mortality reduction schemes can be found in standards such as ISO 2394 (extracts in Table 1). Therein, the SWTP is applied as part of an LQI based boundary condition for monetary optimisation, as indicated in Fig. 4.
Table 1
SWTP for a Selection of Nations Based on 2008 GDP Per Capita, with Differing Mortality Reduction Schemes and Discount Rates: Values in Thousands (Purchasing Power Parity, PPP) $US [12]
Country
SWTP π—life risk reduction is associated with a proportional change in mortality across the age distribution
SWTP ∆—change in mortality due to life risk reduction is uniformly distributed across the age distribution
2%
3%
4%
2%
3%
4%
UK
2600
2178
1873
4105
3665
3270
USA
2488
2100
1822
3187
2833
2542
Australia
3061
2614
2279
4840
4298
3843
India
128
110
93
175
156
139
Figure 4 indicates the relationship between a safety investment decision parameter (p), the impact gradual increases in p has on both the marginal safety investment costs and the marginal failure costs, and also the total life-time cost. The LQI condition, considered in isolation of other safety investment benefits, presents a lower bound for the minimum justified value of p. However, as is indicated, this might not be the optimal value, as other benefits are often realised through investment in safety schemes.

2.3.2 Derivation of a Fire Safety Variant of the J-Value

Section 2.1 points to the challenge of arriving an objective decision metric where accident occurrence rates and their consequences are subject to uncertainty, and differing valuations by societal and private stakeholders.
Individual organisations may wish to apply their own risk aversion to the change in monetary losses/costs associated with damage, loss of assets, and injury depending on their capacity to accept such losses. With respect to life safety, societal considerations result in a lower bound for investments in life safety [12, 23] . Societal life safety considerations thus taken into account, the total judgement value (or JT) is expressed as Eq. 12
$$ J_{T} = \frac{C}{{M_{R} \cdot \Delta D_{e} + \Delta D_{f} }} $$
(12)
where \( M_{R} \) is a risk scalar (-) resulting from risk aversion in an organization’s decision making [24], \( \Delta D_{e} \) is the change in losses/costs associated with damage, loss of assets, and injury, and \( \Delta D_{f} \) is the safety investment that is warranted to protect the lives of N people. For further discussion and derivation of the JT equation, reference is made to [24, 25, 26].
As discussed by Nathwani et al. [18], decision making for society-wide life safety investments necessitates risks to life to be evaluated equitably across population groups and risks. For risks without the possibility of ruin, as is the case for fire safety investments in the built environment where the occurrence of fire is, on a larger scale, independent between buildings, this implies that \( M_{R} \) can be taken equal to unity. For private organizations, where possible consequences are large (e.g. comparable with its total assets), the valuation for MR will be higher as the acceptability of high consequences is, in relative terms, lower than more frequent low consequence events. As noted above, here MR = 1 considering societal decision-making where the tolerability of consequences is explicitly confirmed prior to the ALARP assessment, and where no qualitative distinction is made between tolerable consequences in function of their magnitude, see [27]. This leads to
$$ J_{T} = \frac{C}{{\Delta D_{e} + \Delta D_{f} }} $$
(13)
In the first instance, it is assumed that the only motivation for and quantifiable benefit of a safety scheme is to improve life expectancy. That is, \( \Delta D_{e} = 0 \). For a fire safety application, the J-value is then simply derived from Eq. 10, as shown below
$$ J_{fi} = \frac{C}{{\Delta D_{f} }} = \frac{q}{G}\frac{C}{{C_{x} \Delta f}} = \frac{C}{SWTP \cdot \Delta f} = \frac{C}{{SWTP \cdot \lambda_{ig} \cdot N \cdot \left( {\lambda_{f,0} - \lambda_{f,1} } \right)}} $$
(14)
with \( \lambda_{ig} \) the annual fire occurrence probability [y−1], and \( \lambda_{f,0} \) and \( \lambda_{f,1} \) the per person probability of a fire induced fatality given fire occurrence, before and after implementation of the safety scheme, respectively.
The resulting J-value is of the same form to that proposed by the J-value originators [13] (but with subscript ‘fi’ to differentiate its use in a fire safety application and the omission of ‘T’ inferring other benefits arising from the safety scheme are disregarded), and is equivalent to the LQI net benefit criterion, as has been applied in a limited number of fire safety engineering studies to date [23, 28, 29]. It provides a scalar interpretation of the cost-effectiveness of a given safety scheme. The original formulation has been augmented with additional terms in Eq. 14 that are specific to application in fire safety schemes.
It is relevant to note that in the formulation of Eq. 14 the cost C of the safety scheme is evaluated on an annual basis. If a large upfront cost is associated with the safety scheme, or if large maintenance is required periodically, discounting is required to evaluate the cost and benefits for the J-value on the same basis. This will be discussed further in Sect. 3.3.

