Skip to main content
Erschienen in:
Buchtitelbild

Open Access 2023 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

Energy Poverty and Just Transformation in Greece

verfasst von : Panagiotis Fragkos, Eleni Kanellou, George Konstantopoulos, Alexandros Nikas, Kostas Fragkiadakis, Faidra Filipidou, Theofano Fotiou, Haris Doukas

Erschienen in: Vulnerable Households in the Energy Transition

Verlag: Springer International Publishing

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Low-income population groups often face high energy poverty risks. This phenomenon can be exacerbated through the implementation of ambitious environmental policies to achieve the energy transition—said policies, such as the application of additional taxes on energy products, may lead to regressive social and distributional impacts on low-income households thus increasing the risk of energy poverty. This study focusses on Greece and combines a qualitative analysis of the EU and Greek policy context and strategic framework for energy poverty as well as related poverty alleviation measures with a state-of-the-art model-based assessment of the equity and distributional impacts of the net-zero transition in the country. We use the GEM-E3-FIT general equilibrium model, expanded to represent ten income classes differentiated by income sources, saving rates and consumption patterns. The new modelling capabilities of GEM-E3-FIT are applied to quantify the distributional impacts of ambitious emission reduction targets and at the same time explore their effects on energy-related expenditure and energy poverty by income class in Greece. The country’s transition to climate neutrality increases modestly the income inequality across income classes, with low-income households facing the most negative effects. However, using carbon tax revenues as lump-sum transfers to support household income and as reduced social security contributions have the potential to boost employment and scale down income inequality in Greece.

1 Introduction

The European Union (EU) aims to become the world’s first climate-neutral continent by 2050 (European Commission 2019). The EU climate and energy framework, shaped by the “EU green deal”, the “Fit for 55 package” and the “Clean energy for all Europeans” initiatives, entails a 55% reduction of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions compared to 1990 levels; a 32% share of renewable energy consumption and 32.5% energy savings compared to 2005 levels. Buildings, and consequently households, responsible for 40 and 36% of the total energy consumed and CO2 emissions produced in EU respectively, play a key role to achieve these goals (European Commission 2019). Energy poverty remains a major challenge to be further addressed in the EU. In the effort to tackle it, protect vulnerable consumers, and thus create a just energy transition to climate neutrality, policy efforts have increased, and energy poverty is a key topic in the “Clean energy for all Europeans” package (European Commission 2019). The reduction and mitigation of energy poverty has also been increasingly targeted in energy efficiency, decarbonisation and clean energy policies. Member States through the submission of their NECPs (National Energy and Climate Plans) indicate all the measures intended to alleviate energy poverty. In Greece, where energy poverty is a major social issue and the country scores some of the highest percentages in the EU, policy measures should be a strategic priority.
Despite the attention that the phenomenon of energy poverty has been getting the last years, and especially through the energy crisis of 2021–2022, there have been limited efforts to quantify the distributional and energy poverty implications of the transition to climate neutrality by 2050, especially for the most vulnerable households. Scientific literature is fragmented and focuses mostly on case studies. As a result, it lacks a comprehensive evaluation of distributional impacts across income deciles.
This is the first study where quantified results of the distributional impacts towards net zero energy transition in Greece are presented. In essence, we study, first, the most applicable and important policy targets with a specific focus on energy poverty and the just transition (i.e., Fit for 55 package for 2030 and Climate neutrality by 2050). Then, we simulate the distributional impacts by income decile. This simulation is performed and is fully integrated in the comprehensive, rigorous CGE modelling framework. Last, we also analyse the most relevant measures to tackle income inequality, energy poverty and create a just transition framework. These include, among others, the use of carbon revenues to reduce inequality.
This chapter is organised as follows: the strategic framework for energy poverty in Greece is described in Sect. 2, while Sect. 3 presents the indicators and methodologies used to measure energy poverty. Section 4, in turn, focuses on the poverty alleviation measures in Greece. Section 5 analyses the implications of the European Green Deal on energy poverty and equity in Greece, using a state-of-the-art macroeconomic model enhanced with a representation of income deciles. Last, Sect. 6 provides policy recommendations while it also describes planned future work, and concludes this chapter.

2 Strategic Framework for Energy Poverty in Greece

2.1 EU Policy Context

The European Commission has designed advanced and ambitious policies to tackle energy poverty, committing to protect vulnerable households. In the 2019 “Clean Energy for All Europeans” package, energy poverty was set as one of the key energy policy priorities. Although each Member State is allowed to establish its own criteria for measuring and assessing energy poverty (Faiella and Lavecchia 2021), the need to use a common definition across Europe is well-established, to further facilitate the monitoring and mitigation of the situation—and so is the need to set clear objectives for energy poverty reduction in the National Energy and Climate Plans (NECPs) of each Member State (European Commission 2019). In addition, provisions for dealing with energy poverty have been introduced in a series of European directives.
Indicatively, Directive 2019/944/EU1 outlines the internal electricity market measures aiming at protecting vulnerable and energy-poor consumers in the context of the internal electricity market (social or energy policy measures to help pay electricity bills), launching investments to improve energy efficiency and/or protect consumers (including prohibition of disconnection of energy-poor consumers in critical periods), as well as providing measures other than public interventions in setting the prices for the supply of electricity. For the internal gas market, following up on Directive 2009/73/EE,2 Directive 2019/692/EE3 details provisions for protecting energy-vulnerable households and prohibiting their disconnection in critical periods. Targeting energy efficiency, Directive 2018/2002/EC4 outlines measures aimed at tackling energy poverty and lowering the vulnerability of consumers; while Directive 2018/844/EU,5 outlining the building energy performance framework and the long-term renovation strategy of the built environment, explicitly includes actions and measures to alleviate energy poverty among European households, according to criteria established by the Member States. Finally, Regulation 2018/1999/EU6 (Governance of the Energy Union and Climate Action) requires that consolidated NECPs of EU Member States include estimates of the number of energy-poor households, set a national target to mitigate energy poverty, and provide progress reports including the number of energy-poor households and the policy measures in place to address the issue.
It is, therefore, evident that energy poverty is high on the European Commission’s agenda, especially amidst an energy crisis that is partly driven by Covid-19 recovery efforts as well as the skyrocketing gas and electricity prices caused by changing demand–supply dynamics and by Russia’s invasion of Ukraine in 2022. The EU policy response included the REPowerEU strategy and national measures to reduce reliance on imported gas from Russia and protect vulnerable households from the rising energy prices. It also advocated for the adoption of behavioural changes that can boost energy efficiency. In particular, the proposed measures in the REPowerEU Plan include increasing the energy savings target (from 9 to 13% reduction in final energy consumption compared to the Reference 2020 Scenario), the diversification of the energy supply mix alongside the groundwork for a new “joint purchasing mechanism” for gas imports, accelerated roll-out of renewable energy to replace fossil fuels (upgrading the 2030 target from 40 to 45%), and reduction of fossil-fuel use in all sectors. To support the implementation of the REPowerEU Plan, additional smart investments are deemed necessary across all sectors and levels (national, cross-border and EU). In essence, REPowerEU means that Member States strengthen any national efforts and proactive measures they had kicked off in as early as September 2021 to mitigate the impacts of the looming energy crisis (Sgaravatti et al. 2021).

2.2 National Policy Context

The Greek energy policy framework comprises laws and regulations that are largely harmonised with most of the relevant EC directives and policy measures aiming at protecting vulnerable consumers and especially low-income households. However, much like delays in harmonising national and European energy efficiency legislation in Greece (Nikas et al. 2019), important EU directives (D2019/944/EU1, D2018/2002/EU4) have not yet been fully adopted in the national policy framework.
Nevertheless, significant progress has been made in defining the categories of vulnerable consumers (financially vulnerable, dependent on continuous and uninterrupted energy supply, elderly, people with health problems and residents of disadvantaged areas), whereas several policy measures have been enforced to protect vulnerable consumers, including:
  • the provision of reduced invoices, or a discount on each supplier's published invoices,
  • the installation of prepaid meters,
  • the provision of more favourable terms for paying the electricity and gas bills,
  • the adoption of alternative ways of accessing service and bill payment services,
  • the subsidisation of the electricity and fuel (oil, gas, biomass) consumption, and
  • the prohibition of disconnection of such consumers during critical periods.
In addition, criteria, and procedures for the inclusion of consumers in the above measures as well as obligations of energy providers/suppliers are defined. However, since an official definition for energy poverty at national level has not yet been established (Arsenopoulos et al. 2020) and, considering the lack of a common definition across the EU, identifying the energy-poor population in the country can be challenging.
In 2021, the Greek parliament approved the National Energy Poverty Alleviation Plan (NEPAP 2021), according to the NECP (2019) provision. The plan constitutes the Greek national strategy against energy poverty for 2021–2030 and aims to outline a comprehensive understanding of the situation by mapping and analysing the characteristics of the affected households, focused on those with the highest vulnerability. The NEPAP also proposes effective planning and implementation of the necessary policy measures to achieve the quantitative goals set within the framework of the Greek NECP for a reduction by at least 50% of its relevant energy poverty indicators by 2025, and by 75% by 2030, compared to 2016 (baseline year). Specifically, the Action Plan has been based on the identification of households affected by energy poverty using specific quantitative criteria; the development of a specialised process for recording, monitoring and evaluating the course of alleviating the phenomenon until 2030; the formulation of a well-defined set of policy measures to tackle energy poverty; the development of a mechanism for monitoring and evaluating the effects of each policy measure, to assess their effectiveness or need for adjustments; and the exploration of specific schemes to address energy poverty in vulnerable households either through existing policy measures or through new ones.

