Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Review of Accounting Studies 3/2023

18-04-2022

Bank financial reporting opacity and regulatory intervention

Author: John Gallemore

Published in: Review of Accounting Studies | Issue 3/2023

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

I study the association between bank financial reporting opacity, measured by delayed expected loan loss recognition, and the intervention decisions made by bank regulators. Examining U.S. commercial banks during the 2007–09 financial crisis, I find that delayed expected loan loss recognition is negatively associated with the likelihood of regulatory intervention (measured by either severe enforcement action or closure). This result is robust to using various specifications and research designs. In additional analyses, I find evidence suggesting that this association is driven by regulators exploiting financial reporting opacity to practice forbearance. My findings contribute to the extant literature on bank opacity, regulatory forbearance, and the consequences of loan loss provisioning by suggesting that delayed expected loan loss recognition affects regulatory intervention decisions.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
Similarly, Fischer and Verrecchia (2000) show that if investors are unable to fully unwind reporting bias, they will reduce their price response to reported fundamentals (e.g., earnings). Non-regulator bank stakeholders are likely to lack the training and private information necessary to unwind financial reporting opacity, especially relative to bank regulators (Stigler 1971; White 2012).
 
2
Prior work takes a more indirect approach, interpreting opaque reporting choices by banks (Huizinga and Laeven 2012) or changes in accounting standards (Blacconiere 1991; Blacconiere et al. 1991; Skinner 2008) as evidence that regulators may desire financial reporting opacity for forbearance purposes.
 
3
I discuss institutional details and prior research on U.S. bank supervision and intervention in Appendix A.
 
4
Forbearance and “too-big-to-fail” are distinct concepts. The latter refers to government bailouts and other support for systemically important institutions whose collapse could directly result in major problems for connected institutions. In contrast, regulators can practice forbearance on banks of any size, and the motives for such forbearance need not depend on the implications of the bank’s failure for the rest of the system. For example, it is widely accepted that regulators practiced forbearance on troubled thrifts during the U.S. savings and loan crisis in the 1980s, most of which would not have been considered “too big to fail” (Santomero and Hoffman 1998).
 
5
When the FDIC closes a bank, it sends a team to take over the bank’s operations. These teams can be large even for small banks. For example, the FDIC sent 80 agents to close a bank with 100 employees (Joffe-Walt 2009).
 
6
While forbearance can have benefits, it also has potential costs. If forbearance allows managers to increase risk-taking (“gambling for resurrection”), it could increase the ultimate cost of resolving the bank (Cole and White 2017). Furthermore, given the debtlike nature of their payoffs, uninsured creditors may prefer timely intervention in troubled banks, and they may run if they observe that the bank’s health is deteriorating (Diamond and Dybvig 1983). Ideally, regulators will balance the benefits of forbearance against these potential costs.
 
7
The OCC guide suggests that, to assess such tactics, examiners should pay attention to the loan loss reserve and how it relates to problem loans. The guide does not discuss the specific DELR measure that I employ in this study.
 
8
Regulators could affect provisioning behavior via less formal channels, such as conversations during on-site inspections. That said, enforcement actions can be used to address provisioning behavior.
 
9
While this discussion focuses on funding providers, other parties can inhibit forbearance. For example, politicians and the media can criticize regulators for a perceived lack of oversight. Furthermore, monitoring by one party can spark actions by another (e.g., political criticism of bank regulators could lead to depositor withdrawals).
 
10
Consistent with this idea, Rochet (2004) and Decamps et al. (2004) analytically show that if bondholders act as if a bank is in trouble (e.g., withdraw funds), regulators can be forced to intervene because forbearance becomes too costly for the regulator and/or government. While these models refer to bondholders, these bondholders are essentially providers of uninsured funding, similar to uninsured depositors.
 
11
Relatedly, Parlatore (2017) finds that if bank opacity impairs depositors’ ability to understand a bank’s deteriorating financial condition, they may be less likely to withdraw their funds, and Gao and Jiang (2018) show that reporting discretion can reduce the incidence of bank runs.
 
12
There are two reasons why non-regulator bank stakeholders may not assume the worst when observing financial reporting opacity. First, as Fischer and Verrecchia (2000) show, if stakeholders are not fully aware of the manager’s reporting strategy, then reporting bias adds noise to the report, leading to an attenuated response. Second, some studies suggest that bank stakeholders value bank opacity because it allows deposits to act as a money-like security whose value does not fluctuate with the underlying assets, which in turn facilitates liquidity risk sharing and creates a medium of exchange without fear of adverse selection (Chen et al. 2021).
 
13
The alternative—not including controls for key financial indicators such as earnings and capitalization—would likely introduce omitted variable bias.
 
14
I focus on the recent 2007–09 financial crisis rather than past crises (e.g., the Great Depression, the savings and loan crisis) for two reasons: (1) the set of call report and state-level macroeconomic variables have greatly expanded over time, enabling me to better mitigate correlated omitted variable concerns; and (2) during other crises, non-closure interventions were not publicly disclosed, precluding their investigation.
 
15
Alternatively, one could examine this association in an international setting. This is a less promising path for several reasons. First, many countries have highly concentrated banking sectors, with few banks and even fewer regulatory interventions. Second, it is challenging to compare interventions across countries because they differ substantially. Third, differences in institutions across countries are likely correlated with financial reporting, making it difficult to isolate the association between financial reporting opacity and intervention. Finally, data on non-U.S. banks is generally lacking in quality and number of variables relative to call report data.
 
16
This follows the SNL classification scheme. Prior research shows that severe enforcement actions are an important form of regulatory intervention: they are associated with reductions in lending (Danisewicz et al. 2018; Kleymenova and Tomy 2020; Peek and Rosengren 1995; Peek and Rosengren 1996) and asset risk (Delis et al. 2017), increases in capital (Kleymenova and Tomy 2020), and negative consequences for the local economy (Danisewicz et al. 2018).
 