3 Inclusion of Other Fire Safety Benefits and Discounting

3.1 Injury and Damage

In the original proposal for the J-value by Thomas et al. [16], the viability of a safety scheme is evaluated purely in terms of its ability to improve (discounted) life expectancy. Commonly, other benefits are realised after the introduction of a safety measure. Non-exhaustively these might include a reduction in injury or the mitigation of damage. This differentiation leads to the total judgement value [26], as previously introduced in Eq. 10. The starting position is, therefore, that the net benefit of the safety measure (\( \Delta D \)) comprises three terms, with ∆Di the utility associated with the change in expected injury rate, ΔDd the utility in the change in expected material damage rate in addition to the previously defined ΔDf, such that
$$ \Delta D = \Delta D_{f} + \Delta D_{e} = \Delta D_{f} + \Delta D_{i} + \Delta D_{d} $$
(15)
In the case of injury, let ∆i be the reduction in the expected fire induced injury rate (per person, per annum) because of the safety investment, C. For a given injury in fire, a cost can be attributed. This cost represents the total equivalent monetary cost of the injury and thus includes e.g. medical costs, lost productivity, possible permanent disability and psychological distress. As, typically, the safety investment is taken to benefit a large population and, for any given fire, the nature of the injury will not be known, an average cost per injury can be adopted for valuing the implications of a typical injury (ζi). This leads to the utility associated with the change in injury rate (∆Di) for a population size N
$$ \Delta D_{i} = N\Delta i\zeta_{i} = N\lambda_{ig} (\lambda_{i,0} - \lambda_{i,1} )\zeta_{i} $$
(16)
with \( \lambda_{i,0} \) and \( \lambda_{i,1} \) the probability of an individual suffering injury should a fire occur (per fire) before and after the implementation of the safety scheme, respectively. This formulation assumes that the safety scheme mostly affects the rate of injuries, not the type of injury when an injury occurs.
Similarly, in the case of material damage, ∆Dd can be defined as the change in expected per fire damage costs
$$ \Delta D_{d} = \lambda_{ig} \left( {\Delta \zeta_{d,0} - \Delta \zeta_{d,1} } \right) $$
(17)
with \( \Delta \zeta_{d,0} \) and \( \Delta \zeta_{d,1} \) the expected material damage in the case of fire before and after the implementation of the safety scheme, respectively.
Revisiting Eq. 14, an alternative total judgement value emerges for fire safety applications, which will be defined as Jfi,T such that
$$ J_{fi,T} = \frac{C}{{\Delta D_{f} + \Delta D_{i} + \Delta D_{d} }} $$
(18)

3.2 Renewal Process and Implications for Valuation of Damages

The valuation of losses due to fatalities, injury and damage are subject to uncertainty. In Eqs. 14 to 17, the fire ignition rate (\( \lambda_{ig} \)) is taken to correspond with some consequence, in terms of expected fatalities, injury and damage. However, for each individual accident occurrence, the consequences are not known, and would vary significantly between events. This means the J-value, as noted in Eq. 18 would fluctuate, making objective decision-making challenging on a case by case basis.
For societal decision-making, where the need for safety features is assessed conceptually considering a wide portfolio of buildings and continued future need of the public for these buildings, a renewal process is assumed where the building is restored or replaced (depending upon the post-fire outcome) to its pre-fire condition after each fire event, as argued by Fischer [23]. Consequently, the building is exposed to the possibility of repeated fire occurrences. It is assumed that after each fire event the building is reinstated considering the same safety features as in the original design. Any losses are thus not a consequence of faulty designs or implementation, but are a manifestation of the residual risk inherent in each design. Fundamental derivations for renewal processes can be found in [30, 31].
The implementation of Eq. 18 may be on the basis of mean values in the context of societal-decision making (i.e. absent of private risk aversion multipliers, and/or a risk of ruin). That is, the ignition rate is normalised to a ‘per unit’ basis, as are the corresponding (mean) number of fatalities, injuries and damages, both before and after the implementation of a safety measure.