3 Measuring the Problem

3.1 The Diversity of Indicators to Identify and Measure Energy Poverty

There are three prevailing measurement methods to identify energy poverty, including (i) expenditure-based indicators that estimate the magnitude of energy poverty on a household by considering the household’s energy costs and income and comparing them to a selected threshold; (ii) consensual-based indicators, based on which inhabitants assess their household’s living conditions, regarding thermal comfort and other conditions (humidity, insulation, etc.), and their ability to afford expenditures required to secure healthy living conditions; and (iii) direct measurement, which sets a standard for an offered energy service (heating/cooling) and assesses energy poverty against this standard (Siksnelyte-Butkiene et al. 2021). However, Thomson and Snell (2016) suggest another measurement method to identify energy-poor households at local level, using welfare benefits, area-based approaches, demographic criteria or a mix thereof.
The first method used to measure energy poverty was the ten-percent rule proposed by Boardman in 1991. The ten-percent rule identifies as energy poor those households that spend on energy expenses more than 10% of their net income. The rule has been contested about its success to identify the phenomenon when other factors (e.g., energy efficiency, social factors, etc.) are considered. Other indices proposed to face the inadequacies of this rule include the Low Income-High Cost (Hills 2012) and the Minimum Income Standard indicator (Moore 2012). However, these are based on inflexible thresholds that are mostly theoretical, disregard actual energy costs and the equivalised ratio between income and energy-related expenditures or the difficulties in accounting different energy services (Tirado Herrero 2017).
Another approach on measuring energy poverty is that of Equivalisation of Modelled Energy Costs, proposed by Antepara et al. (2020) to face the problem of unreliable energy consumption data or behavioural practices due to socio-economic factors that may modify domestic energy use patterns. This methodology models energy bills on building energy conditions and consumption patterns and relates them to socio-demographic weighted (equivalised) variables.
To integrate more aspects, several multidimensional energy poverty indices have been established in the literature (e.g., Nussbaumer et al. 2012; Bersisa 2019; Ntaintasis et al. 2019; Crentsil et al. 2019). One of the first attempts to introduce composite indicators was that from Healy and Clinch (2002), who used 6 subjective indicators. Recently, Delugas and Brau (2018) identified energy poverty as a factor of wellbeing, Gouveia et al. (2019) combined energy performance with social and economic indicators, while Sokolowski et al. (2020) combined five quantitative (monetary) and qualitative (non-monetary) indicators, aiming to address limitations of previous single- or multi-dimensional indices.
To measure energy poverty at the European level, the EU Energy Poverty Advisory Hub (EPAH) has proposed several different indicators, four primary and nineteen secondary.7 The primary indicators comprise the shares of the (sub-) population that delay paying utility bills and that cannot keep their home sufficiently warm, calculated on the basis of answers to closed-ended questions (EUSilc); as well as household income and energy expenditure (with data from Household Budget Surveys—HBS)—e.g., energy expenses being more than twice the national average household income. However, caution is advised regarding structural differences in energy expenditure among households, situations where energy is often—albeit not exclusively—included in rent, and high energy efficiency standards or considerable underconsumption of energy. The secondary indicators include average prices paid by a household per kWh from district heating or generated from specific components such as fuel oil, biomass, and coal; electricity and gas prices for different types of consumers; energy consumption expenditure on electricity, gas, and other fuels as a share of income for 5 income quintiles; accommodation-related indicators such as average number of rooms per person in owned, rented, and all dwellings; location (densely populated or intermediate residential area); dwelling condition (leakage, dampness, or rot); and people at risk of poverty or social exclusion or death in winter.
The 2030 framework of the Covenant of Mayors also commits to contributing to energy poverty alleviation,8 based on six classes of indicators: climate, facilities/housing, mobility, socio-economic aspects, policy and regulatory framework and participation/awareness-raising. The climate category includes the energy consumption for space heating and cooling a building and the frequency of hot and cold waves per month each year. Facilities or housing indicators leverage various data that may be available at the municipal level—e.g., on buildings, households, etc. This data may include energy consumption such as the percentage of municipal energy consumption per capita over national energy consumption per capita, or information on the living conditions such as the percentage of population/households with leakage, dampness, or rot in their dwelling, the percentages of households/individuals experiencing discomfort in heating or cooling and those connected to the electricity or gas grid. Indicators also report systems for heating and cooling, e.g., central heating, oil boilers, wood boilers, conventional gas boilers and central cooling systems. There also exist indicators relating to the energy efficiency of buildings, specifically for categories F, G, H, the percentages of buildings refurbished each year that have an Energy Performance Certificate (EPC) higher than B. In addition, there are assessments on occupants, social housing flats to total flats, and social housing energy demand of the national median demand. Finally, this category is completed by indicators relating to the share of households with absolute energy expenditure above a defined share of the national average, considering the average age of buildings by period of construction, and the ratio of households/individuals relying primarily on clean fuels and related technology. The mobility category includes indicators focusing on public transport (distance to nearest station, frequency of transit to serve the public, household access to essential services by foot, bicycle, or public transport, share of social housing households without easy access to public transport and of households receiving support to pay for public transport services). Socio-economic indicators include unemployment, inability to keep the house sufficiently warm or cool, money spent on electricity or gas consumption, citizens’ spending on energy services compared to their income and national average, arrears on utility bills, age, education level, household situation (vulnerability, poverty and at-risk-of-poverty, state aid, and GDP- or income-based indicators). Policy and regulatory indicators report on the status of energy poverty strategy, incentives for owner schemes, rent regulation and specific energy-poverty policy measures. Finally, participation/awareness-raising refers to the existence of a deterrent to rent increases due to energy retrofits, and engagement and cooperation with local actors on energy poverty.

3.2 Measuring Energy Poverty in Greece

Among the several methodological approaches for identifying energy-poor households, the Hellenic Ministry of Environment and Energy has selected the 4 EPAH indicators to make an initial assessment of the situation in the country (NEPAP 2021). The Centre of Renewable Energy Sources and Saving (CRES), in charge of the National Observatory of Energy Poverty, has proposed an additional indicator, namely the coverage of basic energy needs per household, calculated as the ratio of actual recorded energy consumption to theoretically required energy consumption for specific uses; particular attention is paid at how required household energy uses are determined.
In the context of the NEPAP (2021), it is desirable to identify energy-poor households through a combined multi-dimensional index, which considers as many factors as possible, as proposed by Directive 2019/944/EU1 (and related to income, purchasing costs of energy products, and energy efficiency of residential buildings). Finally, an additional indicator, I&IIeq, is also included to target the households that simultaneously meet both of the following requirements:
  • the annual cost of the total household’s energy is lower than 80% of the annual cost to cover the minimum required energy consumption (Condition I), and
  • the equivalised net income of each household (based on the equivalent number of household’s members according to the OECD scale) on an annual basis is lower than the 60% of the median of the corresponding income for all households according to the definition of relative poverty (Condition IIeq).
According to the I&IIeq indicator’s initial calculation, the percentage of affected households in 2016 amounted to 14% of all households (approximately 573,000 households). The latest progress report,9 issued in 2021, calculates the I&IIeq at about 12% (approximately 497 thousand households). Continuous evaluation of this indicator to measure energy poverty is a priority, in order to make adjustments to policy measures and regulations as needed according to new scientific evidence on the factors that impact energy poverty.

