Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 3-4/2023

21-10-2022

Bureaucratic beliefs and law enforcement

Authors: Fuhai Hong, Dong Zhang

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 3-4/2023

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Why are laws and contracts effectively enforced in some developing countries but shelved, undermined, or sabotaged in others, even when formal institutions are in place? We develop a model to explore the interaction between the ruler, front-line bureaucrats, and civilians. We emphasize that bureaucrats’ beliefs play a vital role in determining law enforcement outcomes. Bureaucrats’ beliefs about the ruler’s type determine their expectations about whether the ruler would launch an investigation when observing law non-enforcement, which then shapes their incentive to enforce laws. The ruler’s discretion to pursue personal interests has a signaling value as to his or her type. Our game generates a unique separating equilibrium, wherein ruler types differ in whether to exercise discretion to advance personal interests and the bureaucrats enforce the law if and only if not observing the ruler’s discretion. The game also yields two pooling equilibria where different ruler types choose the same strategy. We illustrate the theoretical insights with a comparative discussion of rulers in weak states and in developmental states.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
Note that the cost of enforcing the law, E, must be distinguished from the penalty in Game LE, f.
 
2
The cost C also includes the ruler’s intervention cost of removing the bureaucrat and enforcing the law in the second round of the social game. Since law non-enforcement occurs if and only if the fighting equilibrium in the first round of the social game is witnessed, the ruler’s investigation and intervention will go hand in hand in equilibrium.
 
3
They are a pure transfer. In Spence’s (1973) classic education-as-a-signal model, education is assumed to be unproductive; the insights do not qualitatively change in an extended model when education is productive. In our model, similarly, relaxing the assumption that the ruler’s pursuit of private benefits does not harm social welfare will complicate the analysis but does not change the insights of our model qualitatively. As long as the direct impact of the ruler's discretion on social welfare (payoffs in the social game) is small enough, the social game’s equilibrium is unaffected; separating and pooling equilibria on the ruler’s discretion choice still exist in our model.
 
4
While we assume for simplicity that whether to exercise discretion is a binary decision for the ruler, as in other signaling models, our setup can be extended to cases wherein the ruler’s exercise of discretion is a continuous variable without affecting the results qualitatively.
 
5
When not observing the ruler’s discretionary action, the bureaucrat infers that the ruler is the high type and will launch an investigation if observing non-enforcement, inducing the bureaucrat to enforce the law and ultimately making the civilians produce.
 
6
The belief, which equals the proportion of type-H rulers, of course depends on a number of historical, cultural and institutional factors.
 
7
The only exception is Proposition 2(a), where both types of ruler exercise discretion while the bureaucrats enforce the law because their prior belief about the ruler’s type is sufficiently large \(\left( {p > \frac{E}{W}} \right)\).
 
8
BBC News, August 30, 2000, “Mobutu’s Legacy: Show over Substance,” http://​news.​bbc.​co.​uk/​2/​hi/​africa/​903324.​stm (last accessed on July 9, 2022).
 
9
We thank the guest editor for raising this insightful point.
 
10
The self-disciplined leadership in the Asian developmental states is also partially attributed to the presence of external threats. See, e.g., Doner, Ritchie and Slater (2005), for a discussion.
 