3.3 Inclusion of Discounting

As the safety investment relates to the reduction of future risk, the cost–benefit analysis (J-value in this case) requires that future costs and benefits incurred at different times are discounted to a common reference point, or annualised, using a (continuous) discount rate (γ).
In the above derivations, both the investment cost C and the benefit terms were evaluated on an annual basis. If the safety investment, however, relates to a single upfront investment (e.g. in permanent structural fire protection), the future benefit terms incurred over the lifetime L need to be discounted to the investment time for the J-value evaluation. For example, in the case of ∆D, applying the derivations set out in Van Coile, et al. [32] yields the discounted equivalent, ∆Dγ of
$$ \Delta D_{\gamma } = \frac{\Delta D}{\gamma } \cdot \left( {1 - e^{ - \gamma L} } \right) = \frac{{\Delta D_{f} + \Delta D_{i} + \Delta D_{d} }}{\gamma } \cdot \left( {1 - e^{ - \gamma L} } \right) $$
(19)

3.4 Implementation and Continuing Costs

While both annualised costs and a single upfront investment have been treated above, a more general formulation of the cost (C) considers an upfront sum (C0), and depending on the particular scheme there may also be an ongoing annual cost (m) which is paid over its life (L). This cost can be expressed as
$$ C = C_{0} + m_{\gamma } $$
(20)
where \( m_{\gamma } \) is deduced via the common net present value calculation procedure:
$$ m_{\gamma } = \mathop \sum \limits_{t = 1}^{L} \frac{m}{{\left( {1 + \gamma } \right)^{t} }} $$
For a scheme that includes, say, a sprinkler system, then there will be installation and maintenance costs, whereas the application of a passive fire protection system may only incur an up-front increased construction cost.