4 Energy Poverty Alleviation Measures in Greece

National efforts to deal with the situation in Greece follow the NECP (2019) and NEPAP (2021) provisions. Actions are promoted towards three axes: consumer protection (financial support to households affected by extreme conditions of energy poverty, and protection through regulatory measures), energy efficiency and RES diffusion (financing measures with long-term impact, such as improvement of deep building renovations, energy efficiency improvements and increased use of Renewable Energy Sources), and informative and training actions for affected consumers and professionals of energy saving actions. All actions that have been implemented or are currently in place today are listed in Table 1.
Table 1
Energy poverty alleviation measures in Greece
Name
Description
Beneficiaries
Put in force
In place as of fall 2022
Social Household Tariff
Special tariff to reduce electricity prices for vulnerable households, provided by all electricity providers, since 2011. The subsidy is provided for a certain amount of energy (kWh) per month and is higher for energy-poor households
Vulnerable & energy-poor households
2011
Yes
Solidarity Services Tariff
Tariff of reduced cost, applicable to public legal entities and NGOs, who provide social care services, provided by all electricity suppliers
Legal entities and NGOs on social care sector
2013
Yes
Heating allowance
A heating allowance to households for consumption of subsidised types of heating fuels or thermal energy, due to increases in the final price of specific energy products; in 2021, biomass (firewood, pellets) was added to fossil fuels. The allowance is given according to defined criteria (income, place of residence, etc.)
Vulnerable & energy-poor households
2012
Yes
Electricity allowance—PowerPass
Subsidy of electricity bills to consumers with variable tariffs, starting in 2022 amidst the energy price spikes following gas supply cut-offs associated with (policy responses to) Russia’s invasion in Ukraine. Its amount and beneficiaries are determined by the government based on social and economic criteria
All energy consumers
2022
Yes
Replacement of old, energy-consuming electrical appliances (Recycle-Replace appliance)
A 2022 subsidy for replacing old, high-consuming electrical appliances (air conditioners, refrigerators, and freezers) with new, more efficient ones. The subsidy is higher for low-income households
All households
2022
Yes
Horizontal electricity subsidy
A subsidy provided by the “Energy Transition Fund” to support electricity end-users. It is applied to all consumers without exception, regardless of income or other property criteria (households, businesses, etc.). The amount of the subsidy per MWh varies by type of consumer's tariff and consumption and is increased for energy-poor households
All energy consumers
2022
Yes
Horizontal gas subsidy
A subsidy provided to all gas consumers (households and businesses) to support them against the increased gas prices. The subsidy is applied to all consumers without exception, regardless of income or other property criteria, and it is foreseen to cover 50% of the last year increases. The subsidy size per MWh varies according to the consumer's tariff
All gas consumers
2022
Yes
Biomass grant
A grant dedicated to the supply of firewood to citizens residing in mountainous areas, supporting them to cover part of their winter needs for biomass. The implementation of the action is promoted collectively or individually and is supervised by the relevant forestry authority per geographical area
Citizens of mountainous municipalities
2022
Yes
Fast-track reconnections
One-off special aid (only for 2021) to support low-income consumers, who have been disconnected from the electricity supply network due to arrears. The purpose of the allowance is to enable them to submit a reconnection request and grant them a fast-track reconnection even if the arrears remain
Extreme energy-poor households
2021
No
Regulatory package
Measures for the protection of vulnerable electricity/gas consumers that bind all energy providers through the Supply Code Amendment. The measures include an extension of the deadline (to at least forty days) for paying the bill and flexible facilitation in the payment methods, suspension of supply cuts due to arrears during the winter and summer periods, strict conditions for contract termination, etc
Vulnerable & energy-poor households
2016
Yes
Households Energy retrofits subsidies
Increased funding from financing tools for retrofitting interventions aimed at houses of low energy efficiency, belonging to low-income citizens that are unable to afford all residence upgrade expenses. The interventions concern deep renovations of the buildings, installation of efficient, low-carbon heating and cooling systems (e.g., heat pumps), and installation of RES technologies with storage
All households
2011
Yes
Tax deduction for renovation costs
Taxpayers implementing building renovations that include energy efficiency interventions can use this incentive to reduce their final tax. 40% of the cost of the works is deducted from the annual taxable income (spread to a period of 4 years)
Citizens
2021
Yes
“Save-Renovate for Young People”
A subsidy to homeowners (aged 18 to 39) of up to 90% for energy efficiency interventions and 30% for renovation works to their residence
All citizens aged 18 to 39
2022
No
Support of Just Transition Plan to Coal regions
Interventions foreseen for 10,000 vulnerable households, especially in the areas covered by the Just Transition Plan. Financial support is provided for the radical renovation of homes, with a subsidy of up to 90%, in combination with the installation of RES systems. The establishment of energy communities to address energy poverty is also foreseen
All households within the Coal Regions
2021
Yes
Energy communities
Actions to support vulnerable consumers and address citizens’ energy poverty through the scheme of energy communities (Energy Communities 2018). Indicative measures include renewable energy supply or use of virtual net metering, communication activities, home energy retrofits, or other relevant actions that reduce energy consumption for vulnerable homes
All households and energy consumers
2018
Yes
Implementation of technical and/or behavioural measures (Energy efficiency obligation schemes)
Energy businesses (fuel and energy service providers, electricity suppliers etc.) are obliged to contribute to national energy saving and efficiency targets by using their own capital to promote technical and/or behavioural support to (vulnerable) households
Measures taken to support energy-poor households provide them with a premium coefficient on calculating achieved energy savings
Modifications are expected to cover large-scale interventions
All households
2017
Yes
Net-metering subsidy
A subsidy provided to at least 250,000 roofs PV units for net-metering expansion. Beneficiaries include households and small businesses in urban and rural areas, covering (part of) their electricity needs through solar energy. The subsidy is intended to cover 40–60% of the investment
Households and small businesses in rural and urban areas
Expected in 2022
No
Energy poverty alleviation subsidy for municipal actions through energy communities
Subsidies to municipal and regional authorities to establish energy communities and install RES units to support vulnerable consumers and mitigate energy poverty in their citizens. The subsidy is intended to cover up to 100% of the costs of setting up the Energy Communities and implementing the relevant investments
Vulnerable and energy-poor households
Expected in 2022
No
Communication and education
Provision of targeted communication and training actions for affected households, and of professionals involved in supporting these households (facilitation practices for covering energy costs, awareness on existing protection measures, availability of financing to improve energy efficiency, etc.)
Energy poor and vulnerable households, Professionals
Expected in 2022
No
Price Comparison Tool of energy products
A platform for comparing prices and terms of tariffs offered by electricity and natural gas providers. Complaints and requests to network operators and electricity/gas service providers can be accepted, with monitoring of the progress of said request
All energy consumers
2020
Yes
Source Authors’

5 Implications of the European Green Deal on Energy Poverty and Equity

This section aims to analyse the accruing impacts if the EU implements the Fit-for-55 target of reducing its greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions by at least 55% in 2030, compared to 1990 levels, and then achieves the goal of climate neutrality by 2050. This requires the adoption of strong climate policies (e.g., high carbon pricing) to drive a complete restructuring of the EU and Greek energy system towards renewable energy technologies, clean fuels and energy efficiency improvements. However, high carbon pricing would entail large-scale economic restructuring directly impacting the production, demand and competitiveness of different sectors. The decarbonisation of the energy system is not expected to impact uniformly all sectors of the economy, with large reductions expected in carbon-intensive activities, such as mining/extraction, refineries and fossil-based power generation. These changes in the structure of energy-economic systems will be accompanied by changes in fuel and electricity prices as well as changes in financing requirements: the purchase and operation of energy and electrical equipment/appliances will change with increasing capital expenditures (CAPEX) and lower operating and fuel purchase expenditures (OPEX).
The implications of decarbonisation on economic systems are manifested via large changes in capital and labour markets, which in turn impact the activities of all economic agents. Strong carbon pricing may also cause regressive distributional impacts, disproportionately affecting disadvantaged population groups that face high energy expenditures as a share of their income combined with difficulties in accessing low-cost funding. The imposition of additional taxes on energy products would increase the risk of energy poverty along with other challenges that low-income households in Greece and the EU face.
The analysis in this section is based on the state-of-the-art GEM-E3-FIT model, a computable general equilibrium (CGE) model for assessing the implications of energy and climate policies. Typically, general equilibrium models feature a single representative household in each national economy that averages incomes and consumption patterns. However useful when large-scale modelling is required, this aggregation may mask critical insights regarding social and distributional implications of climate policies among diverse households; distributional impacts refer to how costs and benefits of a policy or sets of policies are distributed among different regions, sectors, and households. Ignoring such distributional effects in climate policymaking may result in regressive distributional impacts and increased societal inequalities due to the lack of measures to mitigate negative impacts on vulnerable population groups. For this reason, GEM-E3-FIT is further expanded to represent ten household income classes in EU Member States, to consistently capture the potential distributional impacts of ambitious energy and climate policies for Greece until 2050 (a detailed description of the model expansion can be found in Fragkos et al. 2021).