17
I investigate these two intervention types together in my main analyses for parsimony and because both represent serious interventions. In Section 5.2, I separately examine different intervention types.
 
18
For example, the St. Louis Federal Reserve’s financial crisis timeline starts in February 2007 (https://​www.​stlouisfed.​org/​financial-crisis/​full-timeline). Intervention was less common before the crisis. For example, there were no bank closures in either 2005 or 2006.
 
19
Another benefit of DELR is that it can be measured for both public and private banks, in contrast to alternatives such as SEC restatements, which are only available for public banks. Most commercial banks are privately held.
 
20
I employ a 20-quarter window in order to balance two objectives: (a) having a sufficiently long time-series to estimate the component regressions, and (b) allowing banks to change their delayed loan loss recognition over time. For these regressions, bank-level variables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles within each quarter.
 
21
I do not include ΔGDP as a macroeconomic control here as it is only available at the state level from 2005.
 
22
I include DELR as a standalone variable, whereas some studies (e.g., Chen et al. 2021) interact DELR with bank fundamentals. The key difference is that other studies seek to examine how DELR affects stakeholder responses to bank fundamentals, and their findings suggest that DELR is a bank attribute associated with reduced stakeholder sensitivity to such fundamentals. This suggests that including DELR as a standalone variable will capture the regulator’s preference to forbear on banks for which the potential for stakeholder reactions to jeopardize forbearance is reduced.
 
23
The FDIC lists 325 banks that were closed during my sample period. Of these, 49 did not file call reports as of December 31, 2006, because they were savings banks or savings and loans (and therefore not commercial banks). Therefore, my closure sample begins with the remaining 276 commercial banks. Likewise, SNL has data on 1763 bank-level severe enforcement actions during my sample period, representing 1458 unique banks. But 209 did not file call reports as of December 31, 2006, because they were credit unions, savings banks, or savings and loans. An additional four banks filed call reports but received their enforcement action several years after filing their final call report; I exclude these enforcement actions from my analysis due to their unusual nature. Therefore, my severe enforcement action sample begins with the remaining 1245 unique commercial banks.
 
24
Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentiles.
 
25
In untabulated analyses, I find that my inferences are unaffected if I instead cluster standard errors by bank, state, or regulatory combination (the OCC for nationally chartered banks, or the combination of the applicable state regulator with either the FDIC or Federal Reserve for state chartered banks).
 
26
It is important to note that this approach assumes that a given regulator’s leniency and/or policies equally affect all banks under its supervision, which may not be the case. Therefore, I cannot conclusively rule out this story. In an untabulated test, I find that including the Agarwal et al. (2014) leniency index does not affect my inferences.
 
27
The propensity scores are created by using the coefficients from a regression of High DELR on the full set of control variables. The matching is done without replacement and using a caliper of 0.001. My inferences are also robust to a PSM approach that matches on Intervention using all independent variables except DELR.
 
28
Additionally, in untabulated analyses I find that DELR exhibits low (< 0.1) correlations with key measures of bank health, such as the non-performing loans ratio, tier 1 capital ratio, or the level or change in the loan loss reserve, highlighting a benefit of the within-bank approach to measuring DELR.
 
29
I follow Oster (2019)‘s suggestion of setting R(max) to 1.3 times the R-squared from the fully specified regression. Furthermore, I conservatively assume that no control variables are fully observed. If I instead assume that certain key variables are fully observed (specifically Tier 1 Ratio, ROA, NPL, and Size), the Oster deltas increase to 2.56 and 252 in the panel and cross-sectional samples, respectively.
 
30
I find similar results in additional untabulated robustness tests: using probit regression, excluding commercial banks owned by non-U.S.-based holding companies, dropping all observations associated with banks that did not report a call report in the year before closure, including a measure of ΔHPI based on county-level housing price indices, and classifying the acquisition of Wachovia by Wells Fargo in 2008 as an intervention.
 
31
Including these additional variables removes banks that were closed in year t + 1 from the sample, as these banks would likely not file year-end call reports in year t+1. I only conduct this test using the panel sample; a similar test using the cross-sectional sample would eliminate all banks that did not file call reports in December 2010.
 
32
Beatty and Liao (2020) suggest an alternative approach to addressing this issue: using the addition to the nonaccrual asset in place of the change in non-performing loans. However, since additions to nonaccrual assets are not reported by commercial banks until Q3 2006, I cannot employ this approach. Beatty and Liao (2020) conclude that in the absence of data on additions to nonaccrual assets, one should use the change in non-performing loans (see p. 10 of their study), which I employ in my primary DELR measure.
 
33
In my primary analyses, I estimate DELR using the provision through the fourth quarter of year t, so that the timing of DELR matches the key metrics it impacts, such as capital ratios and earnings (which are also measured as of the fourth quarter of year t). However, this estimation requires ΔNPLt + 1, meaning that ΔNPL from the first quarter of year t+1 is used. If the bank’s intervention occurs in the first quarter of year t+1, there is an overlap between the measurement period of DELR and Intervention. I conduct two untabulated tests using the panel sample to examine whether the overlap is responsible for my findings. First, I exclude observations where intervention occurred in the first quarter of year t+1. Second, I re-estimate Eq. 1 measuring all bank-level independent variables as of the third quarter of year t (which eliminates the overlap). In each test, I find a strong negative association between DELR and intervention. Another potential issue is that requiring ΔNPL in the first quarter of year t+1 might result in the observation not being included in the analysis if the intervention resulted in the bank not filing a call report in the first quarter of year t+1. I find no such examples in the cross-sectional sample. In the panel sample, I find 20 observations that filed a call report in the fourth quarter of year t but not in the first quarter of year t+1. However, these observations had missing DELR values in prior quarters; thus, the missing call report was not responsible for their exclusion.
 
34
Relatedly, several studies reports suggest that U.S. bank regulators likely practiced forbearance during the crisis (Brown and Dinç 2011; Government Accountability Office 2011; Rapoport 2013).
 