11
See also Kimenyi and Shughart (2010) on Kenya.
 
12
See Holmstrom & Milgrom (1987, 1991) for a general analysis of high-powered contracts.
 
Literature
go back to reference Acemoglu, D., Verdier, T., & Robinson, J. A. (2004). Kleptocracy and divide-and-rule: A model of personal rule. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(2–3), 162–192.CrossRef Acemoglu, D., Verdier, T., & Robinson, J. A. (2004). Kleptocracy and divide-and-rule: A model of personal rule. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(2–3), 162–192.CrossRef
go back to reference Adamson, J. (2020). Political institutions, resources, and war: Theory and evidence from ancient Rome. Explorations in Economic History, 76, 101324.CrossRef Adamson, J. (2020). Political institutions, resources, and war: Theory and evidence from ancient Rome. Explorations in Economic History, 76, 101324.CrossRef
go back to reference Adamson, J. (2021). The scope of political jurisdictions and violence: Theory and evidence from Africa. Public Choice, 186, 467–490.CrossRef Adamson, J. (2021). The scope of political jurisdictions and violence: Theory and evidence from Africa. Public Choice, 186, 467–490.CrossRef
go back to reference Amsden, A. (2001). The rise of “the rest”: Challenges to the west from late- industrializing economies. Oxford University Press.CrossRef Amsden, A. (2001). The rise of “the rest”: Challenges to the west from late- industrializing economies. Oxford University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Ashraf, N., Bandiera, O., & Jack, B. K. (2014). No margin, no mission? A field experiment on incentives for public service delivery. Journal of Public Economics, 120, 1–17.CrossRef Ashraf, N., Bandiera, O., & Jack, B. K. (2014). No margin, no mission? A field experiment on incentives for public service delivery. Journal of Public Economics, 120, 1–17.CrossRef
go back to reference Avis, E., Ferraz, C., & Finan, F. (2018). Do government audits reduce corruption? Estimating the impacts of exposing corrupt politicians. Journal of Political Economy, 126(5), 1912–1964.CrossRef Avis, E., Ferraz, C., & Finan, F. (2018). Do government audits reduce corruption? Estimating the impacts of exposing corrupt politicians. Journal of Political Economy, 126(5), 1912–1964.CrossRef
go back to reference Baicker, K., & Jacobson, M. (2007). Finders keepers: Forfeiture laws, policing incentives, and local budgets. Journal of Public Economics, 91(11–12), 2113–2136.CrossRef Baicker, K., & Jacobson, M. (2007). Finders keepers: Forfeiture laws, policing incentives, and local budgets. Journal of Public Economics, 91(11–12), 2113–2136.CrossRef
go back to reference Becker, G. S., & Stigler, G. J. (1974). Law enforcement, malfeasance, and compensation of enforcers. The Journal of Legal Studies, 3(1), 1–18.CrossRef Becker, G. S., & Stigler, G. J. (1974). Law enforcement, malfeasance, and compensation of enforcers. The Journal of Legal Studies, 3(1), 1–18.CrossRef
go back to reference Bertrand, M., Burgess, R., Chawla, A., & Xu, G. (2020). The glittering prizes: Career incentives and bureaucrat performance. The Review of Economic Studies, 87(2), 626–655. Bertrand, M., Burgess, R., Chawla, A., & Xu, G. (2020). The glittering prizes: Career incentives and bureaucrat performance. The Review of Economic Studies, 87(2), 626–655.
go back to reference Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2009). The origins of state capacity: Property rights, taxation, and politics. American Economic Review, 99(4), 1218–1244.CrossRef Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2009). The origins of state capacity: Property rights, taxation, and politics. American Economic Review, 99(4), 1218–1244.CrossRef
go back to reference Bobonis, G. J., Camara Fuertes, L. R., & Schwabe, R. (2016). Monitoring corruptible politicians. American Economic Review, 106(8), 2371–2405.CrossRef Bobonis, G. J., Camara Fuertes, L. R., & Schwabe, R. (2016). Monitoring corruptible politicians. American Economic Review, 106(8), 2371–2405.CrossRef
go back to reference Boix, C., & Svolik, M. W. (2013). The foundations of limited authoritarian government: Institutions, commitment, and power-sharing in dictatorships. The Journal of Politics, 75(2), 300–316.CrossRef Boix, C., & Svolik, M. W. (2013). The foundations of limited authoritarian government: Institutions, commitment, and power-sharing in dictatorships. The Journal of Politics, 75(2), 300–316.CrossRef