5.1 Inequality and Energy Poverty Indicators

Rising income inequality is a global concern, implying that economic growth is not inclusive and its benefits are not equally distributed to all households (EC 2017). Income inequality can reduce economic growth, while raising concerns about sustainable growth, as the gap between rich and poor widens (EC 2018b). Income inequality is defined as inequality in earnings received from employment, private income from investments and property, transfers between households, state benefits, pensions and rent (UN 2015).
There has been considerable debate on the drivers of income inequality (IMF 2015), which typically include:
  • changes in labour market, which directly impact unemployment and the distribution of wages—e.g., part-time and temporary employment, gender gap, workers with low labour skills who are commonly the first to be substituted (OECD 2011)
  • labour institutions, which may lead to reduced wage dispersion (IMF 2015)
  • technological change, which increases productivity and well-being but requires higher skilled labour contributing to increased inequality—e.g., digitisation and automation changing occupational structures with replacement of routine-based jobs (OECD 2011)
  • trade globalisation, which tends to widen the income gap, negatively influencing the wages of unskilled labour despite trade increasing competitiveness and efficiency, thereby boosting economic growth (IMF 2015)
  • financial globalisation, which facilitates efficient international allocation of capital but can also aggravate income inequality, since foreign direct investments are mostly directed to technology development, increasing demand for high-skilled workers (Furceri and Loungani 2013)
  • education, which determines occupational choice, access to jobs, and the level of wages (Stiglitz and Greenwald 2014);
  • redistributive policies, with tax and transfer systems playing a major role in income equality, with types of taxes and socially security contribution having different impacts on inequality (OECD 2012)
  • household composition and ageing population (Bubbico and Freytag 2018),
  • distribution of wealth, as return on capital is a large source of households’ income (Piketty 2014; Cagetti and De Nardi 2008).
Most of these drivers are featured in GEM-E3-FIT modelling framework, including:
  • a detailed representation of the labour market with endogenous involuntary unemployment for five different occupation and skill types
  • endogenous technological change through learning by doing and learning by R&D, particularly for low-carbon technologies
  • a detailed representation of ten income classes through multiple households
  • endogenous bilateral trade of goods and services
  • an endogenous representation of human capital development and the decision of households for education enabling an upgrade of skills
  • a detailed representation of direct and indirect taxes, subsidies and other benefits
Table 2 includes the most common indicators to measure income inequality. The Gini coefficient is the most established and popular indicator, while the decile dispersion ratio presents the ratio of the average income of two deciles. However, this indicator does not use information about the distribution of income within deciles and does not provide information about incomes in the middle of the distribution. Other indicators have been developed to improve understanding about income distribution, e.g., the Generalised Entropy family (e.g., the Theil index) and the Atkinson index.
Table 2
Indicators to measure income inequality
Indicator
Description/relevance for inequality
Mean and median income by household
The mean income is the amount obtained by dividing the total aggregate income of a group by the number of units. The median is the income level that divides the population into two groups of equal size. The use of the median corrects potential distortion that may be caused by the existence of extreme values
Decile dispersion ratio
This measure presents the ratio of the average income of e.g., the richest 10% of the population divided by the average income of the poorest 10% (Haughton and Khandker 2009). The indicator is vulnerable to extreme values and outliers
S80/S20 income quintile share ratio or 20:20 ratio
Comparing the income received by the top 20% of the population with the bottom 20% of the population
Gini coefficient
The Gini coefficient is based on the Lorenz curve, a cumulative frequency curve that compares the distribution of income with the uniform distribution that represents equality. It represents the extent to which the distribution of income differs between an equal distribution (Gini coefficient of 0) and perfect inequality (Gini coefficient of 1)
Atkinson index
This index is based on the Gini index and includes a sensitivity parameter, which can range from 0 (meaning indifference about the nature of the income distribution), to infinity (where the focus is on the lowest income group) (De Maio 2007)
At-risk poverty rate
The share of people with an equivalised disposable income below the at-risk-of-poverty threshold, which is set at 60% of the national median equivalised disposable income (Eurostat 2019)
Severely and materially deprived
It reflects the inability of a household to afford some goods and services considered to be necessary for an adequate life (Eurostat 2019). The indicator measures the share of population that cannot afford three (material deprivation) or four (severe material deprivation) of the nine items listed in a reference year
Source Authors’
The analysis of distributional impacts focuses on the income changes between deciles. The indicators of income inequality can be estimated using a combination of modelling results, and additional income data. This chapter focuses on the Gini coefficient and the Decile Dispersion ratio (S80/S20), as these indicators complement each other.10
Extreme poverty and income inequality have decreased globally after 2000, largely owing to the decrease in inequality between countries (Revenga and Dooley 2019). In 2020, the Gini coefficient for the EU was 30.0, compared to 30.2 in 2010, showcasing stability in income inequality. Bulgaria has the highest Gini coefficient, while the lowest inequality in the EU is observed in Belgium, Finland, Czech Republic, Slovenia and Slovakia (Eurostat 2019). Greece registers a value close to the European average, with signs of inequality reduction in the last decade (the Gini coefficient declined from 32.9 in 2010 to 31.4 in 2020). In 2020, the EU-28 S80/S20 ratio was 4.9, implying that the richest 20% of the population receives about five times higher income relative to the poorest 20%. This share has been stable in the 2010s. Greece ranks slightly higher than the EU average, but with clear signs of reducing inequalities, with the S80/S20 indicator declining from 5.61 in 2010 to 5.23 in 2020.
A combination of energy-inefficient housing and appliances, high energy prices and low-income levels typically determine if a household is at risk of energy poverty (Pye et al. 2015; Gouveia et al. 2019). Our study focuses on expenditure-based indicators to assess energy poverty dynamics that can be quantified using GEM-E3-FIT model outcomes on energy expenditure and income per decile, in particular the share of energy expenditure in income (2 M). This indicator measures the share of households, whose share of energy expenditure relative to their disposable income is more than twice the national median share. The highest income group has a very low share of households in energy poverty (Bouzarovski et al. 2020, as the richer a household is, the lower the share of income is dedicated to energy expenditure. The proportion of households whose share of energy expenditure in income is more than twice the national median share is estimated at 16.2% in 2015 in the EU, with Greece being very close to the EU average (Fig. 1). However, this hides remarkable differences across income deciles in Greece, with more than half of those in the first decile facing substantial energy poverty risks.11

5.2 Modelling Income Inequality and Energy Poverty with GEM-E3-FIT

Macroeconomic models enhanced with a representation of different socio-economic groups (e.g., income classes) can be used to evaluate the distributional implications of climate policies. Despite the challenges in terms of data integration and computational modelling issues, the introduction of multiple households enhances the capability of conventional macroeconomic models to assess income distribution effects (Zhang 2019). The representation of multiple households in CGE modelling has been long established (Cockburn 2001; Rutherford et al. 2005; Balasko and Tourinho 2014) but is usually constrained by limited data availability. There are ways to differentiate households, but income class is the most relevant for distributional analysis. The main caveat of this approach is that it does not capture inequality within the income deciles and the fact that households can switch deciles and change compositions (CPB 2011).
GEM-E3-FIT is multiregional, multi-sectoral, recursive-dynamic, providing details on the macroeconomy and its complex interactions with the environment and the energy system. The model has been recently enhanced with a representation of ten income classes aiming to assess the distributional implications of climate policies. It simultaneously represents 46 regions (including the EU countries individually) and 53 activities linked through bilateral trade flows and runs until 2050 (E3Modelling 2017). It covers the interlinkages between productive sectors, consumption, labour and capital, bilateral trade, investment dynamics and price formation of commodities. GEM-E3-FIT formulates the supply and demand behaviour of economic agents that are assumed to exhibit optimising behaviour while market-derived prices are adjusted to clear markets. It allows for a consistent comparative analysis of policy scenarios as it ensures that the economic system remains in general equilibrium.
Industries operate within a perfect competition market regime and maximise profits, considering the possibilities of input substitutions between capital, labour, energy and materials. Household demand, savings and labour supply are derived from utility maximisation using a linear expenditure system (LES) formulation. Households receive income from labour supply and from holding shares in companies. Investment by sector is dynamic, depending on adaptive anticipation of capital return and activity growth by sector. A distinctive feature of GEM-E3-FIT (Fig. 2) is the representation of imperfect labour markets through involuntary unemployment, simulated by an empirical labour supply equation that links wages and unemployment levels for five labour skills.
Various policy instruments can be represented in GEM-E3-FIT, including energy and climate measures, and their interactions with policies related to labour market, economy, trade and innovation. Policies are evaluated based on their impact on sectoral growth, income distribution, employment, economic competitiveness and GDP. GEM-E3-FIT can assess the impacts of market-oriented policy instruments, such as carbon taxes and pollution permits, and investigate market-driven structural changes. It can analyse policy impacts in the allocation of capital, income, trade and labour, and provide insights on compensating measures aiming at alleviating adverse distributional effects among and within countries.
The representation of multiple households in CGE models is a challenging task both from a computational and data point of view (Zhang 2019). In the current study, this is implemented with a linkage of the CGE GEM-E3-FIT model with a satellite module with multiple households, through a sequential exchange of prices, incomes and demands until an equilibrium point is established (Rutherford and Tarr 2004; Rausch et al. 2011). This approach is easier to implement in large-scale CGE models with manageable computational complexity (compared to the hard-link approach) and it is thus adopted in GEM-E3-FIT. This was driven by the empirical findings of Rutherford and Tarr (2004), who showed very limited benefits from using the hard-link representation compared to the sequential approach. Considering the large geographic and sectoral granularity of the model and the need for short running time, we adopted the soft-link approach in the current study. The methodology is described in detail by Fragkos et al. (2021).
The equivalised disposable income by decile is used to calculate inequality indicators, but GEM-E3-FIT produces total disposable income by decile. The estimation of equivalised disposable income can be implemented by assuming that the equivalised household size by decile remains constant over 2015–2050 combined with a simplified assumption about the number of households by decile. GEM-E3-FIT results on income by decile can be used to quantify the Gini coefficient, by estimating 10 points of the Lorenz curve, each one representing an income decile group. The area under the Lorenz curve can be calculated by summing the areas of the 10 trapeziums, allowing to estimate the Gini coefficient as equal to the area below the line of perfect equality minus the area calculated below the Lorenz curve divided by the area below the line of perfect equality (0.5). The decile dispersion indicators (S80/S20 ratio) can be directly estimated via the income by decile quantified by GEM-E3-FIT. The disposable income of the last two and first two decile groups is utilised to calculate the S80/S20 indicator using GEM-E3-FIT results.
The “share of energy expenditure in income” indicator is used to identify energy poverty and can be estimated using the decile’s total energy expenditure and total disposable income. However, this indicator requires information on the distribution of absolute energy expenditures and incomes on household level to derive changing median values. GEM-E3-FIT cannot provide the median of these indicators; thus, we estimate only an adjusted 2 M indicator using the model output (i.e., the average share of energy expenditure in income by decile). While this approach does not reflect the unequal distributions within a decile, it provides insights regarding the economic burden of energy-related expenses on household budgets. In the analysis below, two indicators are used to measure the impacts of decarbonisation by decile group, namely “the share of energy expenditure for fuels and electricity in household income” (Indicator 1) and “the share of energy expenditure for fuels/electricity and energy equipment in household income (Indicator 2)”.
The integration of multiple households in GEM-E3-FIT requires data for disaggregating household expenditure by product category and income class, household earnings by branch and income class and data for calculating energy poverty indicators. Two key data sources are used: the EU Survey on Income and Living Conditions (SILC) and the Household Budget Survey (HBS).12 We use SILC data for disaggregating income sources and HBS data for detailing household consumption and calculating expenditure-based energy poverty indicators. Income and expenditure disaggregation are based on the micro data on an average per-household level and per-income decile. Data for each country and for each income decile is extracted from the SILC and HBS microdata for the latest available year, including data for the structure of population (e.g., number and size of households, occupation), income (income sources per occupation, benefits, transfers, allowances, dividends and property income and saving rates), expenditures (taxes, transfers and consumption per purpose) and indicators on energy poverty and income inequality. It should be noted that the model-based development and data analysis is conducted at muti-regional pan-European level (with a focus on Greece) as other European countries influence the national Greek economy through various modelling channels, including international trade, technology innovation capital and labour transfers.
Income deciles are constructed using national household sample weights included in the HBS dataset and each household in the dataset is assigned to a decile. Subsequently, average expenditures of households within each decile by Classification of Individual Consumption by Purpose (COICOP) category are calculated, using sample weights to obtain the actual distribution in the population. For energy expenditure and net income, standard deviations and skewness by income decile are calculated in the same way. To calculate the average share of energy expenditure in household income by decile, household energy expenditures are divided by incomes. Then, weighted averages, standard deviations and skewness by country and income decile were calculated, using household sample weights. Data for other variables are extracted from the SILC database: total gross and disposable incomes, decile-specific top cut-off points, standard deviations, skewness, income per occupation (ISCO-88), tax payments, income from other sources: various household and personal-level benefits and transfers, interests, properties and pensions.
Two key data-related challenges have emerged: the first relates to data structure that represents how individuals are nested in households, and the second to GEM-E3-FIT representing only household income. As household-level information is key to macroeconomic modelling, we assigned household-level income deciles to individuals for calculating resulting per-capita averages and per-decile totals. For most variables, macro-level data published by Eurostat cannot be replicated and thus Eurostat data is used for calculating the respective shares.