35
When the indicator variable is based on or is closely related to a continuous control variable, I remove the associated control variable from the regression in order to facilitate the interpretation of the indicator coefficient.
 
36
Chen et al. (2021) find that while opacity impairs depositor monitoring, the effect weakens during the early part of the financial crisis, which they attribute to depositors not attempting to distinguish between banks (i.e., not monitoring) during this period. In an untabulated analysis, I replicate their design in my sample, using High DELR as the measure of financial reporting opacity. I find that High DELR weakens the sensitivity of uninsured deposit flows to bank performance in my sample period, consistent with Chen et al. (2021)‘s main finding of opacity impairing depositor monitoring. Furthermore, this effect is weaker (stronger) in the earlier (later) part of my sample period, again consistent with their findings. My findings suggest that depositor monitoring, and thus the facilitating effect of DELR for forbearance, returned after the early crisis period. As noted above, this was also the period in which regulators were likely facing significant resource constraints and the DIF balance was at its lowest, suggesting that forbearance incentives had sharply increased. These findings are consistent with DELR facilitating forbearance by reducing stakeholder responses to bank fundamentals, and help explain why the DELR-intervention association is concentrated within the latter part of my sample period.
 
37
I find similar results when measuring state banking sector weakness using the deposit-weighted percentage of banks with a tier 1 capital ratio in close proximity to the 6% threshold for being considered well-capitalized.
 
38
The interaction term coefficients are not statistically different across models; this appears to be driven by the relatively large standard error in the federally chartered subsample. Furthermore, the main effect of DELR is statistically significant (insignificant) within the federally (state-) chartered banks. I interpret this as suggesting that both regulators exploit DELR for forbearance, but that the motivation for such forbearance differs across regulators: the state banking sector is a primary factor for state regulators, whereas non-regional factors (such as resolution costs) motivate forbearance for national regulators.
 
39
The underlying assumption is that bank lending generally occurs in counties where the bank has branches. The FHFA does not report county-level ΔHPI when there are too few transactions to create the index, so I cannot create this variable for all bank-years in the panel sample.
 
40
Put differently, regulators may still prefer to forbear on banks with less non-regulator monitoring, but they should be less dependent on financial reporting opacity to facilitate such forbearance. For example, while regulators may desire to forbear on banks with significant insured deposits, opacity should be less important for facilitating such forbearance since insured depositors, whose claims are not at risk, are less likely to monitor the bank.
 
41
In my sample, on average approximately 11% of assets are funded by brokered deposits and non-deposit liabilities. Given that the average equity-to-asset and cash-to-asset ratios are 11 and 5.5%, respectively, runs by these funding providers could cause solvency and liquidity problems for banks.
 
42
Consistent with this idea, prior research finds that non-banking firms exhibit less earnings management when there is greater analyst coverage (Yu 2008; Burgstahler and Eames 2003) and institutional ownership (Bushee 1998; Jiambalvo et al. 2002; Roychowdhury 2006).
 
43
I classify a bank as Private if I cannot link it or its holding company to a CRSP or CUSIP identifier (which signals the presence of traded equity or debt), either via the call reports or manual inspection. Since there are multiple potential sophisticated monitors (equity analysts, bond raters, hedge funds, the business press, etc.), this analysis instead examines banks that likely lack collective exposure to such monitoring. In untabulated analyses, I find that the DELR-intervention association is no longer significant in the presence of two specific sophisticated monitors (equity analysts and institutional owners), consistent with the tabulated findings.
 
44
I only examine bank-level enforcement actions in this analysis; personnel-level actions are excluded.
 
45
For example, a severe enforcement action may require that the regulator subsequently conduct an on-site inspection or additional off-site monitoring, and closing a bank requires the FDIC to send a team of employees.
 
46
A reading of a random selection of non-severe enforcement actions suggests that the issues addressed arose either during onsite inspections or via offsite monitoring, consistent with regulatory monitoring leading to their issuance.
 
47
I find similar results when using lagged time-varying bank covariates in the panel sample (results untabulated).
 
48
It is important to note that, despite this apparent benefit to DELR, banks and/or regulators may not uniformly seek to increase it for several reasons. First, prior research suggests that banking sectors with greater DELR have increased risk-taking (Bushman and Williams 2012); thus, there may be a cost for allowing greater DELR on average. Second, regulators may apply greater scrutiny to high DELR banks during non-crisis periods, while exploiting DELR during a crisis to avoid intervention. This is consistent with the intuition, from Morrison and White (2013), that regulators may prefer transparency ex ante, but opt for opacity during a crisis as it allows them to forbear secretly without creditors knowing. Finally, more sophisticated stakeholders, such as institutional investors, may be reluctant to provide capital or liquidity to high DELR banks. This is difficult to examine empirically in my sample but is consistent with prior research (Bushman and Williams 2015).
 
49
I follow prior research (Curry et al. 1999; Lucca et al. 2014) in using the term “enforcement actions” to collectively refer to the various formal actions that bank regulators can take against banks, including written agreements, cease-and-desist orders, prompt corrective action directives, and less severe interventions. Regulators can also issue enforcement actions against individuals, but these actions are not examined in this study.
 