go back to reference Bratton, M., & van de Walle, N. (1997). Democratic experiments in Africa: Regime transitions in comparative perspective. Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Bratton, M., & van de Walle, N. (1997). Democratic experiments in Africa: Regime transitions in comparative perspective. Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Chehabi, H. E., & Linz, J. J. (1998). A theory of sultanism I: A type of nondemocratic rule. In H. E. Chehabi & J. J. Linz (Eds.), Sultanistic regimes (pp. 3–25). Johns Hopkins University Press.CrossRef Chehabi, H. E., & Linz, J. J. (1998). A theory of sultanism I: A type of nondemocratic rule. In H. E. Chehabi & J. J. Linz (Eds.), Sultanistic regimes (pp. 3–25). Johns Hopkins University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Cho, I.-K., & Kreps, D. M. (1987). Signaling games and stable equilibria. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102(2), 179–221.CrossRef Cho, I.-K., & Kreps, D. M. (1987). Signaling games and stable equilibria. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102(2), 179–221.CrossRef
go back to reference Dal Bó, E., Finan, F., & Rossi, M. A. (2013). Strengthening state capabilities: The role of financial incentives in the call to public service. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(3), 1169–1218.CrossRef Dal Bó, E., Finan, F., & Rossi, M. A. (2013). Strengthening state capabilities: The role of financial incentives in the call to public service. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(3), 1169–1218.CrossRef
go back to reference Deserranno, E. (2019). Financial incentives as signals: Experimental evidence from the recruitment of village promoters in Uganda. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 11(1), 277–317. Deserranno, E. (2019). Financial incentives as signals: Experimental evidence from the recruitment of village promoters in Uganda. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 11(1), 277–317.
go back to reference Dickson, B. J. (1993). The lessons of defeat: The reorganization of the Kuomintang on Taiwan, 1950–52. The China Quarterly, 133, 56–84.CrossRef Dickson, B. J. (1993). The lessons of defeat: The reorganization of the Kuomintang on Taiwan, 1950–52. The China Quarterly, 133, 56–84.CrossRef
go back to reference Dincecco, M., & Prado, M. (2012). Warfare, fiscal capacity, and performance. Journal of Economic Growth, 17(3), 171–203.CrossRef Dincecco, M., & Prado, M. (2012). Warfare, fiscal capacity, and performance. Journal of Economic Growth, 17(3), 171–203.CrossRef
go back to reference Doner, R. F., Ritchie, B. K., & Slater, D. (2005). Systemic vulnerability and the origins of developmental states: Northeast and Southeast Asia in comparative perspective. International Organization, 59(2), 327–336.CrossRef Doner, R. F., Ritchie, B. K., & Slater, D. (2005). Systemic vulnerability and the origins of developmental states: Northeast and Southeast Asia in comparative perspective. International Organization, 59(2), 327–336.CrossRef
go back to reference Emizet, K. (1998). Confronting leaders at the apex of the state: The growth of the unofficial economy in Congo. African Studies Review, 41(1), 99–137.CrossRef Emizet, K. (1998). Confronting leaders at the apex of the state: The growth of the unofficial economy in Congo. African Studies Review, 41(1), 99–137.CrossRef
go back to reference Fearon, J., & Laitin, D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political Science Review, 97(1), 75–90.CrossRef Fearon, J., & Laitin, D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political Science Review, 97(1), 75–90.CrossRef
go back to reference Finan, F., Olken, B. A., & Pande, R. (2017). The personnel economics of the developing state. In Handbook of economic field experiments (Vol. 2, pp. 467–514). Elsevier. Finan, F., Olken, B. A., & Pande, R. (2017). The personnel economics of the developing state. In Handbook of economic field experiments (Vol. 2, pp. 467–514). Elsevier.
go back to reference Friedman, D. (1999). Why not hang them all: The virtues of inefficient punishment. Journal of Political Economy, 107(S6), S259–S269.CrossRef Friedman, D. (1999). Why not hang them all: The virtues of inefficient punishment. Journal of Political Economy, 107(S6), S259–S269.CrossRef
go back to reference Gans-Morse, J. (2012). Threats to property rights in Russia: From private coercion to state aggression. Post-Soviet Affairs, 28(3), 263–295.CrossRef Gans-Morse, J. (2012). Threats to property rights in Russia: From private coercion to state aggression. Post-Soviet Affairs, 28(3), 263–295.CrossRef