5.3 Scenario Design

The Reference (REF) scenario is a projection of the future evolution of the global economic and energy system based on existing trends, exogenous assumptions and scientific expertise on specific fields. Socio-economic developments replicate IEA assumptions (IEA 2019) and are consistent with the SSP2 scenario widely used by the IPCC. For the EU, socio-economic assumptions are based on the Ageing Report of the European Commission (EC 2018a, 2018b). The scenario assumes that already adopted climate policies and pledges, including the Nationally Determined Contributions (NDCs), are implemented by 2030. After 2030, no additional emission reduction effort is assumed, implying that the carbon prices resulting from NDCs in 2030 are kept constant until 2050. The costs of power generation and other energy technologies are calibrated to IRENA (2020), while technology progress is included for low-carbon technologies. ETS carbon revenues are recycled through the public budget.
We also develop a scenario consistent with the Paris Agreement goal to limit global temperature increase to well below 2 °C, which is proxied with the imposition of a global cumulative CO2 budget of 1000 GtCO2 over 2010 in line with the IPCC 6th Assessment Report (IPCC 2022). A universal carbon price is implemented from 2020 onwards to reach the global cumulative CO2 budget. As the stringency of the mitigation effort increases over time, the global carbon tax grows from 80$/tnCO2 in 2030 (in line with IEA 2019) to about 350$/tnCO2 in 2050. In addition, the EU implements the Green Deal targets of GHG emission reduction of 55% in 2030 and net-zero transition by mid-century. The policy mix adopted to drive the EU energy system decarbonisation includes various instruments—e.g., strengthened EU ETS, subsidies insulation in buildings, accelerated expansion of renewable energy, ambitious technology standards, increased electrification of energy services and uptake of innovative mitigation options (e.g., carbon capture storage, hydrogen, etc.) (Table 3).
Table 3
Scenario description
 
Scenario Description
EU Climate target
Non-EU climate targets
REF
Reference scenario
Meets the EU NDC in 2030, no additional efforts after 2030
Meet their NDCs in 2030, policy ambition does not increase beyond 2030
DECARB
EU meets EGD Targets by 2030 & 2050, Global decarbonisation to 2 °C
EU achieves 55/97% emissions reduction in 2030/2050 relative to 1990
Countries adopt ambitious universal carbon pricing to meet the 2 °C target

5.4 Results on Socio-Economic Variables and Distributional Effects

In the REF scenario, economic activity and emissions are found to gradually decouple by 2050 with emissions intensity of GDP declining in all countries, by about 2% annually over 2020–2050. This is a result of the accelerated uptake of renewable energy and low-carbon technologies, the more efficient use of energy resources, fuel switching and stricter environmental regulations. As we aim to analyse the distributional impacts of climate policies, the disaggregated household-related projections by income decile should be constructed to ensure consistency with the national-level GEM-E3-FIT outputs—here, for Greece. The projections for income deciles are based on the income level and source, occupation, consumption patterns and savings, through empirically estimated relations to disaggregate household energy demand by income decile.
In Greece, the recent evolution of income distribution among deciles shows limited changes in the last decade with small variations in the income shares of the bottom and top income quintiles. As there are large differences in earnings of different occupation types, the income distribution in the study is modelled via wage evolution of different occupation types and their respective distribution across deciles depending on sectoral evolution and labour intensity of the economy. According to OECD (2006), savings are highly concentrated at the top of the income distribution and saving rates increase with income. Over time, saving rates by decile as a percentage of disposable income do not vary largely (Eurostat 2019) and can be assumed as constant in the REF scenario by 2050. The disaggregation of GEM-E3-FIT output into income deciles requires additional assumptions:
  • Within decile, the income distribution is assumed constant over time
  • The equivalised household size is assumed constant
  • Consumption patterns and tax rates by decile are assumed constant over time
  • Distribution of personal and household benefits and allowances from government by deciles is assumed constant over time
Technical progress, ageing population, changes in consumer behaviour, consumption patterns, industrial competitiveness and policies shape the structure of socio-economic developments in Greece. Changes in income distribution in the country are largely driven by GDP growth, labour supply and demand, technical progress, sectoral growth, wage differentials across skills, the distribution of skills, capital earnings and transfers across deciles. The composition of value added differs significantly across sectors indicating that policies can have different distributional effects across countries. Income inequality is mostly influenced by inequality in labour skills and wages (Keeley 2015; Harrison et al. 2011). In the model, each household receives a share of the total wage income, based on the distribution of income by decile for each skill. The wage income from low-skilled occupations and service workers is more equally spread across different deciles, while income from high-skilled occupations (e.g., managers, technicians) and dividends is mostly directed to higher income deciles in Greece. In contrast, low-income households receive most of social benefits and other allowances. Economic development in the REF scenario involves a gradual transition towards a more service-oriented, technology-rich economy, resulting in a slight redirection of labour demand towards higher skills. Over 2020–2050 there is a slight decline in the value-added share generated by low-skilled occupations (e.g., agricultural jobs) and an increase in the share of higher skilled jobs (e.g., managers). The change in occupations and labour skills has direct impacts on the distribution of income (Fig. 3). As demand for high skills grows, a higher share of total wages would be directed towards higher deciles. Low-income groups receive income mainly from low-skill occupations, and thus their income is negatively affected. However, low-income deciles are dependent on government benefits and allowances, while higher deciles receive income mostly from labour and capital endowments.
The transition towards a high-skilled and capital-intensive Greek economy results in increasing income inequality in the REF scenario as indicated by the Gini coefficient and the S80/S20 index. The inequality indicators strongly depend on the assumption of constant distribution of occupations across deciles, which faces limitations as it does not consider the impacts of potential labour supply adjustments induced by the transition to high skills, which may change skill distributions across the deciles.
The REF scenario dynamics result in limited increase in the Gini coefficient in Greece from 2020 levels (30.5%) by 0.7 percentage points (pp) in 2030 (31.2%); however, in the longer term, increased automation, digitisation and higher requirements for labour skills drive a larger increase in income inequality, with the Gini coefficient increasing to 33.8 in 2050 (Fig. 4). Greece is expected to remain close to the EU average in terms of the Gini coefficient until 2050 (the EU Gini coefficient is projected to slightly increase from 30% in 2020 to 32.8% in 2050). The S80/S20 indicator is projected to increase over time in the REF scenario, from 5.2 in 2020 to 5.45 in 2030, and further to 6.1 in 2050.
The implementation of ambitious climate policies towards the long-term climate neutrality target (DECARB scenario) would have large-scale impacts triggered by the accelerated uptake of renewable energy and energy efficiency, the massive electrification of end-uses and the deployment of CCS and green hydrogen. The imposition of high carbon pricing drives energy system transformation towards a more capital-intensive structure, with increased investment to renewable energy, electric vehicles and energy efficiency projects, leading to increases in CAPEX and a drop in OPEX and energy purchasing costs. As GEM-E3-FIT assumes optimal use of available capital resources in the REF scenario, reallocation of investments towards low-carbon, energy-efficient technologies in the DECARB scenario leads to the so-called “crowding-out effect”, as firms and households finance their clean energy investment by spending less on other commodities and investment purposes. High carbon prices increase the cost of energy services for firms and households and, hence, production costs throughout the economy, with a depressing effect on consumption and GDP; this is partly alleviated by increased investment in low-carbon technologies. Overall, the net-zero transition is projected to lead to a slowdown of EU economic growth by 0.3% in 2030 and 1.1% in 2050 compared to the REF levels with differential impacts across countries, depending on their economic structure, their relative position in international trade (especially for fossil fuels and low-carbon technologies) and the mitigation effort. The DECARB scenario impacts differently specific sectors in Greece, with sectors directly related to fossil fuels (e.g., mining, refineries, and fossil-based power plants) facing pronounced negative effects due to the shift towards low-carbon energy sources. In contrast, increased electrification of energy services drives increased activity in the electricity sector, required for electric vehicles and heat pumps, and the emergence of green hydrogen after 2035. The output of energy-intensive industrial sectors declines by about 2% with regard to the REF scenario, due to their carbon-intensive structure, as energy costs represent a high share of production costs. Energy efficiency improvements imply increased requirements for construction directed to building retrofits and thermal insulation.
The employment impacts of DECARB are relatively limited and are driven by declining GDP counterbalanced by the uptake of more labour-intensive technologies—e.g., renewable energy and energy efficiency (Fragkos and Paroussos 2018). This aggregate effect masks large differences across productive activities, with some sectors facing extensive job losses (e.g., lignite mining, refineries) due to reduced output, while others are influenced positively by the transition (e.g., electricity, construction). These employment shifts across sectors require extensive re-allocation of workforce and the development of labour skills related to decarbonisation. The labour markets will be influenced by the transition, not only in activities directly linked to the transition, but also for workers at various levels of the supply chain or in sectors that observe a knock-on impact through multiplier effects (construction, agriculture).
The DECARB scenario would have a depressing effect in the Greek economy with GDP projected to decline by about 1% in 2050 compared to REF levels. Private consumption and employment are also negatively impacted. Higher unemployment levels would negatively influence average wage rates, with total income reducing by 0.4% in 2030 and 1.5% in 2050. The largest impacts are felt in low-income deciles, with the income of the lowest decile dropping by 2% from REF levels in 2050, while impacts are limited (less than 1%) in high-income groups; overall, we project a slightly increasing income inequality in Greece. This implies a slight increase in Gini coefficient from 33.8 in REF to 34.2 in DECARB in 2050.
The net-zero transition would also impact the composition of the Greek value added with increased share of high-skilled occupations to the detriment of low-skilled ones, due to higher demand for high-skilled labour required for the transition and the wage differential across different occupations and skills (as increased demand for managers results in a relatively higher increase in their respective share in income). The skills transition entails replacement of labour-intensive and low-skill occupations (Fig. 5), such as lignite mining, by skill-intensive occupations for the design, manufacturing, development and installation of clean technologies and innovative low-carbon products—these include manufacturing and software engineers, project designers, land development advisors and other high-skilled professional or managerial positions (Fragkos et al. 2021).