Literature
go back to reference Acharya, V.V., T. Philippon, M. Richardson, and N. Roubini. (2009). A bird's-eye view: The financial crisis of 2007-2009: Causes and remedies. In Restoring financial stability: How to repair a failed system, ed. V.V. Acharya and M. Richardson. John Wiley & Sons.CrossRef Acharya, V.V., T. Philippon, M. Richardson, and N. Roubini. (2009). A bird's-eye view: The financial crisis of 2007-2009: Causes and remedies. In Restoring financial stability: How to repair a failed system, ed. V.V. Acharya and M. Richardson. John Wiley & Sons.CrossRef
go back to reference Admati, A. (2016). It takes a village to maintain a dangerous financial system. Working paper, Stanford University Graduate School of Business. Admati, A. (2016). It takes a village to maintain a dangerous financial system. Working paper, Stanford University Graduate School of Business.
go back to reference Agarwal, S., D. Lucca, A. Seru, and F. Trebbi. (2014). Inconsistent regulators: Evidence from banking. Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (2): 889–938.CrossRef Agarwal, S., D. Lucca, A. Seru, and F. Trebbi. (2014). Inconsistent regulators: Evidence from banking. Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (2): 889–938.CrossRef
go back to reference Akins, B., L. Li, J. Ng, and T.O. Rusticus. (2016). Bank competition and financial stability: Evidence from the financial crisis. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 51 (1): 1–28.CrossRef Akins, B., L. Li, J. Ng, and T.O. Rusticus. (2016). Bank competition and financial stability: Evidence from the financial crisis. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 51 (1): 1–28.CrossRef
go back to reference Antoniades, A. (2015). Commercial bank failures during the great recession: The real (estate) story. In Working paper. International Settlements. Antoniades, A. (2015). Commercial bank failures during the great recession: The real (estate) story. In Working paper. International Settlements.
go back to reference Arena, M. (2008). Bank failures and bank fundamentals: A comparative analysis of Latin America and East Asia during the nineties using bank-level data. Journal of Banking & Finance 32 (2): 299–310.CrossRef Arena, M. (2008). Bank failures and bank fundamentals: A comparative analysis of Latin America and East Asia during the nineties using bank-level data. Journal of Banking & Finance 32 (2): 299–310.CrossRef
go back to reference Aubuchon, C.P., and D.C. Wheelock. (2010). The geographic distribution and characteristics of U.S. bank failures, 2007-2010: Do bank failures still reflect local economic conditions? Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 92 (5): 395–415. Aubuchon, C.P., and D.C. Wheelock. (2010). The geographic distribution and characteristics of U.S. bank failures, 2007-2010: Do bank failures still reflect local economic conditions? Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 92 (5): 395–415.
go back to reference Balla, E., E. S. Prescott, and J. R. Walter. (2015). Did the financial reforms of the early 1990s fail? A comparison of bank failures and FDIC losses in the 1986-92 and 2007-13 periods. Working Papers Series (Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond) 15 (5):1–38. Balla, E., E. S. Prescott, and J. R. Walter. (2015). Did the financial reforms of the early 1990s fail? A comparison of bank failures and FDIC losses in the 1986-92 and 2007-13 periods. Working Papers Series (Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond) 15 (5):1–38.
go back to reference Basu, S., J. Vitanza, and W. Wang. (2020). Asymmetric loan loss provisioning. Available at SSRN 3349530. Basu, S., J. Vitanza, and W. Wang. (2020). Asymmetric loan loss provisioning. Available at SSRN 3349530.
go back to reference Beatty, A., and S. Liao. (2011). Do delays in expected loss recognition affect banks' willingness to lend? Journal of Accounting and Economics 52 (1): 1–20.CrossRef Beatty, A., and S. Liao. (2011). Do delays in expected loss recognition affect banks' willingness to lend? Journal of Accounting and Economics 52 (1): 1–20.CrossRef
go back to reference Beatty, A., and S. Liao. (2014). Financial accounting in the banking industry: A review of the empirical literature. Journal of Accounting and Economics 58 (2/3): 339–383.CrossRef Beatty, A., and S. Liao. (2014). Financial accounting in the banking industry: A review of the empirical literature. Journal of Accounting and Economics 58 (2/3): 339–383.CrossRef
go back to reference Beatty, A., and S. Liao. (2020). Alternative evidence and views on asymmetric loan loss provisioning. Journal of Accounting and Economics 70 (2–3): 101362.CrossRef Beatty, A., and S. Liao. (2020). Alternative evidence and views on asymmetric loan loss provisioning. Journal of Accounting and Economics 70 (2–3): 101362.CrossRef
go back to reference Blacconiere, W.G. (1991). Market reactions to accounting regulations in the savings and loan industry. Journal of Accounting & Economics 14 (1): 91–113.CrossRef Blacconiere, W.G. (1991). Market reactions to accounting regulations in the savings and loan industry. Journal of Accounting & Economics 14 (1): 91–113.CrossRef
go back to reference Blacconiere, W.G., R.M. Bowen, S.E. Sefcik, and C.H. Stinson. (1991). Determinants of the use of regulatory accounting principles by savings and loans. Journal of Accounting & Economics 14 (2): 167–201.CrossRef Blacconiere, W.G., R.M. Bowen, S.E. Sefcik, and C.H. Stinson. (1991). Determinants of the use of regulatory accounting principles by savings and loans. Journal of Accounting & Economics 14 (2): 167–201.CrossRef
go back to reference Boot, A.W.A., and A.V. Thakor. (1993). Self-interested bank regulation. American Economic Review 83 (2): 206–212. Boot, A.W.A., and A.V. Thakor. (1993). Self-interested bank regulation. American Economic Review 83 (2): 206–212.
go back to reference Bovenzi, J.F., and A.J. Murton. (1988). Resolution costs of bank failures. FDIC Banking Rev. 1: 1. Bovenzi, J.F., and A.J. Murton. (1988). Resolution costs of bank failures. FDIC Banking Rev. 1: 1.
