Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Journal of Economics and Finance 4/2022

Open Access 06.07.2022

The role of domestic and foreign economic uncertainties in determining the foreign exchange rates: an extended monetary approach

verfasst von: S. M. Woahid Murad

Erschienen in: Journal of Economics and Finance | Ausgabe 4/2022

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This study extends the monetary model of the exchange rate by incorporating news-based domestic and US economic policy uncertainties (EPUs). We consider 12 developed and developing economies and use monthly data covering 2000:M1 to 2017:M2. The extended monetary model is estimated by the panel quantile regression of Machado and Santos Silva (2019) and Pesaran (2006) common correlated effects within linear and nonlinear panel ARDL frameworks. The estimates illustrate the significant effects of EPUs on developed and developing economies. The ARDL models show that the impact of EPUs is mostly a long-run phenomenon. The Wald test statistics confirm asymmetric effects of EPUs at different quantiles. Moreover, the Wald statistics also support the asymmetric effects of increasing and decreasing EPUs. Overall, domestic, and foreign economic uncertainties significantly affect developed and developing economies’ exchange rates, at least in the long run. Therefore, economic uncertainty should be considered in determining the exchange rate. This extended model might be more appropriate in the post-Covid-19 era.
Hinweise

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

1 Introduction

In the aftermath of the recent global financial crisis (2007:Q4 to 2009:Q2), economists devote themselves extensively to measuring different sorts of economic uncertainty and analyzing its macroeconomic effects (for instance, Bloom 2009, 2014; Carrière-Swallow and Céspedes 2013; Jurado et al. 2015; Baker et al. 2016; Jo, and Sekkel, 2019; and Ahir et al. 2020). The COVID-19 pandemic intensifies the importance of studying the economic uncertainty further1. According to Hassett and Metcalf (1999), macroeconomic policies may not work properly under such uncertain prospects. For instance, Handley and Limão (2017) found that policy uncertainty adversely affects investment in export-oriented firms and technological progress, which diminishes trade and real income. Bloom et al. (2018) examined how uncertainty shaped business cycles and found that uncertainty reduced GDP by almost 2.5%. Moreover, Caggiano et al. (2017) also found that the incremental effect of unpredictable policy uncertainty on unemployment in the US economy is significantly larger during the recession. Likewise, policy uncertainty also affects the short-run and long-run money demand functions (Ivanovski and Churchill 2019; Hossain and Arwatchanakarn 2020; and Murad et al. 2021). Consequently, it is essential to encompass economic uncertainty in the conventional macroeconomic model and estimate its effect in determining macroeconomic variables. Analogously, an exchange rate determination model is not an exception.
Numerous studies examine the effect of economic risks and uncertainty on the exchange rate return and volatility. Most of these studies find a positive and statistically significant effect of economic uncertainty on the exchange rate volatility (Krol 2014; Balcilar et al. 2016; Chen et al. 2020; Bush and López Noria 2021; Abid and Rault 2021). However, such analyses do not explore the direction of movement of the exchange rate, namely, whether economic uncertainty appreciates or depreciates domestic currency. On the contrary, very few empirical works analyze the effect of economic uncertainty on the exchange rate and its expectations (Kido 2016; Beckmann and Czudaj 2017; Abid 2020) finds adverse spillover effects of US economic uncertainty on the high-yielding currencies, while the effect is positive for the Japanese currency. Like Kido (2016), Beckmann and Czudaj (2017) also find that economic, fiscal, and monetary uncertainties adversely affect Euro, Canadian dollar, and British pound sterling against the US dollar, while the Japanese yen appreciates at higher uncertainty. Furthermore, Abid (2020) revisits the determination of the exchange rate. Using a linear ARDL model, the author obtains significant short-run and long-run effects of economic uncertainty on the exchange rate. However, except for Beckmann and Czudaj (2017), most prior studies do not consider a conventional monetary approach to exchange rate determination. Therefore, most of these studies may potentially suffer from model misspecification due to omitting relevant variables. Moreover, Beckmann and Czudaj (2017) include only economic, monetary, and fiscal uncertainty indexes of the US in estimating exchange rates of Canada, Euro Area, Japan, and the UK. They do not incorporate the domestic economic uncertainties of the corresponding economies.
The novelty of this study is including both domestic and US economic policy uncertainties (EPUs) within the monetary approach to the exchange rate.2 Recently developed panel quantile regression with the method of moments and nonlinear panel ARDL models have been employed in the analysis to explore potential asymmetric effects of EPUs on the exchange rates.
The rest of this paper covers the following sections: Sect. 2 describes the specification of the empirical model, sources of data, and methods, while Sect. 3 discusses empirical results obtained from the analysis. Finally, the conclusion and policy recommendations are presented in Sect. 4.