go back to reference Gans-Morse, J. (2016). The triple threat to property rights: Credible commitment dilemmas, principal-agent problems, and private coercion. Working Paper. Gans-Morse, J. (2016). The triple threat to property rights: Credible commitment dilemmas, principal-agent problems, and private coercion. Working Paper.
go back to reference Geddes, B. (1999). What do we know about democratization after twenty years? Annual Review of Political Science, 2(1), 115–144.CrossRef Geddes, B. (1999). What do we know about democratization after twenty years? Annual Review of Political Science, 2(1), 115–144.CrossRef
go back to reference Gondola, C. D. (2002). The history of Congo. Greenwood Publishing Group. Gondola, C. D. (2002). The history of Congo. Greenwood Publishing Group.
go back to reference Greif, A. (1993). Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early trade: The Maghribi traders’ coalition. The American Economic Review, 83(3), 525–548. Greif, A. (1993). Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early trade: The Maghribi traders’ coalition. The American Economic Review, 83(3), 525–548.
go back to reference Hadfield, G. K., & Weingast, B. R. (2014). Microfoundations of the rule of law. Annual Review of Political Science, 17, 21–42.CrossRef Hadfield, G. K., & Weingast, B. R. (2014). Microfoundations of the rule of law. Annual Review of Political Science, 17, 21–42.CrossRef
go back to reference Hajnal, G., & Boda, Z. (2021). Illiberal transformation of government bureaucracy in a fragile democracy: The case of Hungary. In M. W. Bauer, B. G. Peters, J. Pierre, K. Yesilkagit, & S. Becker (Eds.), Democratic backsliding and public administration: How populists in government transform state bureaucracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hajnal, G., & Boda, Z. (2021). Illiberal transformation of government bureaucracy in a fragile democracy: The case of Hungary. In M. W. Bauer, B. G. Peters, J. Pierre, K. Yesilkagit, & S. Becker (Eds.), Democratic backsliding and public administration: How populists in government transform state bureaucracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Hanna, R., & Wang, S.-Y. (2017). Dishonesty and selection into public service: Evidence from India. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 9(3), 262–290. Hanna, R., & Wang, S.-Y. (2017). Dishonesty and selection into public service: Evidence from India. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 9(3), 262–290.
go back to reference Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1987). Aggregation and linearity in the provision of intertemporal incentives. Econometrica, 55(2), 303–328.CrossRef Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1987). Aggregation and linearity in the provision of intertemporal incentives. Econometrica, 55(2), 303–328.CrossRef
go back to reference Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1991). Multitask principal-agent analyses: Incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 7, 24–52.CrossRef Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1991). Multitask principal-agent analyses: Incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 7, 24–52.CrossRef
go back to reference Jackson, R. H., & Rosberg, C. G. (1984). Personal rule: Theory and practice in Africa. Comparative Politics, 16(4), 421–442.CrossRef Jackson, R. H., & Rosberg, C. G. (1984). Personal rule: Theory and practice in Africa. Comparative Politics, 16(4), 421–442.CrossRef
go back to reference Johnson, N. D., & Koyama, M. (2017). States and economic growth: Capacity and constraints. Explorations in Economic History, 64, 1–20.CrossRef Johnson, N. D., & Koyama, M. (2017). States and economic growth: Capacity and constraints. Explorations in Economic History, 64, 1–20.CrossRef
go back to reference Khan, A. Q., Khwaja, A. I., & Olken, B. A. (2015). Tax farming redux: Experimental evidence on performance pay for tax collectors. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131(1), 219–271.CrossRef Khan, A. Q., Khwaja, A. I., & Olken, B. A. (2015). Tax farming redux: Experimental evidence on performance pay for tax collectors. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131(1), 219–271.CrossRef
go back to reference Kimenyi, M. S., & Shughart, W. F. (2010). The political economy of constitutional choice: A study of the 2005 Kenyan constitutional referendum. Constitutional Political Economy, 21, 1–27.CrossRef Kimenyi, M. S., & Shughart, W. F. (2010). The political economy of constitutional choice: A study of the 2005 Kenyan constitutional referendum. Constitutional Political Economy, 21, 1–27.CrossRef