go back to reference Brinkmann, E.J., P.M. Horvitz, and H. Ying-Lin. (1996). Forbearance: An empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Services Research 10 (1): 27–41.CrossRef Brinkmann, E.J., P.M. Horvitz, and H. Ying-Lin. (1996). Forbearance: An empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Services Research 10 (1): 27–41.CrossRef
go back to reference Brown, C.O., and I.S. Dinç. (2005). The politics of bank failures: Evidence from emerging markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics 120 (4): 1413–1444.CrossRef Brown, C.O., and I.S. Dinç. (2005). The politics of bank failures: Evidence from emerging markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics 120 (4): 1413–1444.CrossRef
go back to reference Brown, C.O., and I.S. Dinç. (2011). Too many to fail? Evidence of regulatory forbearance when the banking sector is weak. Review of Financial Studies 24 (4): 1378–1405.CrossRef Brown, C.O., and I.S. Dinç. (2011). Too many to fail? Evidence of regulatory forbearance when the banking sector is weak. Review of Financial Studies 24 (4): 1378–1405.CrossRef
go back to reference Brown, R.A., and S. Epstein. (1992). Resolution costs of bank failures: An update of the FDIC historical loss model. FDIC Banking Rev. 5: 1. Brown, R.A., and S. Epstein. (1992). Resolution costs of bank failures: An update of the FDIC historical loss model. FDIC Banking Rev. 5: 1.
go back to reference Burgstahler, D.C., and M.J. Eames. (2003). Earnings management to avoid losses and earnings decreases: Are analysts fooled? Contemporary Accounting Research 20 (2): 253–294.CrossRef Burgstahler, D.C., and M.J. Eames. (2003). Earnings management to avoid losses and earnings decreases: Are analysts fooled? Contemporary Accounting Research 20 (2): 253–294.CrossRef
go back to reference Bushee, B.J. (1998). The influence of institutional investors on myopic R&D investment behavior. Accounting Review: 305–333. Bushee, B.J. (1998). The influence of institutional investors on myopic R&D investment behavior. Accounting Review: 305–333.
go back to reference Bushman, R., and W.R. Landsman. (2010). The pros and cons of regulating corporate reporting: A critical review of the arguments. Accounting & Business Research 40 (3): 259–273.CrossRef Bushman, R., and W.R. Landsman. (2010). The pros and cons of regulating corporate reporting: A critical review of the arguments. Accounting & Business Research 40 (3): 259–273.CrossRef
go back to reference Bushman, R.M., and C.D. Williams. (2012). Accounting discretion, loan loss provisioning, and discipline of banks’ risk-taking. Journal of Accounting and Economics 54 (1): 1–18.CrossRef Bushman, R.M., and C.D. Williams. (2012). Accounting discretion, loan loss provisioning, and discipline of banks’ risk-taking. Journal of Accounting and Economics 54 (1): 1–18.CrossRef
go back to reference Bushman, R.M., and C.D. Williams. (2015). Delayed expected loss recognition and the risk profile of banks. Journal of Accounting Research 53 (3): 511–553.CrossRef Bushman, R.M., and C.D. Williams. (2015). Delayed expected loss recognition and the risk profile of banks. Journal of Accounting Research 53 (3): 511–553.CrossRef
go back to reference Chen, Q., I. Goldstein, Z. Huang, and R. Vashishtha. (2021). Bank transparency and deposit flows. Working paper, Duke University, University of Pennsylvania, and Yale University. Chen, Q., I. Goldstein, Z. Huang, and R. Vashishtha. (2021). Bank transparency and deposit flows. Working paper, Duke University, University of Pennsylvania, and Yale University.
go back to reference Cole, R.A., and L.J. White. (2012). Déjà vu all over again: The causes of U.S. commercial bank failures this time around. Journal of Financial Services Research 42 (1/2): 5–29.CrossRef Cole, R.A., and L.J. White. (2012). Déjà vu all over again: The causes of U.S. commercial bank failures this time around. Journal of Financial Services Research 42 (1/2): 5–29.CrossRef
go back to reference Cole, R.A., and L.J. White. (2017). When time is not on our side: The costs of regulatory forbearance in the closure of insolvent banks. Journal of Banking & Finance 80: 235–249.CrossRef Cole, R.A., and L.J. White. (2017). When time is not on our side: The costs of regulatory forbearance in the closure of insolvent banks. Journal of Banking & Finance 80: 235–249.CrossRef
go back to reference Costello, A.M., J. Granja, and J. Weber. (2019). Do strict regulators increase the transparency of banks? Journal of Accounting Research 57 (3): 603–637.CrossRef Costello, A.M., J. Granja, and J. Weber. (2019). Do strict regulators increase the transparency of banks? Journal of Accounting Research 57 (3): 603–637.CrossRef
go back to reference Curry, T., J. O'Keefe, J. Coburn, and L. Montgomery. (1999). Financial distressed banks: How effective are enforcement actions in the supervision process? FDIC Banking Review 12 (2): 1–18. Curry, T., J. O'Keefe, J. Coburn, and L. Montgomery. (1999). Financial distressed banks: How effective are enforcement actions in the supervision process? FDIC Banking Review 12 (2): 1–18.
go back to reference Dang, T. V., G. Gorton, and B. Holmstrom. (2015). Ignorance, debt and financial crises. Working paper, Columbia University, University of Mannheim, Yale University, MIT, and NBER. Dang, T. V., G. Gorton, and B. Holmstrom. (2015). Ignorance, debt and financial crises. Working paper, Columbia University, University of Mannheim, Yale University, MIT, and NBER.
go back to reference Dang, T.V., G. Gorton, B. Holmström, and G. Ordoñez. (2017). Banks as secret keepers. American Economic Review 107 (4): 1005–1029.CrossRef Dang, T.V., G. Gorton, B. Holmström, and G. Ordoñez. (2017). Banks as secret keepers. American Economic Review 107 (4): 1005–1029.CrossRef
go back to reference Danisewicz, P., D. McGowan, E. Onali, and K. Schaeck. (2018). The real effects of banking supervision: Evidence from enforcement actions. Journal of Financial Intermediation 35: 86–101.CrossRef Danisewicz, P., D. McGowan, E. Onali, and K. Schaeck. (2018). The real effects of banking supervision: Evidence from enforcement actions. Journal of Financial Intermediation 35: 86–101.CrossRef