2 Model specification, data, and methods

Considering the purchasing power parity, money market equilibrium, and the uncovered interest parity, the monetary model of exchange rate can be expressed as
$${s}_{i,t}={\lambda }_{0}+{\lambda }_{1}\left({m}_{i,t}-{m}_{i,t}^{*}\right)+{\lambda }_{2}\left({y}_{i,t}-{y}_{i,t}^{*}\right)+{\lambda }_{3}\left({i}_{i,t}-{i}_{i,t}^{*}\right)+{u}_{i,t}$$
(1)
where \(s\) is the exchange rate of corresponding domestic currency against the US dollar; \(m\) and \({m}^{*}\) are domestic and the US money supplies; \(y\) and \(y\) are domestic and the US incomes; \(i\) and \({i}^{*}\) are domestic, and the US interest rates, and finally, \(u\) is the white noise error term. \(i\) and \(t\) denote \(i\)th economy and time, respectively. All the variables are transformed in natural log. Now, including EPUs, an extended monetary model can be obtained from Eqs. (1),
$${s}_{i,t}={\beta }_{0}+{\beta }_{1}\left({m}_{i,t}-{m}_{i,t}^{*}\right)+{\beta }_{2}\left({y}_{i,t}-{y}_{i,t}^{*}\right)+{\beta }_{3}\left({i}_{i,t}-{i}_{i,t}^{*}\right)+{\beta }_{4}{epu}_{i,t}+{\beta }_{5}{epu}_{i,t}^{*}+{\epsilon }_{i,t}$$
(2)
where \(epu\) and \({epu}^{*}\) are domestic and the US economic policy uncertainty, respectively. These two variables are also converted in natural log. According to the prior studies, it is expected that \({\beta }_{1}=1\), implying that if the domestic money supply increases relative to the US money supply, the exchange rate will proportionately increase. Similarly, if domestic income relatively increases or the domestic interest rate relatively decreases, the domestic demand for holding money will increase. Therefore, \({\beta }_{2}\) is likely to be negative and \({\beta }_{3}\) is likely to be positive.3 Moreover, domestic EPU and the US EPU are expected to have negative and positive effects on the exchange rate, respectively.
This study considers five developed countries and regions, namely, Canada, Euro, Japan, Sweden, UK, and seven developing countries, i.e., Brazil, Chile, China, India, Korea, Mexico, and Russia. The period covered in the study is from 2000:M1 to 2017:M2. The countries, regions and the period of this study have been selected based on the availability of data of the considered variables. Except for EPUs, the data of all variables is collected from International Financial Statistics (IFS) published by the IMF. The domestic and the US EPUs are news-based economic uncertainty measures developed by Baker et al. (2016). They are collected from the authors’ website.4
Equation (2) is estimated using the panel quantile regression model of Machado and Santos Silva (2019). One advantage of this method is that it does not rely on conditional means; it is based on the method of moments. Therefore, endogenous variables can be easily accommodated in this method. To check the robustness of the findings obtained from panel quantile regression, the linear and nonlinear ARDL models are employed. Both linear and nonlinear autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) models are estimated using Pesaran (2006). Shin et al. (2014) postulate the nonlinear ARDL model for time series analysis. However, after decomposing the policy variables in positive and negative cumulative sums, the linear ARDL model of Pesaran (2006) can be augmented in the asymmetric ARDL model (for instance, Eberhardt and Presbitero 2015; Salisu and Isah 2017). For estimating the nonlinear panel ARDL model, the domestic EPU is decomposed in the following way,
$$\begin{array}{l}epu_{i,t}^{pos} = \sum\limits_{j = 1}^t {\Delta epu_{i,j}^{pos}} = \sum\limits_{j = 1}^t m ax\left( {\Delta ep{u_{i,j}},0} \right)\\epu_{i,t}^{neg} = \sum\limits_{j = 1}^t {\Delta epu_{i,j}^{neg}} = \sum\limits_{j = 1}^t m in\left( {\Delta ep{u_{i,j}},0} \right)\end{array}$$
(3)
Analogously, the US EPU is decomposed as
$$\begin{array}{l}epu_t^{*pos} = \sum\limits_{i = 1}^t {\Delta epu_i^{*pos}} = \sum\limits_{i = 1}^t m ax\left( {\Delta epu_i^*,0} \right)\\epu_t^{*neg} = \sum\limits_{i = 1}^t {\Delta epu_i^{*neg}} = \sum\limits_{i = 1}^t m in\left( {\Delta epu_i^*,0} \right)\end{array}$$
(4)
After replacing \(epu\) and \({epu}^{*}\) by their positive and negative partial sums in Eq. (2), an asymmetric ARDL model is obtained, which is.
$$\begin{array}{l}{s_{i,t}} = {\gamma _0} + {\gamma _1}\left( {{m_{i,t}} - m_{i,t}^*} \right) + {\gamma _2}\left( {{y_{i,t}} - y_{i,t}^*} \right) + {\gamma _3}\left( {{i_{i,t}} - i_{i,t}^*} \right) + \\{\gamma _4}epu_{i,t}^{pos} + {\gamma _5}epu_{i,t}^{neg} + {\gamma _6}epu_{i,t}^{*pos} + {\gamma _7}epu_{i,t}^{*neg} + {\nu _{i,t}}\end{array}$$
(5)
Like Eq. (2), Eq. (5) is also estimated using Pesaran (2006). The statistical significance of the asymmetric effect is justified using the Wald test. However, the panel unit root tests of all the variables are estimated before going to the panel ARDL model. Using Herwartz and Siedenburg (2008), Demetrescu and Hanck (2012), and Herwartz et al. (2019) unit root tests, it is found that all variables are integrated of order 1.5