3.5 Application of the J-Value to an Exemplar Scheme

To conceptually demonstrate the application of the proposals developed herein, the fire safety J-value is applied in the evaluation of the cost effectiveness of an exemplar fire safety scheme. This mitigates the need for specific discussions regarding the possible benefits and costs associated with a specific safety scheme, for example, sprinkler protection. Solely for the purpose of demonstration, arbitrary but sufficiently reasonable input figures for the purpose of evaluating the viability of the safety scheme are provided in Table 2.
Table 2
Exemplar Fire Safety Scheme CBA Inputs
Input
Symbol
Metric
Unit
Number of buildings that could be affected by fire
N units
1,000,000
Units
Number of building fires (ignitions)
N fi
1500
Fires/year
Fatalities due to building fires prior to implementation of the safety scheme
\( N \cdot \lambda_{f,0} \)
0.01
Person/fire
Injuries due to building fires prior to implementation of the safety scheme
\( N \cdot \lambda_{i,0} \)
0.33
Injuries/fire
Cost of injury prevented
\( \zeta_{i} \)
20,000
£/injury
Average cost of damage to property per fire
\( \zeta_{d,0} \)
10,000
£/fire
Reduction in fatalities due to safety scheme
χf
90
%/fire
Reduction in injuries due to safety scheme
χi
75
%/fire
Reduction in damage due to safety scheme
χd
90
%/fire
Safety scheme upfront cost
C 0
2000
£
Maintenance cost per annum of safety scheme
m
100
£
Discount rate
γ
3
%
Design life of safety scheme
L
50
year
Two assessments are carried out herein: Firstly, the analysis examines the societal benefit of the exemplar system with the given inputs. Secondly, the maximum safety investment that might be justifiable for a given safety objective is investigated. In each case the Society Willing to Pay (SWTP) has been taken to be £2,500,000 per statistical life saved corresponding to a typical UK value from Table 1.
For the societal benefit analysis, the derived quantities leading to the evaluation of the fire safety J-value are summarised in Table 3. The resultant J-value demonstrates that, on the prerequisite that the absence of the safety scheme leads to a tolerable mortality rate, an investment in such a safety scheme would lead to a net dis-benefit to society. That is, the costs are circa 3 times the benefits when evaluated over the scheme’s life-time.
Table 3
Derived Quantities in CBA for the Societal Benefit of the Exemplar System
Derived quantity
Symbol
Derivation
Metric
Unit
Annual fire occurrence rate
\( \lambda_{ig} \)
\( \frac{{N_{fi} }}{{N_{units} }} \)
0.0015
Fires/building/year
Fatalities due to building fires post implementation of the safety scheme
\( N \cdot \lambda_{f,1} \)
\( N \cdot \lambda_{f,0} \left( {1 - \chi_{f} } \right) \)
0.001
Person/ignition
Life preservation benefit
\( \Delta D_{f} \)
\( N \cdot SWTP \cdot \lambda_{ig} \left( {\lambda_{f,0} - \lambda_{f,1} } \right) \)
33.75
£/year/building
Injuries due to building fires post implementation of the safety scheme
\( N \cdot \lambda_{i,1} \)
\( N \cdot \lambda_{i,0} \left( {1 - \chi_{i} } \right) \)
0.0825
Injuries/ignition
Injury reduction benefit
\( \Delta D_{i} \)
\( N \cdot \lambda_{ig} (\lambda_{i,0} - \lambda_{i,1} )\zeta_{i} \)
7.43
£/year/building
Fire induced damage post implementation of the safety scheme
\( \Delta \zeta_{d,1} \)
\( (1 - \chi_{d} )\Delta \zeta_{d,0} \)
1000
£/fire
Damage reduction benefit
\( \Delta D_{d} \)
\( \lambda_{ig} \left( {\Delta \zeta_{d,0} - \Delta \zeta_{d,1} } \right) \)
13.50
£/year/building
Benefit arising from safety scheme
D
\( \Delta D_{f} + \Delta D_{i} + \Delta D_{d} \)
54.68
£/year/building
Discounted benefit over installation life, L
Dγ
\( \Delta D_{\gamma } = \frac{\Delta D}{\gamma } \cdot \left( {1 - e^{ - \gamma L} } \right) \)
1415.85
£/building
Discounted maintenance cost
m γ
\( {\mathop \sum \limits_{t = 1}^{L} \frac{m}{{\left( {1 + \gamma } \right)^{t} }}} \)
2572.98
£/building
Costs of safety measure
C
\( c_{0} + m_{\gamma } \)
4572.98
£/building
J-value for fire safety scheme
J T,fi
\( \frac{C}{{\Delta D_{\upgamma} }} \)
3.23
(–)
In analogy to the evaluation in Table 3, to investigate the maximum safety investment let the objective of a given safety scheme be a 50% reduction in fatalities and injuries per building per annum. For simplicity, it is also assumed that the safety scheme is 100% effective, and the operational life of the safety measure is also 50 years. The maximum justifiable investment in the safety scheme (C), would arise when JT,fi = 1.0 which is considered as an investment not leading to a net dis-benefit to society.
Table 4 shows the corresponding derived quantities where the result is that the justifiable investment would be circa £614 per building for the given safety objective. If any such safety provision required maintenance, the upfront investment cost plus the discounted life-time maintenance cost would have to remain below £614 for the J-value not to exceed unity.
Table 4
Derived Quantities in CBA for the Maximum Safety Investment Analysis
Derived quantity
Symbol
Derivation
Metric
Unit
Annual fire occurrence rate
\( \lambda_{ig} \)
\( \frac{{N_{fi} }}{{N_{units} }} \)
0.0015
Fires/building/year
Fatalities due to building fires post implementation of the safety scheme
\( N \cdot \lambda_{f,1} \)
N \( \cdot 0.5\lambda_{f,0} \)
0.005
Person/ignition
Life preservation benefit
\( \Delta D_{f} \)
\( N \cdot SWTP \cdot \lambda_{ig} \cdot 0.5\lambda_{f,0} \)
18.7
£/year/building
Injuries due to building fires post implementation of the safety scheme
\( N \cdot \lambda_{i,1} \)
\( N \cdot 0.5\lambda_{i,0} \)
0.167
Injuries/ignition
Injury reduction benefit
\( \Delta D_{i} \)
\( N \cdot \lambda_{ig} \cdot 0.5\lambda_{i,0} \cdot \zeta_{i} \)
5.01
£/year/building
Benefit arising from safety scheme
D
\( \Delta D_{f} + \Delta D_{i} \)
23.71
£/year/building
Discounted benefit over installation life, L
Dγ
\( \Delta D_{\gamma } = \frac{\Delta D}{\gamma } \cdot \left( {1 - e^{ - \gamma L} } \right) \)
613.99
£/building
Justifiable cost of safety measure
C
\( C{ = }\Delta D_{\varvec{\gamma}} \)
613.99
£/building

