Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Society 1/2023

21-12-2022 | Original Article

Dialing for Dollars, Dialing for Domination: Normatively Evaluating the Congressional Fundraising Imperative

Author: Prithviraj Datta

Published in: Society | Issue 1/2023

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Members of the United States Congress labor under a pressing fundraising imperative. Congresspersons believe that they must raise very large sums of money in order to secure re-election, to help their fellow partisans in Congress get re-elected, and to rise to positions of Congressional and party leadership. This leads members of Congress to accord tremendous importance to fundraising while in office. In this article, I draw on the normative scholarship on domination to offer a novel critique of the Congressional fundraising imperative. There is good reason, I argue here, to believe that the fundraising imperative promotes the domination of non-affluent Americans by their wealthy counterparts, thereby unjustifiably depriving citizens of ordinary means of their freedom.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
I refer to both members of the House and the Senate as “Congresspersons.”
 
2
Since the habit of campaign spending is widespread among the affluent (e.g., Cook et al. 2014), I use the terms “donors,” “wealthy Americans,” and their equivalents interchangeably.
 
3
Ian Shapiro (2016, 93–97) pays closer attention to campaign finance than domination theorists typically do. Shapiro only makes passing reference to the fundraising imperative, however, and does not elaborate on why he believes that the “arms-logic of fundraising” occasions domination (2016, 97). For Shapiro, the primary way the American campaign spending regime promotes domination is by allowing well-resourced donors to limit the range of perspectives to which voters are exposed during election campaigns: i.e., by “saturating…media markets and drowning out competing views” (2016, 96). Shapiro’s analysis thus does not obviate the need for an account that identifies, in a sustained and in-depth manner, the role that the fundraising imperative might play in encouraging domination in the American political context.
 
4
Due to the strong status quo bias that characterizes Congressional decision-making, it is much easier for politically influential sectors of society to block the consideration and passage of measures that they oppose than it is for them to ensure the enactment of those they support (Gilens 2012).
 
5
I refer to this as “domination” from this point on for brevity’s sake, although it is, strictly speaking, a specific kind of domination.
 
6
Domination theorists often refer to this condition as that of “arbitrary” dependence. As the term “arbitrariness” often has connotations that are distinct from dependence upon the wills and whims of others in ordinary parlance, however, I refrain from using it here to avoid confusion.
 
7
In this regard, the present conception of domination differs from Shapiro’s, for whom domination involves actual abuse of power “into the service of an illegitimate purpose” (2012, 308). My conception tracks the standard scholarly understanding of domination.
 
8
Although the protection and furthering of basic interests is necessary for a self-ordered existence, it is not sufficient for the same. There are many other preconditions that need to be satisfied for persons to be able to live entirely in accordance with their own choices and plans. The absence of domination is thus just one element of freedom understood as the ability to lead a self-ordered existence (see also Pettit 1997).
 
9
Economic inequality, it is worth mentioning, tends to fall when Democrats control Congress (Bartels 2016).
 
10
While Lessig and I both take issue with the fundraising imperative for promoting dependence, we are concerned with different kinds of dependence. For Lessig, the fundraising imperative occasions a “dependency” on the part of Congress on wealthy donors—thereby giving rise to concerns of political corruption. On my account, in contrast, the problem with the fundraising imperative is that it likely renders non-affluent citizens dependent on the wealthy—thus occasioning concerns about domination and unfreedom. Lessig does not advert to this latter sort of dependence anywhere.
 
11
This would also be the case if Congress were to track the preferences of the majority on a near-exclusive basis, as other majoritarian critics of the fundraising imperative argue that it must to be regarded as normatively legitimate (Page and Gilens 2020; Stephanopoulos 2015).
 
12
Page and Gilens (2020, chap. 1) argue that democracy means rule in accordance with majority preferences on a near-exclusive basis. As Sabl (2015) notes, however, virtually no democratic theorist understands democracy in this way, indicating that there are good reasons against endorsing such robustly majoritarian conceptions of democracy.
 
13
While not entirely opposed to clean elections reforms, Lessig is clear that he much prefers democracy vouchers over them (2012, 264–265). This preference makes sense given his strong commitment to robust majoritarianism.
 
14
As the fundraising imperative is not the sole cause of the domination that the non-affluent likely experience, reforming campaign finance alone cannot protect against it. Widespread economic, social, and political reforms are needed to robustly insulate the non-wealthy against the risk of domination by the affluent.
 