go back to reference Davenport, A., and K. McDill. (2006). The depositor behind the discipline: A micro-level case study of Hamilton bank. Journal of Financial Services Research 30 (1): 93–109.CrossRef Davenport, A., and K. McDill. (2006). The depositor behind the discipline: A micro-level case study of Hamilton bank. Journal of Financial Services Research 30 (1): 93–109.CrossRef
go back to reference Decamps, J.-P., J.-C. Rochet, and B. Roger. (2004). The three pillars of Basel II: Optimizing the mix. Journal of Financial Intermediation 13 (2): 132–155.CrossRef Decamps, J.-P., J.-C. Rochet, and B. Roger. (2004). The three pillars of Basel II: Optimizing the mix. Journal of Financial Intermediation 13 (2): 132–155.CrossRef
go back to reference Delis, M.D., P.K. Staikouras, and C. Tsoumas. (2017). Formal enforcement actions and bank behavior. Management Science 63 (4): 959–987.CrossRef Delis, M.D., P.K. Staikouras, and C. Tsoumas. (2017). Formal enforcement actions and bank behavior. Management Science 63 (4): 959–987.CrossRef
go back to reference Delis, M.D., P.K. Staikouras, and C. Tsoumas. (2019). Supervisory enforcement actions and bank deposits. Journal of Banking & Finance 106: 110–123.CrossRef Delis, M.D., P.K. Staikouras, and C. Tsoumas. (2019). Supervisory enforcement actions and bank deposits. Journal of Banking & Finance 106: 110–123.CrossRef
go back to reference Diamond, D.W., and P.H. Dybvig. (1983). Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. Journal of Political Economy 91 (3): 401–419.CrossRef Diamond, D.W., and P.H. Dybvig. (1983). Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. Journal of Political Economy 91 (3): 401–419.CrossRef
go back to reference Dudley, W. C. (2009). Lessons learned from the financial crisis. Paper read at eighth annual BIS conference, June 26, 2009, at Basel, Switzerland. Dudley, W. C. (2009). Lessons learned from the financial crisis. Paper read at eighth annual BIS conference, June 26, 2009, at Basel, Switzerland.
go back to reference Edwards, J.M. (2011). FDICIA v. Dodd-frank: Unlearned lessons about regulatory forbearance. Harvard Business Law Review 1: 280–301. Edwards, J.M. (2011). FDICIA v. Dodd-frank: Unlearned lessons about regulatory forbearance. Harvard Business Law Review 1: 280–301.
go back to reference Eisenbach, T. M., D. O. Lucca, and R. M. Townsend. (2016). The economics of bank supervision. National Bureau of economic research working paper series no. 22201. Eisenbach, T. M., D. O. Lucca, and R. M. Townsend. (2016). The economics of bank supervision. National Bureau of economic research working paper series no. 22201.
go back to reference Fischer, P.E., and R.E. Verrecchia. (2000). Reporting bias. The Accounting Review 75 (2): 229–245.CrossRef Fischer, P.E., and R.E. Verrecchia. (2000). Reporting bias. The Accounting Review 75 (2): 229–245.CrossRef
go back to reference Gao, P., and X. Jiang. (2018). Reporting choices in the shadow of bank runs. Journal of Accounting & Economics 65 (1): 85–108.CrossRef Gao, P., and X. Jiang. (2018). Reporting choices in the shadow of bank runs. Journal of Accounting & Economics 65 (1): 85–108.CrossRef
go back to reference Goldberg, L.G., and S.C. Hudgins. (1996). Response of uninsured depositors to impending S&L failures. Quarterly Review of Economics & Finance 36 (3): 311–325.CrossRef Goldberg, L.G., and S.C. Hudgins. (1996). Response of uninsured depositors to impending S&L failures. Quarterly Review of Economics & Finance 36 (3): 311–325.CrossRef
go back to reference Goldberg, L.G., and S.C. Hudgins. (2002). Depositor discipline and changing strategies for regulating thrift institutions. Journal of Financial Economics 63 (2): 263–274.CrossRef Goldberg, L.G., and S.C. Hudgins. (2002). Depositor discipline and changing strategies for regulating thrift institutions. Journal of Financial Economics 63 (2): 263–274.CrossRef
go back to reference Goldsmith-Pinkham, P., B. Hirtle, and D. O. Lucca. (2016). Parsing the content of bank supervision. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports (No. 770). Goldsmith-Pinkham, P., B. Hirtle, and D. O. Lucca. (2016). Parsing the content of bank supervision. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports (No. 770).
go back to reference Gomez, M., A. Landier, D. Sraer, and D. Thesmar. (2020). Banks’ exposure to interest rate risk and the transmission of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics. Gomez, M., A. Landier, D. Sraer, and D. Thesmar. (2020). Banks’ exposure to interest rate risk and the transmission of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics.
go back to reference Gorton, G. (2013). The development of opacity in U.S. banking. Working paper, Yale University. Gorton, G. (2013). The development of opacity in U.S. banking. Working paper, Yale University.
go back to reference Greene, W. (2004). The behaviour of the maximum likelihood estimator of limited dependent variable models in the presence of fixed effects. The Econometrics Journal 7 (1): 98–119.CrossRef Greene, W. (2004). The behaviour of the maximum likelihood estimator of limited dependent variable models in the presence of fixed effects. The Econometrics Journal 7 (1): 98–119.CrossRef
go back to reference Greene, W. (2010). Testing hypotheses about interaction terms in nonlinear models. Economics Letters 107 (2): 291–296.CrossRef Greene, W. (2010). Testing hypotheses about interaction terms in nonlinear models. Economics Letters 107 (2): 291–296.CrossRef
go back to reference Henderson, C., W. Lang, and W. Jackson. (2015). Insider bank runs: Community bank fragility and the financial crisis of 2007. Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. Henderson, C., W. Lang, and W. Jackson. (2015). Insider bank runs: Community bank fragility and the financial crisis of 2007. Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.
go back to reference Hirtle, B., A. Kovner, and M. C. Plosser. (2016). The impact of supervision on bank performance. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports (No. 768). Hirtle, B., A. Kovner, and M. C. Plosser. (2016). The impact of supervision on bank performance. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports (No. 768).