5.5 Results on Energy Poverty

The deep energy system transformation towards net-zero requires large-scale investment by households targeted to the renovation of buildings and the purchase of energy-efficient equipment and low-carbon technologies, which are capital-intensive and increase CAPEX, thereby posing challenges for low-income classes. The latter cannot afford energy-efficient appliances, houses and cars, which fuels the threat of energy poverty. Energy affordability is affected by how income inequality changes due to decarbonisation, as the amount of disposable income available for energy-related expenditure is impacted. The energy expenditure indicators (introduced in the previous section) are quantified using GEM-E3-FIT results combined with data on expenditure for fuels, electricity and energy equipment from PRIMES-Buimo (Fotiou et al. 2022).
The share of energy expenditure in income differs across income deciles, indicating the different levels of vulnerability to changes in energy prices, with lower income deciles having the highest vulnerability. The share of energy expenditure to income (Indicator 1) is estimated at 19% in 2020 for the lowest decile in Greece but is only 3% for the high-income deciles (Fig. 6). When also considering the expenditure for energy equipment (including appliances, heating devices, cars, transport equipment), the share of energy expenditure (Indicator 2) increases by an average of 5.5 pp, ranging from 8 to 22% across income deciles. The increases are relatively higher in high-income deciles that commonly purchase more expensive equipment, highly efficient appliances and more luxurious cars relative to low-income groups.
In the REF scenario, the share of energy expenditure to income declines somewhat in the longer term across income deciles, as household incomes increase faster than energy consumption and energy prices. The same trend is also evident when expenditure for energy and transport equipment is considered as well (Indicator 2), with this indicator dropping by about 1–2% across income groups.
Decarbonisation entails substantial changes in household energy-related expenditure, along with the subsequent income distributional changes described above. Strong carbon pricing, increased prices for energy products and the need to purchase more expensive low-carbon and efficient equipment result in increased energy expenditure across income deciles. The Energy Expenditure Indicator 1 increases by about 0.2–0.8 pp from REF in 2050, driven by increased energy-related expenditure and slight reduction in household income. The highest increases are found in low-income classes, indicating additional challenges to purchase energy and mobility services leading to higher threats for energy poverty increase. Higher increases are calculated based on the Energy Expenditure Indicator 2 that include the increased costs to purchase advanced energy-efficient equipment and low-emission cars. The highest increase is projected for low-income deciles (Fig. 7).
The reduced income and increased energy expenditure would have larger impacts on low-income groups, increasing their vulnerability to energy poverty. Several measures are discussed to alleviate such risks and pave the way for a just transition, most of them based on different ways to use carbon revenues (Budolfson et al. 2021). Here, we quantitatively assess the distributional impacts of directing the carbon revenues via lump-sum to households and via reduced social security contributions (DECARB_EQ), instead of recycling them through the public budget. The distribution of lump-sum transfers to different income groups follows the distribution of social benefits and allowances. The additional carbon revenues amount to about 1–1.5% of GDP and thus the redirection of carbon revenues has an important effect on income inequality. The available income of Greek households increases by more than 1% from REF levels, but this is moderated by the macroeconomic impacts of the transition in the longer run. Increased government benefits have large positive impacts for lower income deciles that largely depend on these benefits and allowances (their incomes increase by close to 2.5% from Reference), while the impacts are lower for high-income households and even turn negative in 2050, due to the reduced economic activity with GDP declining relative to the REF scenario. This leads to reduced income inequalities, as reflected in a reduction of the Gini coefficient, induced using carbon revenues as lump-sum transfers that mostly benefit lower income households. This measure counterbalances the regressive impacts of the skills transition and reduces income inequality with the Gini coefficient in Greece declining by 0.8 pp and 1.4 pp in 2030 and 2050, respectively, relative to REF, with similar trends observed also in the S80/S20 index (Fig. 8).

6 Conclusions

Decarbonisation efforts can result in large-scale economic restructuring with potential regressive distributional impacts, disproportionately affecting disadvantaged population groups. The imposition of additional carbon taxes on energy products and the need to purchase energy efficient albeit more expensive equipment may negatively affect low-income households that face funding scarcity while increasing the threat of energy poverty. Environmental policies are commonly associated, in literature, with regressive distributional impacts that negatively affect low-income households. Ignoring such distributional effects can result in less effective policies and increased social inequalities. Well-designed strategies and policies are required to achieve progressive outcomes by considering appropriate compensation schemes, either by increasing household income through lump-sum payments, reducing other taxes or through the social security system.
After studying the EU and national policy context, the challenges to quantifying energy poverty, and the relevant policies in place in Greece, the GEM-E3-FIT model—expanded to represent ten income deciles by differentiating their income sources, savings and consumption patterns—is used to quantify the socio-economic and distributional impacts of the transition to net zero by 2050. Decarbonisation affects employment and labour income, leading to a reduction in low-skilled labour demand combined with an increase in high-skilled jobs required for the transition. This causes negative distributional impacts through the labour market leading to higher social inequality levels. The net-zero transition can also increase the energy-related expenditure in households, especially in low-income groups, raising the issues of energy poverty and energy affordability, since these income classes already spend a large share of their income to purchase energy services and equipment.
Overall, the model-based analysis shows that decarbonisation increases modestly existing inequality across income classes, with low-income households facing more negative effects than higher income ones. However, using carbon revenues as lump-sum transfers to households and requiring reduced social security contributions has clear benefits. These include increasing total employment while significantly reducing the inequality across income classes. Since we assume that the distribution of lump-sum transfers follows the distribution of social benefits and allowances to income groups, the redistribution of carbon revenues will significantly reduce income inequality bringing high benefits for low-income households.
We find that, if Greece—alongside other EU countries—adopts the necessary carbon tax and then returns revenues to citizens on an equal per capita basis, it will be possible to meet the net-zero target in 2050 while also reducing inequality. These results indicate that it is possible for a society to implement strong climate action without hampering goals for equity and development.
An important caveat of the analysis, to be addressed in planned future research, is the assumption that income distribution remains constant over time within deciles, which is rather simplistic. If additional data is provided and model running time is improved, the GEM-E3-FIT modelling framework can be further enhanced to represent income percentiles, thus improving its simulation properties, especially when it comes to assessing policy impacts for the most vulnerable income groups. In addition, the model-based analysis can be expanded to cover the recent increases in energy prices and the RePowerEU strategies that will highly impact the economic and distributional impacts of the transition to net zero in Greece and in the rest of the EU countries.