Literature
go back to reference Abramowitz, Alan, Brad Alexander, and Thad Gunning. 2006. Incumbency, Redistricting, and the Decline of Competition in U.S. House Elections. Journal of Politics 68: 75-88.CrossRef Abramowitz, Alan, Brad Alexander, and Thad Gunning. 2006. Incumbency, Redistricting, and the Decline of Competition in U.S. House Elections. Journal of Politics 68: 75-88.CrossRef
go back to reference Ansolabehere, Stephen, John de Figueiredo, and James Snyder. 2003. Why Is There So Little Money in U.S. Politics? Journal of Economic Perspectives 17: 105–30.CrossRef Ansolabehere, Stephen, John de Figueiredo, and James Snyder. 2003. Why Is There So Little Money in U.S. Politics? Journal of Economic Perspectives 17: 105–30.CrossRef
go back to reference Barber, Michael. 2016a. Representing the Preferences of Donors, Partisans, and Voters in the U.S. Senate. Public Opinion Quarterly 80: 225–49.CrossRef Barber, Michael. 2016a. Representing the Preferences of Donors, Partisans, and Voters in the U.S. Senate. Public Opinion Quarterly 80: 225–49.CrossRef
go back to reference Barber, Michael. 2016b. Ideological Donors, Contribution Limits, and the Polarization of American Legislatures. Journal of Politics, 78, 296-310.CrossRef Barber, Michael. 2016b. Ideological Donors, Contribution Limits, and the Polarization of American Legislatures. Journal of Politics, 78, 296-310.CrossRef
go back to reference Barber, Michael, Brandice Canes-Wrone, and Sharece Thrower. 2017. Ideologically Sophisticated Donors. American Journal of Political Science 61: 271–88.CrossRef Barber, Michael, Brandice Canes-Wrone, and Sharece Thrower. 2017. Ideologically Sophisticated Donors. American Journal of Political Science 61: 271–88.CrossRef
go back to reference Bartels, Larry. 2016. Unequal Democracy. Princeton University Press. Bartels, Larry. 2016. Unequal Democracy. Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Blasi, Vincent. 1994. Free Speech and the Widening Gyre of Fund-Raising. Columbia Law Review 94: 1281–1325.CrossRef Blasi, Vincent. 1994. Free Speech and the Widening Gyre of Fund-Raising. Columbia Law Review 94: 1281–1325.CrossRef
go back to reference Boatright, Robert. 2013. Getting Primaried. University of Michigan Press. Boatright, Robert. 2013. Getting Primaried. University of Michigan Press.
go back to reference Bowman, Jarron. 2020. Do the affluent override average Americans? Measuring policy disagreement and unequal influence. Social Science Quarterly 101.3: 1018-1037. Bowman, Jarron. 2020. Do the affluent override average Americans? Measuring policy disagreement and unequal influence. Social Science Quarterly 101.3: 1018-1037.
go back to reference Briffault, Richard. 1999. Public Funding and Democratic Elections. University of Pennsylvania Law Review 148: 563–90.CrossRef Briffault, Richard. 1999. Public Funding and Democratic Elections. University of Pennsylvania Law Review 148: 563–90.CrossRef
go back to reference Broockman, David, Gregory Ferenstein, and Neil Malhotra. 2019. Predispositions and the Political Behavior of American Economic Elites. American Journal of Political Science 63: 212–33.CrossRef Broockman, David, Gregory Ferenstein, and Neil Malhotra. 2019. Predispositions and the Political Behavior of American Economic Elites. American Journal of Political Science 63: 212–33.CrossRef
go back to reference Cann, Damon. 2008. Modeling Committee Chair Selection in the U.S. House of Representatives. Political Analysis 16: 274-289.CrossRef Cann, Damon. 2008. Modeling Committee Chair Selection in the U.S. House of Representatives. Political Analysis 16: 274-289.CrossRef
go back to reference Carnes, Nicholas. 2020. The Cash Ceiling. Princeton University Press. Carnes, Nicholas. 2020. The Cash Ceiling. Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Christiano, Thomas. 2012. Money in Politics. In The Oxford Handbook of Political Philosophy, edited by David Estlund. Oxford University Press. Christiano, Thomas. 2012. Money in Politics. In The Oxford Handbook of Political Philosophy, edited by David Estlund. Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Cohen, Joshua. 2009. Money, Politics, Political Equality. In Philosophy, Politics, Democracy, edited by Joshua Cohen. Harvard University Press. Cohen, Joshua. 2009. Money, Politics, Political Equality. In Philosophy, Politics, Democracy, edited by Joshua Cohen. Harvard University Press.