3 Analysis and discussion

Table 1 reports the method of moments quantile regression (MM-QR). The MM-QR shows that all macroeconomic variables of the monetary model are statistically significant, and hold expected signs for the overall economies. Income and interest rate differentials have an asymmetric effect on the exchange rates. The coefficients of these variables decline as they move to higher quantile. Like Abid (2020), it is found that domestic EPU adversely affects the exchange rate at each quantile. However, the asymmetric effect is not justified by the Wald test. Unlike domestic EPU, the US EPU has no significant impact on the exchange rates. Such outcomes may appear due to aggregation bias. After reexamining the model for developed and developing economies, it is found that domestic EPU negatively and the US EPU positively affect the exchange rates. Beckmann and Czudaj (2016) also find an instantaneous positive effect of the US EPU on the developed countries’ exchange rates.
The coefficients of both EPUs increase at higher quantiles. Hence, the asymmetric effects are significant. Notably, the impact of domestic EPU is larger than the US EPU at each quantile, i.e., the influence of domestic economic uncertainty is harsher than the foreign economic uncertainty in developed countries and regions.
In the case of developing countries, money supply and income differentials are significant and retain expected signs. However, the interest rate differentials are positive at lower quantiles and negative at higher quantiles. Higher interest rate differentials may lead to higher capital inflow in the economy (Dornbusch 1976; Frankel 1979). It may have a substantial influence on the domestic currencies of developing countries to be appreciated. Unlike developed economies, the EPUs significantly affect the exchange rate only at the lowest and highest quantiles in the developing countries. At the lowest quantiles \((\tau =0.1)\), the coefficients both domestic and the US EPUs are negative, while they are positive at the highest quantiles \((\tau =0.9)\).
The Wald test statistics show significant asymmetric effects of the EPUs on the exchange rates. In contrast to the developed countries and region, the coefficients of the US EPU exceed the coefficients of domestic EPU within the same quantiles, implying that the US economic uncertainty plays a dominant role in developing countries. Regarding the effects of economic uncertainty, Carrière-Swallow and Céspedes (2013) unveil that foreign uncertainty shocks’ spillover effect is severe on emerging economies than developed countries because of credit constraints.
To check the robustness of these findings, this study further estimates the linear and nonlinear ARDL models. According to Table 2, the extended monetary approach to exchange rates is mostly a long-run phenomenon. The money supply and income differentials are significant, and hold expected signs in the long run. The results are consistent with the MM-QR models. However, after considering nonstationary panels, the long-run coefficients of interest rate differentials of advanced economies become negative, implying that higher interest rate in advanced economies relative to the US interest rate attracts foreign investors to invest in these advanced economies and domestic investors retain themselves to invest in their own territory. Prior studies find that the interest rate differentials become an integral part of determining the international capital flow during high economic uncertainty.6
Table 1
Determination of nominal exchange rate using the method of moments-quantile regression (MM-QR)
Panel A: All Economies
Wald test for equality
at different quantiles
Variable
Quantile levels
 
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
0.5
0.9
\((m-{m}^{*})\)
0.834***
0.83***
0.826***
0.824***
0.821***
0.818***
0.815***
0.81***
0.802***
2.19
2.19
 
(0.011)
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.01)
(0.011)
(0.012)
(0.014)
(0.018)
  
\((y-{y}^{*})\)
-2.619***
-2.461***
-2.32***
-2.214***
-2.12***
-2.017***
-1.886***
-1.716***
-1.41***
20.73***
20.82***
 
(0.138)
(0.123)
(0.116)
(0.116)
(0.12)
(0.128)
(0.143)
(0.169)
(0.221)
  
\((i-{i}^{*})\)
0.651***
0.615***
0.583***
0.559***
0.538***
0.514***
0.484***
0.446***
0.376***
22.18***
22.28***
 
(0.03)
(0.027)
(0.025)
(0.025)
(0.026)
(0.028)
(0.031)
(0.037)
(0.049)
  
\(epu\)
-0.448***
-0.438***
-0.43***
-0.424***
-0.418***
-0.412***
-0.404***
-0.394***
-0.376***
0.47
0.47
 
(0.054)
(0.048)
(0.045)
(0.046)
(0.047)
(0.05)
(0.056)
(0.066)
(0.087)
  
\({epu}^{*}\)
-0.059
-0.058
-0.057
-0.056
-0.056
-0.055
-0.054
-0.053
-0.05
0.00
0.00
 
(0.081)
(0.072)
(0.068)
(0.068)
(0.07)
(0.075)
(0.084)
(0.098)
(0.129)
  
\(cons.\)
2.384***
2.781***
3.134***
3.399***
3.635***
3.895***
4.222***
4.648***
5.414***
18.38***
18.51***
 
(0.368)
(0.326)
(0.308)
(0.308)
(0.319)
(0.34)
(0.38)
(0.447)
(0.588)
  
Panel B: Developed Economies
Wald test for equality
at different quantiles
Variable
Quantile levels
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
0.5
0.9
\((m-{m}^{*})\)
0.8***
0.76***
0.723***
0.668***
0.636***
0.599***
0.565***
0.53***
0.497***
113.99***
130.50***
 