4 Conclusions

An implementation of the existing J-value [13] method has been developed for the assessment of the cost vs. benefits associated with fire safety investment schemes. The modified (fire safety) J-value is fundamentally consistent with the total judgement value presented in [26], and incorporates the costs associated with mortality, injuries and property damage, as well as accounting for the discounted costs of the implementation of a scheme. A conceptual application of the J-value is presented to illustrate how the method can be used to assess the cost–benefit of an exemplar fire safety scheme and to then examine how the method can be used to determine the justifiable level of investment for a given set of fire safety goals.
The fire safety J-value is also equivalent to the LQI-net-benefit criterion, as has been subject to investigations in fire safety engineering studies for evaluating specific safety schemes, e.g. sprinkler systems [29], variations in exit width [28], and structural reliability [23]. The formulation proposed herein is general and, as such, may be applied to evaluate the efficacy of a range of fire safety schemes, and their associated realisation costs. The J-value is simple in its interpretation, i.e. a value less than or equal to unity implies a net-benefit to society as a result of investment in a particular fire safety scheme.
Unlike typical ALARP applications, the J-value is evaluated using an objective criterion for acceptance. (i.e. a value less than or equal to unity). That is, in the context of gross disproportion, whereby one invests in safety measures until the costs are significantly out of proportion with the benefits, the J-value provides a clearly defined proportionality condition, and is not reliant upon subjective judgements of authorities having jurisdiction.
Parallel complimentary studies [33] discuss a specific application of the J-value concept presented herein to sprinkler installations in single occupancy dwellings (i.e. houses), with results compared for differing jurisdictions (Wales, Australia and New Zealand). Further studies are planned to evaluate the merits of sprinkler installations to London high-rise buildings, as has been advocated in a recent publication by the London Assembly [34].
Open AccessThis article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Literatur
2.
Zurück zum Zitat Hopkin D, Ballantyne A, O’Loughlin E, McColl B (2016) Design goals—fire resistance demands for tall residential buildings. In: Proceedings of Interflam 2016 Hopkin D, Ballantyne A, O’Loughlin E, McColl B (2016) Design goals—fire resistance demands for tall residential buildings. In: Proceedings of Interflam 2016
3.
Zurück zum Zitat DCLG (2006) Approved document B, vol 2—buildings other than dwelling houses, NBS for the Department for Communities and Local Government, London DCLG (2006) Approved document B, vol 2—buildings other than dwelling houses, NBS for the Department for Communities and Local Government, London
4.
Zurück zum Zitat BSI (2015) BS 9991:2015 Fire safety in the design, management and use of residential buildings. Code of practice. British Standards Institution, London BSI (2015) BS 9991:2015 Fire safety in the design, management and use of residential buildings. Code of practice. British Standards Institution, London
5.
Zurück zum Zitat BSI (2017) BS 9999:2017 Code of practice for fire safety in the design, management and use of buildings. British Standards Institution, London BSI (2017) BS 9999:2017 Code of practice for fire safety in the design, management and use of buildings. British Standards Institution, London
6.
Zurück zum Zitat Hopkin D, Coile R Van, Lange D (2017) Certain uncertainty. SFPE, Europe Issue 07 Hopkin D, Coile R Van, Lange D (2017) Certain uncertainty. SFPE, Europe Issue 07
7.
Zurück zum Zitat Spinardi G, Bisby L, Torero J (2017) A review of sociological issues in fire safety regulation. Fire Technol 53:1011–1037CrossRef Spinardi G, Bisby L, Torero J (2017) A review of sociological issues in fire safety regulation. Fire Technol 53:1011–1037CrossRef
8.