Acknowledgements

The research presented in this chapter benefitted from funding under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 Framework Programme for Research and Innovation under grant agreement No. 821124 (NAVIGATE), No. 820846 (PARIS REINFORCE), No. 890437 (POWERPOOR), and No. 101022622 (ECEMF). It also benefitted from funding under the European Union’s Horizon Europe framework program under grant agreement No. 101056306 (IAM COMPACT). The sole responsibility for the content of this chapter lies with the authors; the chapter does not necessarily reflect the opinion of the European Commission.
Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​), which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and indicate if changes were made.
The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter's Creative Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the chapter's Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder.
Fußnoten
1
Directive (EU) 2019/944/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 5 June 2019 on common rules for the internal market for electricity and amending Directive 2012/27/EU.
 
2
Directive 2009/73/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 July 2009 concerning common rules for the internal market in natural gas and repealing Directive 2003/55/EC.
 
3
Directive (EU) 2019/692 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 17 April 2019 amending Directive 2009/73/EC concerning common rules for the internal market in natural gas.
 
4
Directive (EU) 2018/2002 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 11 December 2018 amending Directive 2012/27/EU on energy efficiency.
 
5
Directive (EU) 2018/844 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 30 May 2018 amending Directive 2010/31/EU on the energy performance of buildings and Directive 2012/27/EU on energy efficiency.
 
6
Regulation (EU) 2018/1999 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 11 December 2018 on the Governance of the Energy Union and Climate Action, amending Regulations (EC) No 663/2009 and (EC) No 715/2009 of the European Parliament and of the Council, Directives 94/22/EC, 98/70/EC, 2009/31/EC, 2009/73/EC, 2010/31/EU, 2012/27/EU and 2013/30/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council, Council Directives 2009/119/EC and (EU) 2015/652 and repealing Regulation (EU) No 525/2013 of the European Parliament and of the Council.
 
8
Covenant of Mayors for Climate & Energy EUROPE https://​www.​eumayors.​eu/​support/​energy-poverty.​html.
 
9
Annual Progress Report of the National Energy Poverty Alleviation Plan, year 2021, December 2021, Version 4 (https://​ypen.​gov.​gr/​wp-content/​uploads/​2022/​04/​SDEE-Annual-report-2021-v4-14032022-clean.​pdf).
 
10
For example, the Gini coefficient is particularly sensitive to income differences around the centre of the distribution and thus it should be used in combination with the S80/S20 ratio that gives information about the distribution between lower and upper deciles. It should be noted that changes in within-group inequality are not measured in GEM-E3-FIT, thus losing information on inter-group income disparities.
 