(0.02)
(0.018)
(0.017)
(0.016)
(0.015)
(0.016)
(0.017)
(0.018)
(0.019)
  
\((y-{y}^{*})\)
0.678
0.176
− 0.282
− 0.97**
-1.374***
-1.835***
-2.253***
-2.7***
-3.103***
25.33***
26.07***
 
(0.564)
(0.507)
(0.471)
(0.44)
(0.434)
(0.45)
(0.477)
(0.518)
(0.564)
  
\((i-{i}^{*})\)
0.475***
0.423***
0.376***
0.305***
0.264***
0.217***
0.174**
0.128
0.087
10.25***
10.37***
 
(0.092)
(0.083)
(0.076)
(0.071)
(0.071)
(0.073)
(0.078)
(0.085)
(0.092)
  
\(epu\)
0.019
− 0.171*
− 0.344***
− 0.604***
− 0.756***
− 0.93***
-1.088***
-1.257***
-1.409***
83.91***
92.54***
 
(0.111)
(0.1)
(0.095)
(0.091)
(0.087)
(0.09)
(0.095)
(0.102)
(0.11)
  
\({epu}^{*}\)
0
0.094
0.179
0.306***
0.381***
0.467***
0.544***
0.627***
0.702***
12.99***
13.18***
 
(0.148)
(0.133)
(0.122)
(0.114)
(0.113)
(0.117)
(0.125)
(0.136)
(0.148)
  
\(cons.\)
− 0.12
0.664
1.38***
2.455***
3.086***
3.805***
4.458***
5.157***
5.786***
46.30***
48.76***
 
(0.641)
(0.574)
(0.536)
(0.502)
(0.492)
(0.511)
(0.541)
(0.587)
(0.639)
  
Panel B: Developing Economies
Wald test for equality
at different quantiles
Variable
Quantile levels
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
0.5
0.9
\((m-{m}^{*})\)
0.849***
0.844***
0.841***
0.838***
0.835***
0.834***
0.832***
0.828***
0.818***
0.74
0.74
 
(0.023)
(0.019)
(0.017)
(0.016)
(0.015)
(0.015)
(0.016)
(0.017)
(0.025)
  
\((y-{y}^{*})\)
-2.998***
-2.453***
-2.124***
-1.834***
-1.488***
-1.348***
-1.154***
− 0.735***
0.321
77.77***
94.94***
 
(0.223)
(0.172)
(0.152)
(0.146)
(0.137)
(0.132)
(0.138)
(0.205)
(0.222)
  
\((i-{i}^{*})\)
0.562***
0.365***
0.246***
0.141***
0.016
− 0.035
− 0.105**
− 0.256***
− 0.638***
73.40***
89.02***
 
(0.083)
(0.064)
(0.057)
(0.055)
(0.051)
(0.049)
(0.052)
(0.076)
(0.083)
  
\(epu\)
− 0.188**
− 0.129*
− 0.093
− 0.062
− 0.025
− 0.01
0.011
0.056
0.17*
6.54**
6.65***
 
(0.087)
(0.072)
(0.064)
(0.06)
(0.058)
(0.058)
(0.06)
(0.067)
(0.095)
  
\({epu}^{*}\)
− 0.242*
− 0.159
− 0.108
− 0.064
− 0.011
0.011
0.04
0.104
0.266*
5.02**
5.08**
 
(0.141)
(0.116)
(0.105)
(0.098)
(0.095)
(0.095)
(0.097)
(0.109)
(0.154)
  
\(cons.\)
2.257***
2.364***
2.429***
2.486***
2.554***
2.582***
2.62***
2.703***
2.91***
0.40
0.40
 
(0.649)
(0.536)
(0.483)
(0.452)
(0.437)
(0.438)
(0.447)
(0.492)
(0.709)
  
Notes: (i) Figures in parentheses are standard errors. (ii) *, ** and *** denote the significance level at 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively, and (iii) the statistically significant Wald test results show that the estimated slope coefficients and intercepts for lower quantile \((\tau =0.1)\) are statistically different across medium \((\tau =0.5)\) and upper quantiles\((\tau =0.9)\)
Table 2
Panel ARDL model
Linear Long-run Coefficients
Nonlinear Long-run Coefficients
Coefficient
All
Developed
Developing
Coefficient
All
Developed
Developing
\((m-{m}^{*})\)
0.660***
0.248***
0.0127***
\((m-{m}^{*})\)
0.719***
0.0452***
-0.858***
 
(0.0026)
(0.0025)
(0.0027)
 
(0.0035)
(0.0044)
(0.0034
\((y-{y}^{*})\)
-1.582***
-1.532***
-1.457***
\((y-{y}^{*})\)
-1.537***
-1.444***
-0.866***
 
(0.0045)
(0.0072)
(0.0063)
 
(0.0044)
(0.0052)
(0.0064)
\((i-{i}^{*})\)
0.231***
-0.243***
0.909***
\((i-{i}^{*})\)
0.345***
-0.181***
0.666***
 
(0.0019)
(0.0009)
(0.0027)
 
(0.0020)
(0.0018)
(0.0029)
\(epu\)
1.195***
0.272***
1.151***
\({epu}^{pos}\)
1.211***
0.347***
0.919***
 