Zurück zum Zitat Hadjisophocleous GV, Benichou N (1999) Performance criteria used in fire safety design. Autom Constr 8:489–501CrossRef Hadjisophocleous GV, Benichou N (1999) Performance criteria used in fire safety design. Autom Constr 8:489–501CrossRef
9.
Zurück zum Zitat BSI. (2003). PD 7974-7:2003, Application of fire safety engineering principles to the design of buildings—part 7: probabilistic risk assessment. British Standard BSI. (2003). PD 7974-7:2003, Application of fire safety engineering principles to the design of buildings—part 7: probabilistic risk assessment. British Standard
10.
Zurück zum Zitat Ramachandran G, Charters D (2011) Quantitative risk assessment in fire safety 1. Spon Press, London Ramachandran G, Charters D (2011) Quantitative risk assessment in fire safety 1. Spon Press, London
11.
Zurück zum Zitat Jones-Lee M, Aven T (2011) ALARP—What does it really mean? Reliab Eng Syst Saf 96:877–882CrossRef Jones-Lee M, Aven T (2011) ALARP—What does it really mean? Reliab Eng Syst Saf 96:877–882CrossRef
12.
Zurück zum Zitat ISO (2015) ISO 2394:2015. General principles on reliability of structures, International Standard ISO (2015) ISO 2394:2015. General principles on reliability of structures, International Standard
13.
Zurück zum Zitat Thomas PJ, Stupples DW, Alghaffar MA (2006) The extent of regulatory consensus on health and safety expenditure. part 1: development of the J-value technique and evaluation of the regulators’ recommendations. Process Saf Environ Prot 84(5):329–336. https://doi.org/10.1205/psep.05005 CrossRef Thomas PJ, Stupples DW, Alghaffar MA (2006) The extent of regulatory consensus on health and safety expenditure. part 1: development of the J-value technique and evaluation of the regulators’ recommendations. Process Saf Environ Prot 84(5):329–336. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1205/​psep.​05005 CrossRef
14.
Zurück zum Zitat Rackwitz R (2002) Optimization and risk acceptability based on the life quality index Struct Saf 24:297–331CrossRef Rackwitz R (2002) Optimization and risk acceptability based on the life quality index Struct Saf 24:297–331CrossRef
15.
Zurück zum Zitat Van Coile R, Jomaas G, Bisby L (2017) Defining ALARP for fire safety engineering design via the life quality index. Fire Saf J—under review Van Coile R, Jomaas G, Bisby L (2017) Defining ALARP for fire safety engineering design via the life quality index. Fire Saf J—under review
16.
Zurück zum Zitat Thomas P, Waddington I (2016). Review of the value of a prevented fatality (VPF) used by regulators and others in the UK. Nuclear Future Thomas P, Waddington I (2016). Review of the value of a prevented fatality (VPF) used by regulators and others in the UK. Nuclear Future
17.
Zurück zum Zitat Sunstein CR (2005) Laws of fear. Beyond the precautionary principle. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef Sunstein CR (2005) Laws of fear. Beyond the precautionary principle. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
18.
Zurück zum Zitat Nathwani J, Lind NC, Pandey MD (1997). Affordable safety by choice: the life quality method. University of Waterloo Nathwani J, Lind NC, Pandey MD (1997). Affordable safety by choice: the life quality method. University of Waterloo
19.
Zurück zum Zitat Pandey MD, Nathwani JS, Lind NC (2006) The derivation and calibration of the life-quality index (LQI) from economic principles. Struct Saf 28:341–360CrossRef Pandey MD, Nathwani JS, Lind NC (2006) The derivation and calibration of the life-quality index (LQI) from economic principles. Struct Saf 28:341–360CrossRef
21.
Zurück zum Zitat Thomas P, Waddington I (2017) Validating the J-value safety assessment tool against pan-national data. Process Saf Environ Prot 112A:179–197CrossRef Thomas P, Waddington I (2017) Validating the J-value safety assessment tool against pan-national data. Process Saf Environ Prot 112A:179–197CrossRef
22.
Zurück zum Zitat Rackwitz R , Streicher H (2002) Optimization and target reliabilities. Joint Committee on Structural Safety. JCSS Workshop on Code Calibration, Zurich Rackwitz R , Streicher H (2002) Optimization and target reliabilities. Joint Committee on Structural Safety. JCSS Workshop on Code Calibration, Zurich
23.