12
Both datasets provide relevant information to characterise the different households but have methodological differences; EU-SILC largely focuses of income data at EU level, while the HBS comprises data on household consumption expenditures. HBS and SILC data are based on different samples and cannot easily be matched, as income data vary considerably. SILC data is harmonised across EU countries by Eurostat, while the HBS data are gathered by national statistical offices in a partially harmonised manner (harmonised multi-regional HBS data are published for selected years), not ensuring comparability between countries.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Antepara I, Papada L, Gouveia JP, Katsoulakos N, Kaliampakos D (2020) Improving energy poverty measurement in southern European regions through equivalization of modeled energy costs. Sustainability 12(14):5721CrossRef Antepara I, Papada L, Gouveia JP, Katsoulakos N, Kaliampakos D (2020) Improving energy poverty measurement in southern European regions through equivalization of modeled energy costs. Sustainability 12(14):5721CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Arsenopoulos A, Marinakis V, Koasidis K, Stavrakaki A, Psarras J (2020) Assessing resilience to energy poverty in Europe through a multi-criteria analysis framework. Sustainability 12(12):4899CrossRef Arsenopoulos A, Marinakis V, Koasidis K, Stavrakaki A, Psarras J (2020) Assessing resilience to energy poverty in Europe through a multi-criteria analysis framework. Sustainability 12(12):4899CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Balasko Y (2014) Tourinho OA (2014) Factor proportionality in multiple households closed CGE models: theory and illustrations. Econ Theor Bull 2(2):119–136CrossRef Balasko Y (2014) Tourinho OA (2014) Factor proportionality in multiple households closed CGE models: theory and illustrations. Econ Theor Bull 2(2):119–136CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bersisa M (2019) Multidimensional measure of household energy poverty and its determinants in Ethiopia 1. In: Economic transformation for poverty reduction in Africa. Routledge, pp 58–83 Bersisa M (2019) Multidimensional measure of household energy poverty and its determinants in Ethiopia 1. In: Economic transformation for poverty reduction in Africa. Routledge, pp 58–83
Zurück zum Zitat Boardman B (1991) Fuel poverty: from cold homes to affordable warmth. Belhaven Press, London Boardman B (1991) Fuel poverty: from cold homes to affordable warmth. Belhaven Press, London
Zurück zum Zitat Bouzarovski S, Thomson H, Cornelis M, Varo A, Guyet R (2020) Towards an inclusive energy transition in the European Union: confronting energy poverty amidst a global crisis. EU Energy Poverty Observatory, Luxembourg Bouzarovski S, Thomson H, Cornelis M, Varo A, Guyet R (2020) Towards an inclusive energy transition in the European Union: confronting energy poverty amidst a global crisis. EU Energy Poverty Observatory, Luxembourg
Zurück zum Zitat Bubbico L, Freytag L (2018) Inequality in Europe (online). European Investment Bank (EIB). Available at http://www.eib.org/attachments/efs/econ_inequality_in_europe_en.pdf Bubbico L, Freytag L (2018) Inequality in Europe (online). European Investment Bank (EIB). Available at http://​www.​eib.​org/​attachments/​efs/​econ_​inequality_​in_​europe_​en.​pdf
Zurück zum Zitat Budolfson M, Dennig F, Errickson F, Feindt S, Ferranna M, Fleurbaey M, Klenert D, Kornek U, Kuruc K, Méjean A, Peng W (2021) Protecting the poor with a carbon tax and equal per capita dividend. Nat Clim Chang 11(12):1025–1026CrossRef Budolfson M, Dennig F, Errickson F, Feindt S, Ferranna M, Fleurbaey M, Klenert D, Kornek U, Kuruc K, Méjean A, Peng W (2021) Protecting the poor with a carbon tax and equal per capita dividend. Nat Clim Chang 11(12):1025–1026CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cagetti M, De Nardi M (2008) Wealth inequality: data and models. Macroecon Dyn 12(S2):285–313CrossRef Cagetti M, De Nardi M (2008) Wealth inequality: data and models. Macroecon Dyn 12(S2):285–313CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cockburn J (2001) Trade liberalisation and poverty in Nepal: A CGE micro simulation analysis Cockburn J (2001) Trade liberalisation and poverty in Nepal: A CGE micro simulation analysis
Zurück zum Zitat CPB (2011) The labour market in CGE models CPB (2011) The labour market in CGE models
Zurück zum Zitat Crentsil AO, Asuman D, Fenny AP (2019) Assessing the determinants and drivers of multidimensional energy poverty in Ghana. Energ Policy 133:110884CrossRef Crentsil AO, Asuman D, Fenny AP (2019) Assessing the determinants and drivers of multidimensional energy poverty in Ghana. Energ Policy 133:110884CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat De Maio FG (2007) Income inequality measures. J Epidemiol Community Health 61(10):849–852CrossRef De Maio FG (2007) Income inequality measures. J Epidemiol Community Health 61(10):849–852CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Delugas E, Brau R (2018) Subjective well-being and energy poverty: new insights from the combination of objective and subjective. Mimeo Delugas E, Brau R (2018) Subjective well-being and energy poverty: new insights from the combination of objective and subjective. Mimeo
Zurück zum Zitat EC (2018b) The EU-wide income distribution: inequality levels and decompositions EC (2018b) The EU-wide income distribution: inequality levels and decompositions
Zurück zum Zitat Energy Communities Law of 2018, Law 4513/2018, FEK 9/A/23.01.2018 Energy Communities Law of 2018, Law 4513/2018, FEK 9/A/23.01.2018
Zurück zum Zitat Faiella I, Lavecchia L (2021) Energy poverty. how can you fight it, if you can’t measure it? Energy Build 233:110692 Faiella I, Lavecchia L (2021) Energy poverty. how can you fight it, if you can’t measure it? Energy Build 233:110692
Zurück zum Zitat Fotiou T, Capros P, Fragkos P (2022) Policy modelling for ambitious energy efficiency investment in the EU residential buildings. Energies 15(6):2233CrossRef Fotiou T, Capros P, Fragkos P (2022) Policy modelling for ambitious energy efficiency investment in the EU residential buildings. Energies 15(6):2233CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fragkos P, Fragkiadakis K, Sovacool B, Paroussos L, Vrontisi Z, Charalampidis I (2021) Equity implications of climate policy: assessing the social and distributional impacts of emission reduction targets in the European Union. Energy 237:121591CrossRef Fragkos P, Fragkiadakis K, Sovacool B, Paroussos L, Vrontisi Z, Charalampidis I (2021) Equity implications of climate policy: assessing the social and distributional impacts of emission reduction targets in the European Union. Energy 237:121591CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fragkos P, Paroussos L (2018) Employment creation in EU related to renewables expansion. Appl Energy 230:935–945CrossRef Fragkos P, Paroussos L (2018) Employment creation in EU related to renewables expansion. Appl Energy 230:935–945CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Furceri D, Loungani P (2013) Who let the gini out? Financ Dev 50(4):25–27 Furceri D, Loungani P (2013) Who let the gini out? Financ Dev 50(4):25–27
Zurück zum Zitat Gouveia JP, Palma P, Simoes SG (2019) Energy poverty vulnerability index: a multidimensional tool to identify hotspots for local action. Energy Rep 5:187–201CrossRef Gouveia JP, Palma P, Simoes SG (2019) Energy poverty vulnerability index: a multidimensional tool to identify hotspots for local action. Energy Rep 5:187–201CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harrison A, McLaren J, McMillan M (2011) Recent perspectives on trade and inequality. Annu Rev Econ 3:261–289CrossRef Harrison A, McLaren J, McMillan M (2011) Recent perspectives on trade and inequality. Annu Rev Econ 3:261–289CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Haughton J, Khandker S (2009) Inequality measures. In: Handbook on poverty and inequality. The World Bank, Washington, DC, pp 101–120 Haughton J, Khandker S (2009) Inequality measures. In: Handbook on poverty and inequality. The World Bank, Washington, DC, pp 101–120
Zurück zum Zitat Healy JD, Clinch JP (2002) Fuel poverty, thermal comfort and occupancy: results of a national household-survey in Ireland. Appl Energy 73(3–4):329–343CrossRef Healy JD, Clinch JP (2002) Fuel poverty, thermal comfort and occupancy: results of a national household-survey in Ireland. Appl Energy 73(3–4):329–343CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hills J (2012) Getting the measure of fuel poverty: final report of the Fuel Poverty Review. Hills J (2012) Getting the measure of fuel poverty: final report of the Fuel Poverty Review.
Zurück zum Zitat IEA (2019) World energy outlook. International Energy Agency, Paris IEA (2019) World energy outlook. International Energy Agency, Paris
Zurück zum Zitat IPCC (2022) Climate change 2022: mitigation of climate change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Shukla PR, Skea J, Slade R, Al Khourdajie A, van Diemen R, McCollum D, Pathak M, Some S, Vyas P, Fradera R, Belkacemi M, Hasija A, Lisboa G, Luz S, Malley J (eds)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009157926 IPCC (2022) Climate change 2022: mitigation of climate change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Shukla PR, Skea J, Slade R, Al Khourdajie A, van Diemen R, McCollum D, Pathak M, Some S, Vyas P, Fradera R, Belkacemi M, Hasija A, Lisboa G, Luz S, Malley J (eds)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1017/​9781009157926
Zurück zum Zitat IRENA (2020) Renewable power generation costs in 2019. International Renewable Energy Agency, Abu Dhabi IRENA (2020) Renewable power generation costs in 2019. International Renewable Energy Agency, Abu Dhabi
Zurück zum Zitat Keeley B (2015) Why is income inequality rising? In: Income inequality: the gap between rich and poor. OECD Publishing, Paris Keeley B (2015) Why is income inequality rising? In: Income inequality: the gap between rich and poor. OECD Publishing, Paris
Zurück zum Zitat Moore R (2012) Definitions of fuel poverty: implications for policy. Energy Policy 49:19–26CrossRef Moore R (2012) Definitions of fuel poverty: implications for policy. Energy Policy 49:19–26CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nikas A, Gkonis N, Forouli A, Siskos E, Arsenopoulos A, Papapostolou A, Kanellou E, Karakosta C, Doukas H (2019) Greece: from near-term actions to long-term pathways–risks and uncertainties associated with the national energy efficiency framework. In: Narratives of low-carbon transitions. Routledge, London, pp 180–198 Nikas A, Gkonis N, Forouli A, Siskos E, Arsenopoulos A, Papapostolou A, Kanellou E, Karakosta C, Doukas H (2019) Greece: from near-term actions to long-term pathways–risks and uncertainties associated with the national energy efficiency framework. In: Narratives of low-carbon transitions. Routledge, London, pp 180–198
Zurück zum Zitat Ntaintasis E, Mirasgedis S, Tourkolias C (2019) Comparing different methodological approaches for measuring energy poverty: evidence from a survey in the region of Attika, Greece. Energ Policy 125:160–169CrossRef Ntaintasis E, Mirasgedis S, Tourkolias C (2019) Comparing different methodological approaches for measuring energy poverty: evidence from a survey in the region of Attika, Greece. Energ Policy 125:160–169CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nussbaumer P, Bazilian M, Modi V (2012) Measuring energy poverty: focusing on what matters. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 16(1):231–243CrossRef Nussbaumer P, Bazilian M, Modi V (2012) Measuring energy poverty: focusing on what matters. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 16(1):231–243CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat OECD (2006) The distributional effects of environmental policy OECD (2006) The distributional effects of environmental policy
Zurück zum Zitat OECD (2012) Reducing income inequality while boosting economic growth: Can it be done? In: Economic policy reforms 2012: going for growth (Online). OECD Publishing, Paris OECD (2012) Reducing income inequality while boosting economic growth: Can it be done? In: Economic policy reforms 2012: going for growth (Online). OECD Publishing, Paris
Zurück zum Zitat Piketty T (2014) Capital in the twenty-first century. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MACrossRef Piketty T (2014) Capital in the twenty-first century. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MACrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pye S, Dobbins A, Baffert C, Brajković J, Grgurev I, Miglio R, Deane P (2015) Energy poverty and vulnerable consumers in the energy sector across the EU: analysis of policies and measures. INSIGHT_E Pye S, Dobbins A, Baffert C, Brajković J, Grgurev I, Miglio R, Deane P (2015) Energy poverty and vulnerable consumers in the energy sector across the EU: analysis of policies and measures. INSIGHT_E
Zurück zum Zitat Rausch S, Metcalf G, Reilly J (2011) Distributional impacts of carbon pricing: a general equilibrium approach with micro-data for households. Energy Econ 33:S20–S33 Rausch S, Metcalf G, Reilly J (2011) Distributional impacts of carbon pricing: a general equilibrium approach with micro-data for households. Energy Econ 33:S20–S33
Zurück zum Zitat Revenga A, Dooley M (2019) Income inequality beyond neoliberalism: policies for more inclusive growth. In: Gertz G, Kharas H (ed) Beyond neoliberalism: insights from emerging markets (online). The Brookings Institution Revenga A, Dooley M (2019) Income inequality beyond neoliberalism: policies for more inclusive growth. In: Gertz G, Kharas H (ed) Beyond neoliberalism: insights from emerging markets (online). The Brookings Institution
Zurück zum Zitat Rutherford T, Shepotylo O, Tarr D (2005) The impact on Russia of WTO accession and The Doha agenda: the importance of liberalization of barriers against foreign direct investment in services for growth and poverty. The World Bank Rutherford T, Shepotylo O, Tarr D (2005) The impact on Russia of WTO accession and The Doha agenda: the importance of liberalization of barriers against foreign direct investment in services for growth and poverty. The World Bank
Zurück zum Zitat Rutherford T, Tarr D (2004) Poverty effects of Russia’s WTO accession: modelling “real” households and endogenous productivity effects. The World Bank Rutherford T, Tarr D (2004) Poverty effects of Russia’s WTO accession: modelling “real” households and endogenous productivity effects. The World Bank
Zurück zum Zitat Siksnelyte-Butkiene I, Streimikiene D, Lekavicius V, Balezentis T (2021) Energy poverty indicators: a systematic literature review and comprehensive analysis of integrity. Sustain Cities Soc 67:102756CrossRef Siksnelyte-Butkiene I, Streimikiene D, Lekavicius V, Balezentis T (2021) Energy poverty indicators: a systematic literature review and comprehensive analysis of integrity. Sustain Cities Soc 67:102756CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sokołowski J, Lewandowski P, Kiełczewska A, Bouzarovski S (2020) A multidimensional index to measure energy poverty: the Polish case. Energy Sources Part B 15(2):92–112CrossRef Sokołowski J, Lewandowski P, Kiełczewska A, Bouzarovski S (2020) A multidimensional index to measure energy poverty: the Polish case. Energy Sources Part B 15(2):92–112CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stiglitz JE, Greenwald BC (2014) Creating a learning society: a new approach to growth, development, and social progress. Columbia University Press, Chichester Stiglitz JE, Greenwald BC (2014) Creating a learning society: a new approach to growth, development, and social progress. Columbia University Press, Chichester
Zurück zum Zitat Thomson H, Snell C (2016) Definitions and indicators of energy poverty across the EU. In Energy poverty handbook. Publications Office of the European Union, pp 101–117 Thomson H, Snell C (2016) Definitions and indicators of energy poverty across the EU. In Energy poverty handbook. Publications Office of the European Union, pp 101–117
Zurück zum Zitat Tirado Herrero S (2017) Energy poverty indicators: a critical review of methods. Indoor Built Environ 26(7):1018–1031CrossRef Tirado Herrero S (2017) Energy poverty indicators: a critical review of methods. Indoor Built Environ 26(7):1018–1031CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat UN (2015) Inequality measurement: development issue no 2. In: Development Strategy and Policy Analysis Unit, Development Policy and Analysis Division Department of Economic and Social Affairs (Online) UN (2015) Inequality measurement: development issue no 2. In: Development Strategy and Policy Analysis Unit, Development Policy and Analysis Division Department of Economic and Social Affairs (Online)
Metadaten
Titel
Energy Poverty and Just Transformation in Greece
verfasst von
Panagiotis Fragkos
Eleni Kanellou
George Konstantopoulos
Alexandros Nikas
Kostas Fragkiadakis
Faidra Filipidou
Theofano Fotiou
Haris Doukas
Copyright-Jahr
2023
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-35684-1_10