(0.0020)
(0.0026)
(0.0027)
 
(0.0020)
(0.0036)
(0.0022)
\({epu}^{*}\)
0.139***
0.198***
-0.236***
\({epu}^{neg}\)
1.234***
0.354***
0.826***
 
(0.0013)
(0.0024)
(0.0017)
 
(0.0021)
(0.0040)
(0.0025)
    
\({epu}^{*pos}\)
-0.104***
0.0511***
-0.297***
     
(0.0014)
(0.0033)
(0.0015)
    
\({epu}^{*neg}\)
-0.133***
0.0612***
-0.200***
     
(0.0015)
(0.0035)
(0.0015)
Linear Short-run Coefficients and the Speed of Adjustment
Nonlinear Short-run Coefficients and the Speed of Adjustment
Coefficient
All
Developed
Developing
Coefficient
All
Developed
Developing
\(ECM\)
-0.0045
-0.0124***
-0.0049
\(ECM\)
-0.0046
-0.0158**
-0.0078
 
(0.0034)
(0.0036)
(0.0067)
 
(0.0031)
(0.0059)
(0.0056)
\(\varDelta (m-{m}^{*})\)
0.1060
0.1510
0.0742
\(\varDelta (m-{m}^{*})\)
0.1070
0.1550
0.0698
 
(0.0919)
(0.1290)
(0.1370)
 
(0.0891)
(0.1250)
(0.1320)
\(\varDelta (y-{y}^{*})\)
-0.0073
0.0158**
-0.0201
\(\varDelta (y-{y}^{*})\)
-0.0072
0.0180***
-0.0194
 
(0.0092)
(0.0058)
(0.0137)
 
(0.0091)
(0.0044)
(0.0139)
\(\varDelta (i-{i}^{*})\)
0.0232
-0.0131
0.0531*
\(\varDelta (i-{i}^{*})\)
0.0241
-0.0146
0.0520*
 
(0.0185)
(0.0187)
(0.0240)
 
(0.0181)
(0.0160)
(0.0248)
\(\varDelta epu\)
0.0161
0.0329
0.0050
\({\varDelta epu}^{pos}\)
0.0928
0.2050
0.0080***
 
(0.0123)
(0.0303)
(0.0026)
 
(0.0864)
(0.2030)
(0.0024)
\(\varDelta {epu}^{*}\)
0.0073**
0.0009
0.0122***
\({\varDelta epu}^{neg}\)
-0.0640
-0.1540
0.0006
 
(0.0024)
(0.0031)
(0.0028)
 
(0.0650)
(0.1540)
(0.0032)
    
\({\varDelta epu}^{*pos}\)
0.0111***
0.0060
0.0154***
     
(0.0033)
(0.0056)
(0.0043)
    
\({\varDelta epu}^{*neg}\)
0.0021
-0.00630*
0.00779*
     
(0.0030)
(0.0028)
(0.0035)
Test of asymmetric effects
All
Developed
Developing
 
\(epu\)
\({epu}^{*}\)
\(epu\)
\({epu}^{*}\)
\(epu\)
\({epu}^{*}\)
\({\omega }^{LR}\)
6889***
22,971***
192***
873***
47,875***
26,273***
\({\omega }^{SR}\)
1.07
4.65**
1.01
2.76*
8.06***
1.93
Notes: ***, ** and * indicate 1%, 5% and 10% levels of significance, respectively. The parentheses values show the standard errors. Westerlund et al. (2019) proposed a fixed-T variance estimator that has been used for pooled coefficients in Pesaran (2006). This estimator corrects the heteroscedasticity problem and considers fixed time variance for panels
Furthermore, the linear ARDL model shows that domestic and the US EPUs depreciate domestic currencies of advanced economies in the long run. The nonlinear ARDL model also estimates positive coefficients positive and negative cumulative sums of EPUs, implying that the exchange rate always increases in the long run when domestic and the US economic uncertainties increase or decrease. Although these uncertainty coefficients hold the same sign, their magnitudes are statistically different according to the Wald test. Like the quantile regression, the ARDL models also show that the effect of domestic EPU is larger than the US EPU in the advanced economies. However, domestic EPU has no significant impact on the exchange rates in developed economies during the short run. In the short run, only the US EPU appreciates domestic currencies when the US EPU decreases. The Wald test reports that only the US EPU has an asymmetric effect on the exchange rate in the short run.
On the contrary to the advanced economies, the linear and nonlinear panel ARDL models for developing countries show that domestic EPU positively and the US EPU negatively affect the exchange rates in the long run. The Wald test justifies the asymmetric long-run effects of domestic and foreign EPUs on the exchange rate. In the short run, domestic EPU depreciates the domestic currencies of developing countries when the EPU increases. The foreign EPU positively impacts the exchange no matter whether the US EPU increases or decreases in the short run. However, the Wald test only supports the short-run asymmetric effect of domestic EPU. The adjustment parameters hold the expected sign and are also statistically significant only for advanced economies, and the value is higher in the nonlinear ARDL model.