go back to reference Holmstrom, B. (2012). The nature of liquidity provision: When ignorance is bliss. Paper read at econometric society, ASSA meetings, January 5, 2012, at Chicago, IL. Holmstrom, B. (2012). The nature of liquidity provision: When ignorance is bliss. Paper read at econometric society, ASSA meetings, January 5, 2012, at Chicago, IL.
go back to reference Huizinga, H., and L. Laeven. (2012). Bank valuation and accounting discretion during a financial crisis. Journal of Financial Economics 106 (3): 614–634.CrossRef Huizinga, H., and L. Laeven. (2012). Bank valuation and accounting discretion during a financial crisis. Journal of Financial Economics 106 (3): 614–634.CrossRef
go back to reference Iyer, R., and M. Puri. (2012). Understanding bank runs: The importance of depositor-bank relationships and networks. American Economic Review 102 (4): 1414–1445.CrossRef Iyer, R., and M. Puri. (2012). Understanding bank runs: The importance of depositor-bank relationships and networks. American Economic Review 102 (4): 1414–1445.CrossRef
go back to reference Iyer, R., M. Puri, and N. Ryan. (2013). Do depositors monitor banks? Working paper, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Duke University, Harvard University. Iyer, R., M. Puri, and N. Ryan. (2013). Do depositors monitor banks? Working paper, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Duke University, Harvard University.
go back to reference Jiambalvo, J., S. Rajgopal, and M. Venkatachalam. (2002). Institutional ownership and the extent to which stock prices reflect future earnings. Contemporary Accounting Research 19 (1): 117–145.CrossRef Jiambalvo, J., S. Rajgopal, and M. Venkatachalam. (2002). Institutional ownership and the extent to which stock prices reflect future earnings. Contemporary Accounting Research 19 (1): 117–145.CrossRef
go back to reference Kane, E. J. (1989). The s & l insurance mess: How did it happen? Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute Press; Distributed by University Press of America. Kane, E. J. (1989). The s & l insurance mess: How did it happen? Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute Press; Distributed by University Press of America.
go back to reference Kleymenova, A., and R. E. Tomy. (2020). Observing enforcement: Evidence from banking. Working paper, Federal Reserve and the University of Chicago. Kleymenova, A., and R. E. Tomy. (2020). Observing enforcement: Evidence from banking. Working paper, Federal Reserve and the University of Chicago.
go back to reference Kolasinksi, A. C., and A. F. Siegel. (2010). On the economic meaning of interaction term coefficients in non-linear binary response regression models. Working paper, University of Washington. Kolasinksi, A. C., and A. F. Siegel. (2010). On the economic meaning of interaction term coefficients in non-linear binary response regression models. Working paper, University of Washington.
go back to reference Lambert, T. (2019). Lobbying on regulatory enforcement actions: Evidence from U.S. commercial and savings banks. Management Science 65 (6): 2545–2572.CrossRef Lambert, T. (2019). Lobbying on regulatory enforcement actions: Evidence from U.S. commercial and savings banks. Management Science 65 (6): 2545–2572.CrossRef
go back to reference Liu, C.-C., and S.G. Ryan. (1995). The effect of bank loan portfolio composition on the market reaction to and anticipation of loan loss provisions. Journal of Accounting Research 33 (1): 77–94.CrossRef Liu, C.-C., and S.G. Ryan. (1995). The effect of bank loan portfolio composition on the market reaction to and anticipation of loan loss provisions. Journal of Accounting Research 33 (1): 77–94.CrossRef
go back to reference Liu, C.-C., and S.G. Ryan. (2006). Income smoothing over the business cycle: Changes in banks' coordinated management of provisions for loan losses and loan charge-offs from the pre-1990 bust to the 1990s boom. Accounting Review 81 (2): 421–441.CrossRef Liu, C.-C., and S.G. Ryan. (2006). Income smoothing over the business cycle: Changes in banks' coordinated management of provisions for loan losses and loan charge-offs from the pre-1990 bust to the 1990s boom. Accounting Review 81 (2): 421–441.CrossRef
go back to reference Lucca, D., A. Seru, and F. Trebbi. (2014). The revolving door and worker flows in banking regulation. Journal of Monetary Economics 65: 17–32.CrossRef Lucca, D., A. Seru, and F. Trebbi. (2014). The revolving door and worker flows in banking regulation. Journal of Monetary Economics 65: 17–32.CrossRef
go back to reference Martin, C., M. Puri, and A. Ufier. (2018). Deposit inflows and outflows in failing banks: The role of deposit insurance. Working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research. Martin, C., M. Puri, and A. Ufier. (2018). Deposit inflows and outflows in failing banks: The role of deposit insurance. Working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research.
go back to reference Mishkin, F.S. (2000). Prudential supervision: Why is it important and what are the issues? Working paper. Mishkin, F.S. (2000). Prudential supervision: Why is it important and what are the issues? Working paper.
go back to reference Morrison, A.D., and L. White. (2013). Reputational contagion and optimal regulatory forbearance. Journal of Financial Economics 110 (3): 642–658.CrossRef Morrison, A.D., and L. White. (2013). Reputational contagion and optimal regulatory forbearance. Journal of Financial Economics 110 (3): 642–658.CrossRef
go back to reference Ng, J., and S. Roychowdhury. (2014). Do loan loss reserves behave like capital? Evidence from recent bank failures. Review of Accounting Studies 19 (3): 1234–1279.CrossRef Ng, J., and S. Roychowdhury. (2014). Do loan loss reserves behave like capital? Evidence from recent bank failures. Review of Accounting Studies 19 (3): 1234–1279.CrossRef
go back to reference Nicoletti, A. (2018). The effects of bank regulators and external auditors on loan loss provisions. Journal of Accounting & Economics 66 (1): 244–265.CrossRef Nicoletti, A. (2018). The effects of bank regulators and external auditors on loan loss provisions. Journal of Accounting & Economics 66 (1): 244–265.CrossRef