go back to reference Cook, Faye, Benjamin Page, and Rachel Moskowitz. 2014. Political Engagement by Wealthy Americans. Political Science Quarterly 129: 381–98.CrossRef Cook, Faye, Benjamin Page, and Rachel Moskowitz. 2014. Political Engagement by Wealthy Americans. Political Science Quarterly 129: 381–98.CrossRef
go back to reference Currinder, Marion. 2008. Money in the House. Westview Press. Currinder, Marion. 2008. Money in the House. Westview Press.
go back to reference Doerfler, Ryan, and Samuel Moyn. 2022. The Ghost of John Hart Ely. Vanderbilt Law Review 75: 769-821. Doerfler, Ryan, and Samuel Moyn. 2022. The Ghost of John Hart Ely. Vanderbilt Law Review 75: 769-821.
go back to reference Epp, Derek. 2017. Policy Agendas and Economic Inequality in American Politics. Political Studies 66: 922–39.CrossRef Epp, Derek. 2017. Policy Agendas and Economic Inequality in American Politics. Political Studies 66: 922–39.CrossRef
go back to reference Francia, Peter, and Paul Herrnson. 2003. The Impact of Public Finance Laws on Fundraising in State Legislative Elections. American Politics Research 31: 520–39.CrossRef Francia, Peter, and Paul Herrnson. 2003. The Impact of Public Finance Laws on Fundraising in State Legislative Elections. American Politics Research 31: 520–39.CrossRef
go back to reference Geddis, Andrew. 2000. Campaign Finance Reform After McCain-Feingold. Journal of Law & Politics 16: 571-638. Geddis, Andrew. 2000. Campaign Finance Reform After McCain-Feingold. Journal of Law & Politics 16: 571-638.
go back to reference Gilens, Martin. 2012. Affluence and Influence. Princeton University Press. Gilens, Martin. 2012. Affluence and Influence. Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Gilens, Martin, and Adam Thal. 2018. Doing Well and Doing Good? Public Opinion Quarterly 82: 209-230.CrossRef Gilens, Martin, and Adam Thal. 2018. Doing Well and Doing Good? Public Opinion Quarterly 82: 209-230.CrossRef
go back to reference Hacker, Jacob, and Paul Pierson. 2010. Winner-Take-All Politics. Politics and Society 38: 152–204.CrossRef Hacker, Jacob, and Paul Pierson. 2010. Winner-Take-All Politics. Politics and Society 38: 152–204.CrossRef
go back to reference Hayes, Thomas. 2012. Responsiveness in an era of inequality: The case of the US Senate. Political Research Quarterly 66 (2013): 585–599. Hayes, Thomas. 2012. Responsiveness in an era of inequality: The case of the US Senate. Political Research Quarterly 66 (2013): 585–599.
go back to reference Heberlig, Eric, and Bruce Larson. 2012. Congressional Parties, Institutional Ambition, and the Financing of Majority Control. University of Michigan Press. Heberlig, Eric, and Bruce Larson. 2012. Congressional Parties, Institutional Ambition, and the Financing of Majority Control. University of Michigan Press.
go back to reference Krasno, Jonathan, and Donald Green. 1988. Pre-Empting Quality Challengers in House Elections. Journal of Politics 50: 920-36.CrossRef Krasno, Jonathan, and Donald Green. 1988. Pre-Empting Quality Challengers in House Elections. Journal of Politics 50: 920-36.CrossRef
go back to reference La Raja, Raymond. 2014. Money in the 2014 Congressional Elections, The Forum 12: 713–27. La Raja, Raymond. 2014. Money in the 2014 Congressional Elections, The Forum 12: 713–27.
go back to reference Laborde, Cecile. 2008. Critical Republicanism. Oxford University Press. Laborde, Cecile. 2008. Critical Republicanism. Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Laborde, Cecile. 2010. Republicanism and Global Justice, European Journal of Political Theory 9: 48–69.CrossRef Laborde, Cecile. 2010. Republicanism and Global Justice, European Journal of Political Theory 9: 48–69.CrossRef
go back to reference Lessig, Larry. 2012. Republic, Lost. Hachette Publishing. Lessig, Larry. 2012. Republic, Lost. Hachette Publishing.
go back to reference Lipsitz, Keena. 2004. Democratic Theory and Political Campaigns, Journal of Political Philosophy 12: 163-189.CrossRef Lipsitz, Keena. 2004. Democratic Theory and Political Campaigns, Journal of Political Philosophy 12: 163-189.CrossRef
go back to reference Lovett, Frank. 2010. A General Theory of Domination and Justice. Oxford University Press. Lovett, Frank. 2010. A General Theory of Domination and Justice. Oxford University Press.