4 Conclusions

This study attempts to extend the monetary model to exchange rates by encompassing the domestic and the US economic uncertainties. Relying on the monthly data of advanced and developing economies over 2000:M1 to 2017:M2, it is found that both domestic and foreign economic uncertainties significantly affect the equilibrium exchange rates, at least in the long run. In the case of advanced economies, the effect of domestic EPU exceeds the foreign EPU. In contrast, the foreign EPU is more influential in developing countries. Therefore, economic uncertainty may be considered as a ‘scapegoat’ in the model of Bacchetta and van Wincoop (2004, 2013). After considering the effects of economic uncertainty in the monetary model, all the macroeconomic variables are statistically significant, and hold expected signs in most cases. It supports Engel et al. (2008) findings that the monetary model still has explanatory power in determining exchange rates. According to the findings of this study, economic uncertainty emerges as an integral part of exchange rate determination. The notion would be more relevant in the post-Covid-19 era.
However, Caggiano et al. (2014) and Kido (2016) find the spillover effects of uncertainty shocks severe during the recessionary period. Therefore, this extended monetary model can be reinvestigated after considering economic recessions.

Declarations

Competing interests

I, hereby, declare that no support from any organization for the submitted work; no financial relationships with any organizations that might have an interest in the submitted work; no other relationships or activities that could appear to have influenced the submitted work.
Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Fußnoten
1
A comprehensive literature survey on COVID-19 and economic uncertainty can be found in Baker et al. (2020).
 
2
Bilson (1978) and Frankel (1979) are among the classic articles on the monetary approach to exchange rates. For a comprehensive literature survey including recent studies, see Xie and Chen (2019).
 
3
These hypotheses are derived from Bilson (1978). However, Dornbusch (1976) and Frankel (1979) argue that if interest rates differential rises, capital inflow will also increase in the domestic economy. Therefore, the interest rate differential and exchange rate are expected to move in opposite direction, i.e., \({\beta }_{3}\) is supposed to be negative.
 
4
For detail about the construction of EPU index and the database see www.​policyuncertaint​y.​com.
 
5
To save the space, the results of unit root test are not presented in the paper. However, the results are available from the author upon request.
 