go back to reference Oster, E. (2019). Unobservable selection and coefficient stability: Theory and evidence. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 37 (2): 187–204.CrossRef Oster, E. (2019). Unobservable selection and coefficient stability: Theory and evidence. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 37 (2): 187–204.CrossRef
go back to reference Parlatore, C. (2017). Transparency and bank runs. Working paper, New York University. Parlatore, C. (2017). Transparency and bank runs. Working paper, New York University.
go back to reference Peek, J., and E. Rosengren. (1995). Bank regulation and the credit crunch. Journal of Banking & Finance 19 (3–4): 679–692.CrossRef Peek, J., and E. Rosengren. (1995). Bank regulation and the credit crunch. Journal of Banking & Finance 19 (3–4): 679–692.CrossRef
go back to reference Peek, J., and E.S. Rosengren. (1996). Bank regulatory agreements and real estate lending. Real Estate Economics 24 (1): 55–73.CrossRef Peek, J., and E.S. Rosengren. (1996). Bank regulatory agreements and real estate lending. Real Estate Economics 24 (1): 55–73.CrossRef
go back to reference Pereira, J., I. Malafronte, G. Sorwar, and M. Nurullah. (2019). Enforcement actions, market movement and depositors’ reaction: Evidence from the U.S. banking system. Journal of Financial Services Research 55 (2–3): 143–165.CrossRef Pereira, J., I. Malafronte, G. Sorwar, and M. Nurullah. (2019). Enforcement actions, market movement and depositors’ reaction: Evidence from the U.S. banking system. Journal of Financial Services Research 55 (2–3): 143–165.CrossRef
go back to reference Peria, M.S.M., and S.L. Schmukler. (2001). Do depositors punish banks for bad behavior? Market discipline, deposit insurance, and banking crises. Journal of Finance 56 (3): 1029–1051.CrossRef Peria, M.S.M., and S.L. Schmukler. (2001). Do depositors punish banks for bad behavior? Market discipline, deposit insurance, and banking crises. Journal of Finance 56 (3): 1029–1051.CrossRef
go back to reference Rapoport, M. (2013). Staying alive: Weak banks hang on. The Wall Street Journal (Sept. 29, 2013). Rapoport, M. (2013). Staying alive: Weak banks hang on. The Wall Street Journal (Sept. 29, 2013).
go back to reference Rochet, J.-C. (2004). Rebalancing the three pillars of Basel II. Economic Policy Review 10 (2): 7–21. Rochet, J.-C. (2004). Rebalancing the three pillars of Basel II. Economic Policy Review 10 (2): 7–21.
go back to reference Roychowdhury, S. (2006). Earnings management through real activities manipulation. Journal of Accounting and Economics 42 (3): 335–370.CrossRef Roychowdhury, S. (2006). Earnings management through real activities manipulation. Journal of Accounting and Economics 42 (3): 335–370.CrossRef
go back to reference Ryan, S.G. (2011). Financial reporting for financial instruments. Foundations and Trends in Accounting 6 (3/4): 187–188.CrossRef Ryan, S.G. (2011). Financial reporting for financial instruments. Foundations and Trends in Accounting 6 (3/4): 187–188.CrossRef
go back to reference Santomero, A. M., and P. Hoffman. (1998). Problem bank resolution: Evaluating the options. Working paper, Wharton Financial Institutions Center. Santomero, A. M., and P. Hoffman. (1998). Problem bank resolution: Evaluating the options. Working paper, Wharton Financial Institutions Center.
go back to reference Skinner, D.J. (2008). The rise of deferred tax assets in Japan: The role of deferred tax accounting in the Japanese banking crisis. Journal of Accounting & Economics 46 (2/3): 218–239.CrossRef Skinner, D.J. (2008). The rise of deferred tax assets in Japan: The role of deferred tax accounting in the Japanese banking crisis. Journal of Accounting & Economics 46 (2/3): 218–239.CrossRef
go back to reference Stigler, G.J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics & Management Science 2 (1): 3–21. Stigler, G.J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics & Management Science 2 (1): 3–21.
go back to reference Vyas, D. (2011). The timeliness of accounting write-downs by U.S. financial institutions during the financial crisis of 2007-2008. Journal of Accounting Research 49 (3): 823–860.CrossRef Vyas, D. (2011). The timeliness of accounting write-downs by U.S. financial institutions during the financial crisis of 2007-2008. Journal of Accounting Research 49 (3): 823–860.CrossRef
go back to reference Wheeler, P.B. (2019). Loan loss accounting and procyclical bank lending: The role of direct regulatory actions. Journal of Accounting and Economics 67 (2–3): 463–495.CrossRef Wheeler, P.B. (2019). Loan loss accounting and procyclical bank lending: The role of direct regulatory actions. Journal of Accounting and Economics 67 (2–3): 463–495.CrossRef
go back to reference Wheelock, D.C., and P.W. Wilson. (2000). Why do banks disappear? The determinants of U.S. bank failures and acquisitions. Review of Economics & Statistics 82 (1): 127–138.CrossRef Wheelock, D.C., and P.W. Wilson. (2000). Why do banks disappear? The determinants of U.S. bank failures and acquisitions. Review of Economics & Statistics 82 (1): 127–138.CrossRef
go back to reference White, L. (2012). Corporate governance and prudential regulation of banks: Is there any connection? In research handbook on international banking and governance, ed. J.R. Barth, C. Lin, and C. Wihlborg. Edward Elgar Publishing. White, L. (2012). Corporate governance and prudential regulation of banks: Is there any connection? In research handbook on international banking and governance, ed. J.R. Barth, C. Lin, and C. Wihlborg. Edward Elgar Publishing.
go back to reference Yu, F.F. (2008). Analyst coverage and earnings management. Journal of Financial Economics 88 (2): 245–271.CrossRef Yu, F.F. (2008). Analyst coverage and earnings management. Journal of Financial Economics 88 (2): 245–271.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Bank financial reporting opacity and regulatory intervention
Author
John Gallemore
Publication date
18-04-2022
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Review of Accounting Studies / Issue 3/2023
Print ISSN: 1380-6653
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7136
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-022-09674-4

Other articles of this Issue 3/2023

Review of Accounting Studies 3/2023 Go to the issue