go back to reference Kossow, N. (2019). Populism and corruption. Transparency international anti-corruption helpdesk answer. Kossow, N. (2019). Populism and corruption. Transparency international anti-corruption helpdesk answer.
go back to reference Krekó, P., & Enyedi, Z. (2018). Explaining Eastern Europe: Orbán’s laboratory of illiberalism. Journal of Democracy, 29(3), 39–51.CrossRef Krekó, P., & Enyedi, Z. (2018). Explaining Eastern Europe: Orbán’s laboratory of illiberalism. Journal of Democracy, 29(3), 39–51.CrossRef
go back to reference Lee, K. Y. (2000). From third world to first: The Singapore story, 1965–2000. HarperCollins. Lee, K. Y. (2000). From third world to first: The Singapore story, 1965–2000. HarperCollins.
go back to reference Markus, S. (2015). Property, predation, and protection. Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Markus, S. (2015). Property, predation, and protection. Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference McGuire, M. C., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule: The invisible hand and the use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, 34(1), 72–96. McGuire, M. C., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule: The invisible hand and the use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, 34(1), 72–96.
go back to reference Mkandawire, T. (2015). Neopatrimonialism and the political economy of economic performance in Africa: Critical reflections. World Politics, 67(3), 563–612.CrossRef Mkandawire, T. (2015). Neopatrimonialism and the political economy of economic performance in Africa: Critical reflections. World Politics, 67(3), 563–612.CrossRef
go back to reference Mookherjee, D., & Png, I.P.-L. (1995). Corruptible law enforcers: How should they be compensated? The Economic Journal, 105(428), 145–159.CrossRef Mookherjee, D., & Png, I.P.-L. (1995). Corruptible law enforcers: How should they be compensated? The Economic Journal, 105(428), 145–159.CrossRef
go back to reference Ndulu, B. J., & O’Connell, S. A. (1999). Governance and growth in Sub-Saharan Africa. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(3), 41–66.CrossRef Ndulu, B. J., & O’Connell, S. A. (1999). Governance and growth in Sub-Saharan Africa. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(3), 41–66.CrossRef
go back to reference North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. The Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 803–832.CrossRef North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. The Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 803–832.CrossRef
go back to reference Olken, B. A. (2007). Monitoring corruption: Evidence from a field experiment in Indonesia. Journal of Political Economy, 115(2), 200–249.CrossRef Olken, B. A. (2007). Monitoring corruption: Evidence from a field experiment in Indonesia. Journal of Political Economy, 115(2), 200–249.CrossRef
go back to reference Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87(3), 567–576.CrossRef Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87(3), 567–576.CrossRef
go back to reference Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Piano, E. E. (2019). State capacity and public choice: A critical survey. Public Choice, 178(1), 289–309.CrossRef Piano, E. E. (2019). State capacity and public choice: A critical survey. Public Choice, 178(1), 289–309.CrossRef
go back to reference Polinsky, A. M., & Shavell, S. (2007). The theory of public enforcement of law. In A. M. Polinsky & S. Shavell (Eds.), Handbook of law and economics (pp. 403–454). Elsevier. Polinsky, A. M., & Shavell, S. (2007). The theory of public enforcement of law. In A. M. Polinsky & S. Shavell (Eds.), Handbook of law and economics (pp. 403–454). Elsevier.
go back to reference Quah, J. S. (1995). Controlling corruption in city-states: A comparative study of Hong Kong and Singapore. Crime, Law and Social Change, 22(4), 391–414.CrossRef Quah, J. S. (1995). Controlling corruption in city-states: A comparative study of Hong Kong and Singapore. Crime, Law and Social Change, 22(4), 391–414.CrossRef
go back to reference Quah, J. S. (2011). Curbing corruption in Asian countries: An impossible dream? Emerald Group Publishing Limited.CrossRef Quah, J. S. (2011). Curbing corruption in Asian countries: An impossible dream? Emerald Group Publishing Limited.CrossRef