Zurück zum Zitat Fischer K (2014) Societal decision-making for optimal fire safety. Doctoral dissertation. ETH Zurich, Switzerland Fischer K (2014) Societal decision-making for optimal fire safety. Doctoral dissertation. ETH Zurich, Switzerland
24.
Zurück zum Zitat Thomas PJ, Jones RD, Boyle WJO (2010) The limits to risk aversion. part 1: the point of indiscriminate decision. Process Saf Environ Prot 88(6):381–495CrossRef Thomas PJ, Jones RD, Boyle WJO (2010) The limits to risk aversion. part 1: the point of indiscriminate decision. Process Saf Environ Prot 88(6):381–495CrossRef
25.
Zurück zum Zitat Thomas PJ, Jones RD, Boyle WJO (2010) The limits to risk aversion. part 2: the permission point and examples. Process Saf Environ Prot 88(6):396–406CrossRef Thomas PJ, Jones RD, Boyle WJO (2010) The limits to risk aversion. part 2: the permission point and examples. Process Saf Environ Prot 88(6):396–406CrossRef
26.
Zurück zum Zitat Thomas PJ, Jones RD (2010) Extending the J-value framework for safety analysis to include the environmental costs of a large accident. Process Saf Environ Prot 88(5):297–317CrossRef Thomas PJ, Jones RD (2010) Extending the J-value framework for safety analysis to include the environmental costs of a large accident. Process Saf Environ Prot 88(5):297–317CrossRef
28.
Zurück zum Zitat De Sanctis G, Fontana M (2016) Risk-based optimisation of fire safety egress provisions based on the LQI acceptance criterion. Reliab Eng Syst Saf 152:339–350CrossRef De Sanctis G, Fontana M (2016) Risk-based optimisation of fire safety egress provisions based on the LQI acceptance criterion. Reliab Eng Syst Saf 152:339–350CrossRef
29.
Zurück zum Zitat Hasofer AM, Thomas IR (2008) Cost benefit analysis of a fire safety system based on the life quality index. Fire Saf Sci 9:969–980CrossRef Hasofer AM, Thomas IR (2008) Cost benefit analysis of a fire safety system based on the life quality index. Fire Saf Sci 9:969–980CrossRef
30.
Zurück zum Zitat Pandey MD, Wang Z, Cheng T (2015) Stochastic renewal process models for life cycle cost and utility analysis. Proceedings of ICASP12, Vancouver 12-15/07 Pandey MD, Wang Z, Cheng T (2015) Stochastic renewal process models for life cycle cost and utility analysis. Proceedings of ICASP12, Vancouver 12-15/07
31.
Zurück zum Zitat Pandey MD, van der Weide JAM (2017) Stochastic renewal process models for estimation of damage cost over the life-cycle of a structure. Struct Saf 67:27–38CrossRef Pandey MD, van der Weide JAM (2017) Stochastic renewal process models for estimation of damage cost over the life-cycle of a structure. Struct Saf 67:27–38CrossRef
32.
Zurück zum Zitat Van Coile R, Caspeele R, Taerwe L (2014) Lifetime cost optimization for the structural fire resistance of concrete slabs. Fire Technol 50:1201–1227CrossRef Van Coile R, Caspeele R, Taerwe L (2014) Lifetime cost optimization for the structural fire resistance of concrete slabs. Fire Technol 50:1201–1227CrossRef
33.
Zurück zum Zitat Spearpoint M, Hopkin D (2018). Evaluation of the justifiable investment in residential sprinkler system installations using the J-value methodology. In: Third European symposium on fire safety sciences (ESFSS 2018), 12th–14th Sep 2018, Nancy, France Spearpoint M, Hopkin D (2018). Evaluation of the justifiable investment in residential sprinkler system installations using the J-value methodology. In: Third European symposium on fire safety sciences (ESFSS 2018), 12th–14th Sep 2018, Nancy, France
34.
Zurück zum Zitat Greater London Authority (2018) Never again: sprinklers as the next step towards safer homes, London Assembly Planning Committee, 50 p Greater London Authority (2018) Never again: sprinklers as the next step towards safer homes, London Assembly Planning Committee, 50 p
Metadaten
Titel
The J-Value and Its Role in Evaluating Investments in Fire Safety Schemes
verfasst von
Danny Hopkin
Michael Spearpoint
Ruben Van Coile
Publikationsdatum
11.07.2018
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Fire Technology / Ausgabe 6/2018
Print ISSN: 0015-2684
Elektronische ISSN: 1572-8099
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10694-018-0752-9

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 6/2018

Fire Technology 6/2018 Zur Ausgabe