6
However, numerous studies postulate that the interest rate differentials do not determine the international capital flow (Grubel 1968; Haynes 1988).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Abid A (2020) Economic policy uncertainty and exchange rates in emerging markets: Short and long runs evidence. Finance Res Lett 37:101378CrossRef Abid A (2020) Economic policy uncertainty and exchange rates in emerging markets: Short and long runs evidence. Finance Res Lett 37:101378CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Abid A, Rault C (2021) On the Exchange Rates Volatility and Economic Policy Uncertainty Nexus: A Panel VAR Approach for Emerging Markets. J Quant Econ 19:403–425CrossRef Abid A, Rault C (2021) On the Exchange Rates Volatility and Economic Policy Uncertainty Nexus: A Panel VAR Approach for Emerging Markets. J Quant Econ 19:403–425CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ahir H, Bloom N, Furceri D (2020) The World Uncertainty Index. ASSA 2020 Annual Meeting, January 3–5, San Diego, CA Ahir H, Bloom N, Furceri D (2020) The World Uncertainty Index. ASSA 2020 Annual Meeting, January 3–5, San Diego, CA
Zurück zum Zitat Bacchetta P, van Wincoop E (2004) A scapegoat model of exchange-rate fluctuations. Am Econ Rev 94:114–118CrossRef Bacchetta P, van Wincoop E (2004) A scapegoat model of exchange-rate fluctuations. Am Econ Rev 94:114–118CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bacchetta P, van Wincoop E (2013) On the unstable relationship between exchange rates and macroeconomic fundamentals. J Int Econ 91:18–26CrossRef Bacchetta P, van Wincoop E (2013) On the unstable relationship between exchange rates and macroeconomic fundamentals. J Int Econ 91:18–26CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Baker SR, Bloom N, Davis SJ, Terry SJ (2020) COVID-Induced Economic Uncertainty, Working Paper No. 26983, National Bureau of Economic Research Baker SR, Bloom N, Davis SJ, Terry SJ (2020) COVID-Induced Economic Uncertainty, Working Paper No. 26983, National Bureau of Economic Research
Zurück zum Zitat Baker SR, Bloom N, Davis SJ (2016) Measuring economic policy uncertainty. Q J Econ 131(4):1593–1636CrossRef Baker SR, Bloom N, Davis SJ (2016) Measuring economic policy uncertainty. Q J Econ 131(4):1593–1636CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Balcilar M, Gupta R, Kyei C, Wohar ME (2016) Does economic policy uncertainty predict exchange rate returns and volatility? Evidence from a nonparametric causality-in-quantiles test. Open Economic Review 27(2):229–250CrossRef Balcilar M, Gupta R, Kyei C, Wohar ME (2016) Does economic policy uncertainty predict exchange rate returns and volatility? Evidence from a nonparametric causality-in-quantiles test. Open Economic Review 27(2):229–250CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Beckmann J, Czudaj R (2017) Exchange rate expectations and economic policy uncertainty. Eur J Political Econ 47:148–162CrossRef Beckmann J, Czudaj R (2017) Exchange rate expectations and economic policy uncertainty. Eur J Political Econ 47:148–162CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bilson J (1978) The monetary approach to the exchange rate: some empirical evidence. IMF Staff Paper 25(1):48–75CrossRef Bilson J (1978) The monetary approach to the exchange rate: some empirical evidence. IMF Staff Paper 25(1):48–75CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bloom N, Floetotto M, Jaimovich N, Saporta-Eksten I, Terry S (2018) Really Uncertain Business Cycles Econometrica 86(3):1031–1065 Bloom N, Floetotto M, Jaimovich N, Saporta-Eksten I, Terry S (2018) Really Uncertain Business Cycles Econometrica 86(3):1031–1065
Zurück zum Zitat Bloom N (2009) The impact of uncertainty shocks. Econometrica 77(3):623–685CrossRef Bloom N (2009) The impact of uncertainty shocks. Econometrica 77(3):623–685CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bloom N (2014) Fluctuations in Uncertainty. J Economic Perspect 28:153–176CrossRef Bloom N (2014) Fluctuations in Uncertainty. J Economic Perspect 28:153–176CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bush G, López Noria G (2021) Uncertainty and exchange rate volatility: Evidence from Mexico. Int Rev Econ Finance 75:704–722CrossRef Bush G, López Noria G (2021) Uncertainty and exchange rate volatility: Evidence from Mexico. Int Rev Econ Finance 75:704–722CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Caggiano G, Castelnuovo E, Figueres JM (2017) Economic Policy Uncertainty and Unemployment in the United States: A Nonlinear Approach. Econ Lett 151:31–34CrossRef Caggiano G, Castelnuovo E, Figueres JM (2017) Economic Policy Uncertainty and Unemployment in the United States: A Nonlinear Approach. Econ Lett 151:31–34CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Caggiano G, Castelnuovo E, Groshenny N (2014) Uncertainty shocks and unemployment dynamics in US recessions. J Monet Econ 67:78–92CrossRef Caggiano G, Castelnuovo E, Groshenny N (2014) Uncertainty shocks and unemployment dynamics in US recessions. J Monet Econ 67:78–92CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carrière-Swallow Y, Céspedes LF (2013) The impact of uncertainty shocks in emerging economies. J Int Econ 90(2):316–325CrossRef Carrière-Swallow Y, Céspedes LF (2013) The impact of uncertainty shocks in emerging economies. J Int Econ 90(2):316–325CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chen L, Du Z, Hu Z (2020) Impact of economic policy uncertainty on exchange rate volatility of China. Finance Res Lett 32:101266CrossRef Chen L, Du Z, Hu Z (2020) Impact of economic policy uncertainty on exchange rate volatility of China. Finance Res Lett 32:101266CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Demetrescu M, Hanck C (2012) A simple nonstationary-volatility robust panel unit root test. Econ Lett 117:10–13CrossRef Demetrescu M, Hanck C (2012) A simple nonstationary-volatility robust panel unit root test. Econ Lett 117:10–13CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dornbusch R (1976) Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. J Polit Econ 84(6):1161–1176CrossRef Dornbusch R (1976) Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. J Polit Econ 84(6):1161–1176CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Eberhardt M, Presbitero AF (2015) Public debt and growth: heterogeneity and non-linearity. J Int Econ 97(1):45–58CrossRef Eberhardt M, Presbitero AF (2015) Public debt and growth: heterogeneity and non-linearity. J Int Econ 97(1):45–58CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Engel C, Mark NC, West KD (2007) Exchange Rate Models Are Not as Bad as You Think. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 22:381–441CrossRef Engel C, Mark NC, West KD (2007) Exchange Rate Models Are Not as Bad as You Think. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 22:381–441CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Frankel JA (1979) On the mark: a theory of exchange rates based on real interest differentials. Am Econ Rev 69(4):610–622 Frankel JA (1979) On the mark: a theory of exchange rates based on real interest differentials. Am Econ Rev 69(4):610–622