go back to reference Quah, J. S. (2015). Singapore’s corrupt practices investigation bureau: Four suggestions for enhancing its effectiveness. Asian Education and Development Studies, 4(1), 76–100.CrossRef Quah, J. S. (2015). Singapore’s corrupt practices investigation bureau: Four suggestions for enhancing its effectiveness. Asian Education and Development Studies, 4(1), 76–100.CrossRef
go back to reference Rauch, J. E., & Evans, P. B. (2000). Bureaucratic structure and bureaucratic performance in less developed countries. Journal of Public Economics, 75(1), 49–71.CrossRef Rauch, J. E., & Evans, P. B. (2000). Bureaucratic structure and bureaucratic performance in less developed countries. Journal of Public Economics, 75(1), 49–71.CrossRef
go back to reference Reno, W. (1997). Sovereignty and personal rule in Zaire. African Studies Quarterly, 1(3), 39–64. Reno, W. (1997). Sovereignty and personal rule in Zaire. African Studies Quarterly, 1(3), 39–64.
go back to reference Rotberg, R. I. (2004). The failure and collapse of nation-states. In R. I. Rotberg (Ed.), When states fail: Causes and consequences (pp. 1–50). Princeton University Press.CrossRef Rotberg, R. I. (2004). The failure and collapse of nation-states. In R. I. Rotberg (Ed.), When states fail: Causes and consequences (pp. 1–50). Princeton University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Roth, G. (1968). Personal rulership, patrimonialism, and empire-building in the new states. World Politics, 20(2), 194–206.CrossRef Roth, G. (1968). Personal rulership, patrimonialism, and empire-building in the new states. World Politics, 20(2), 194–206.CrossRef
go back to reference Rupnik, J. (2012). Hungary’s illiberal turn: How things went wrong. Journal of Democracy, 23(3), 132–137.CrossRef Rupnik, J. (2012). Hungary’s illiberal turn: How things went wrong. Journal of Democracy, 23(3), 132–137.CrossRef
go back to reference Silverstein, G. (2008). Singapore: The exception that proves rules matter. In T. Ginsburg & T. Moustafa (Eds.), Rule by law: The politics of courts in authoritarian regimes (pp. 73–101). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Silverstein, G. (2008). Singapore: The exception that proves rules matter. In T. Ginsburg & T. Moustafa (Eds.), Rule by law: The politics of courts in authoritarian regimes (pp. 73–101). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Spence, M. (1973). Job market signaling. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(3), 355–374.CrossRef Spence, M. (1973). Job market signaling. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(3), 355–374.CrossRef
go back to reference Svolik, M. W. (2012). The politics of authoritarian rule. Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Svolik, M. W. (2012). The politics of authoritarian rule. Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Tilly, C. (1990). Coercion, capital, and European States, A.D. 990. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Tilly, C. (1990). Coercion, capital, and European States, A.D. 990. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
go back to reference Tirole, J. (1992). Collusion and the theory of organizations. In J.-J. Laffont (Ed.), Advances in economic theory (pp. 151–206). Cambridge University Press. Tirole, J. (1992). Collusion and the theory of organizations. In J.-J. Laffont (Ed.), Advances in economic theory (pp. 151–206). Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Weber, M. (1978). Economy and society: An outline of interpretive sociology (Vol. 1). University of California Press. Weber, M. (1978). Economy and society: An outline of interpretive sociology (Vol. 1). University of California Press.
go back to reference Wedeman, A. (1997). Looters, rent-scrapers, and dividend-collectors: Corruption and growth in Zaire, South Korea, and the Philippines. Journal of Developing Areas, 31, 457–478. Wedeman, A. (1997). Looters, rent-scrapers, and dividend-collectors: Corruption and growth in Zaire, South Korea, and the Philippines. Journal of Developing Areas, 31, 457–478.
go back to reference Wedeman, A. H. (2012). Double paradox: Rapid growth and rising corruption in China. Cornell University Press.CrossRef Wedeman, A. H. (2012). Double paradox: Rapid growth and rising corruption in China. Cornell University Press.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Bureaucratic beliefs and law enforcement
Authors
Fuhai Hong
Dong Zhang
Publication date
21-10-2022
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 3-4/2023
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-022-01003-2

Other articles of this Issue 3-4/2023

Public Choice 3-4/2023 Go to the issue