go back to reference McCormick, John. 2011. Machiavellian Democracy. Cambridge University Press. McCormick, John. 2011. Machiavellian Democracy. Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Page, Benjamin, and Martin Gilens. 2020. Democracy in America? University of Chicago Press. Page, Benjamin, and Martin Gilens. 2020. Democracy in America? University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Pettit, Philip. 1997. Republicanism. Oxford University Press. Pettit, Philip. 1997. Republicanism. Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Pettit, Philip. 2010. A Republican Law of Peoples. European Journal of Political Theory 9: 70-94.CrossRef Pettit, Philip. 2010. A Republican Law of Peoples. European Journal of Political Theory 9: 70-94.CrossRef
go back to reference Pettit, Philip. 2012. On the People’s Terms. Cambridge University Press. Pettit, Philip. 2012. On the People’s Terms. Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Pevnick, Ryan. 2016. Does the Egalitarian Rationale for Campaign Finance Reform Succeed? Philosophy and Public Affairs 44: 46-76.CrossRef Pevnick, Ryan. 2016. Does the Egalitarian Rationale for Campaign Finance Reform Succeed? Philosophy and Public Affairs 44: 46-76.CrossRef
go back to reference Post, Robert. 2014. Citizens Divided. Harvard University Press. Post, Robert. 2014. Citizens Divided. Harvard University Press.
go back to reference Powell, Eleanor, and Justin Grimmer. 2016. Money in Exile. Journal of Politics 78: 974–88.CrossRef Powell, Eleanor, and Justin Grimmer. 2016. Money in Exile. Journal of Politics 78: 974–88.CrossRef
go back to reference Rahman, K. Sabeel. 2016. Democracy Against Domination. Oxford University Press. Rahman, K. Sabeel. 2016. Democracy Against Domination. Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Rawls, John. 1993. Political Liberalism. Columbia University Press. Rawls, John. 1993. Political Liberalism. Columbia University Press.
go back to reference Sabl, Andrew. 2015. Two Cultures of Democratic Theory. Perspectives on Politics 13: 345-65.CrossRef Sabl, Andrew. 2015. Two Cultures of Democratic Theory. Perspectives on Politics 13: 345-65.CrossRef
go back to reference Shapiro, Ian. 2003. The State of Democratic Theory. Princeton University Press. Shapiro, Ian. 2003. The State of Democratic Theory. Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Shapiro, Ian. 2012. On Non-domination. University of Toronto Law Journal 62: 293-335.CrossRef Shapiro, Ian. 2012. On Non-domination. University of Toronto Law Journal 62: 293-335.CrossRef
go back to reference Shapiro, Ian. 2016. Politics against Domination. Harvard University Press. Shapiro, Ian. 2016. Politics against Domination. Harvard University Press.
go back to reference Skinner, Quentin. 2010. On the Slogans of Republican Political Theory. European Journal of Political Theory 9: 95-102.CrossRef Skinner, Quentin. 2010. On the Slogans of Republican Political Theory. European Journal of Political Theory 9: 95-102.CrossRef
go back to reference Stephanopoulos, Nicholas. 2015. Aligning Campaign Finance Law. Virginia Law Review, 101: 1425–1500. Stephanopoulos, Nicholas. 2015. Aligning Campaign Finance Law. Virginia Law Review, 101: 1425–1500.
go back to reference Taylor, Robert. 2017. Exit Left. Oxford University Press. Taylor, Robert. 2017. Exit Left. Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Torres-Spelliscy, Ciara. 2017. Time Suck. Seton Hall Legislative Journal 42: 271-310. Torres-Spelliscy, Ciara. 2017. Time Suck. Seton Hall Legislative Journal 42: 271-310.
go back to reference Vergara, Camila. 2020. Systemic Corruption. Princeton University Press. Vergara, Camila. 2020. Systemic Corruption. Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Zakaras, Alex. 2013. Expensive Speech, Illegitimate Power. Polity 45: 525-553.CrossRef Zakaras, Alex. 2013. Expensive Speech, Illegitimate Power. Polity 45: 525-553.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Dialing for Dollars, Dialing for Domination: Normatively Evaluating the Congressional Fundraising Imperative
Author
Prithviraj Datta
Publication date
21-12-2022
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Society / Issue 1/2023
Print ISSN: 0147-2011
Electronic ISSN: 1936-4725
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s12115-022-00795-9

Other articles of this Issue 1/2023

Society 1/2023 Go to the issue