Zurück zum Zitat Grubel HG (1968) Internationally diversified portfolios: Welfare gains and capital flows. Am Econ Rev 58:1299–1314 Grubel HG (1968) Internationally diversified portfolios: Welfare gains and capital flows. Am Econ Rev 58:1299–1314
Zurück zum Zitat Handley K, Limão N (2017) Policy Uncertainty, Trade, and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for China and the United States. Am Econ Rev 107(9):2731–2783CrossRef Handley K, Limão N (2017) Policy Uncertainty, Trade, and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for China and the United States. Am Econ Rev 107(9):2731–2783CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hassett KA, Metcalf GE (1999) Investment with uncertain tax policy: does random tax policy discourage investment? Econ J 109:372–393CrossRef Hassett KA, Metcalf GE (1999) Investment with uncertain tax policy: does random tax policy discourage investment? Econ J 109:372–393CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Haynes SE (1988) Identification of interest rates and international capital flows. Rev Econ Stat 70(1):103–111CrossRef Haynes SE (1988) Identification of interest rates and international capital flows. Rev Econ Stat 70(1):103–111CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Herwartz H, Maxand S, Walle YM (2019) Heteroskedasticity-Robust Unit Root Testing for Trending Panels. J Time Ser Anal 40:649–664CrossRef Herwartz H, Maxand S, Walle YM (2019) Heteroskedasticity-Robust Unit Root Testing for Trending Panels. J Time Ser Anal 40:649–664CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Herwartz H, Siedenburg F (2008) Homogenous panel unit root tests under cross-sectional dependence: Finite sample modifications and the wild bootstrap. Comput Stat Data Anal 53:137–150CrossRef Herwartz H, Siedenburg F (2008) Homogenous panel unit root tests under cross-sectional dependence: Finite sample modifications and the wild bootstrap. Comput Stat Data Anal 53:137–150CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hossain AA, Arwatchanakarn P (2020) The effect of economic uncertainty on narrow money demand and its stability in New Zealand: An empirical investigation. Econ Anal Policy 68:88–100CrossRef Hossain AA, Arwatchanakarn P (2020) The effect of economic uncertainty on narrow money demand and its stability in New Zealand: An empirical investigation. Econ Anal Policy 68:88–100CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ivanovski K, Churchill SA (2019) Economic policy uncertainty and demand for money in Australia. Appl Econ 51(41):4516–4526CrossRef Ivanovski K, Churchill SA (2019) Economic policy uncertainty and demand for money in Australia. Appl Econ 51(41):4516–4526CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jo S, Sekkel. R (2019) Macroeconomic uncertainty through the lens of professional forecasters. J Bus Economic Stat 37(3):436–446CrossRef Jo S, Sekkel. R (2019) Macroeconomic uncertainty through the lens of professional forecasters. J Bus Economic Stat 37(3):436–446CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jurado K, Ludvigson SC, Ng S (2015) Measuring Uncertainty. Am Econ Rev 105(3):1177–1216CrossRef Jurado K, Ludvigson SC, Ng S (2015) Measuring Uncertainty. Am Econ Rev 105(3):1177–1216CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kido Y (2016) On the link between the US economic policy uncertainty and exchange rates. Econ Lett 144:49–52CrossRef Kido Y (2016) On the link between the US economic policy uncertainty and exchange rates. Econ Lett 144:49–52CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Krol R (2014) Economic Policy Uncertainty and Exchange Rate Volatility. Int Finance 17:241–256CrossRef Krol R (2014) Economic Policy Uncertainty and Exchange Rate Volatility. Int Finance 17:241–256CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Machado JAF, Santos Silva JMC (2019) Quantiles via moments. J Econ 213(1):145–173CrossRef Machado JAF, Santos Silva JMC (2019) Quantiles via moments. J Econ 213(1):145–173CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Murad SMW, Salim R, Kibria MG (2021) Asymmetric Effects of Economic Policy Uncertainty on the Demand for Money in India. J Quant Econ 19(3):451–470CrossRef Murad SMW, Salim R, Kibria MG (2021) Asymmetric Effects of Economic Policy Uncertainty on the Demand for Money in India. J Quant Econ 19(3):451–470CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nier E, Sedik TS, Mondino T (2014) Gross Private Capital Flows to Emerging Markets: Can the Global Financial Cycle be Tamed? IMF Working Paper, WP/14/196 Nier E, Sedik TS, Mondino T (2014) Gross Private Capital Flows to Emerging Markets: Can the Global Financial Cycle be Tamed? IMF Working Paper, WP/14/196
Zurück zum Zitat Pesaran MH (2006) Estimation and inference in large heterogeneous panels with a multifactor error structure. Econometrica 74(4):967–1012CrossRef Pesaran MH (2006) Estimation and inference in large heterogeneous panels with a multifactor error structure. Econometrica 74(4):967–1012CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Salisu AA, Isah KO (2017) Revisiting the oil price and stock market nexus: a nonlinear panel ARDL approach. Econ Model 66:258–271CrossRef Salisu AA, Isah KO (2017) Revisiting the oil price and stock market nexus: a nonlinear panel ARDL approach. Econ Model 66:258–271CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shin Y, Yu B, Greenwood-Nimmo M (2014) Modelling asymmetric cointegration and dynamic multipliers in a nonlinear ARDL framework. Festschrift in Honor of Peter Schmidt. Springer, New York, pp 281–314CrossRef Shin Y, Yu B, Greenwood-Nimmo M (2014) Modelling asymmetric cointegration and dynamic multipliers in a nonlinear ARDL framework. Festschrift in Honor of Peter Schmidt. Springer, New York, pp 281–314CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Westerlund J, Perova Y, Norkute M (2019) CCE in fixed-T panels. J Appl Econom 34:746–761CrossRef Westerlund J, Perova Y, Norkute M (2019) CCE in fixed-T panels. J Appl Econom 34:746–761CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Xie Z, Chen SW (2019) Exchange rates and fundamentals: A bootstrap panel data analysis. Econ Model 78:209–224CrossRef Xie Z, Chen SW (2019) Exchange rates and fundamentals: A bootstrap panel data analysis. Econ Model 78:209–224CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
The role of domestic and foreign economic uncertainties in determining the foreign exchange rates: an extended monetary approach
verfasst von
S. M. Woahid Murad
Publikationsdatum
06.07.2022
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Journal of Economics and Finance / Ausgabe 4/2022
Print ISSN: 1055-0925
Elektronische ISSN: 1938-9744
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-022-09589-5

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 4/2022

Journal of Economics and Finance 4/2022 Zur Ausgabe