Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Empirical Economics 6/2021

08-01-2021

Direct and network effects of idiosyncratic TFP shocks

Authors: Kristina Barauskaite, Anh Dinh Minh Nguyen

Published in: Empirical Economics | Issue 6/2021

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This study investigates the direct and intersectoral network effects of idiosyncratic TFP shocks on sectors’ growth in the context of US manufacturing industries. To deal with the potential endogeneity of TFP, we propose a novel set of instruments for contemporaneous regressors. These instruments are technology shocks identified via sign restriction from sectoral SVAR models. Using US input–output tables and industry-level data, we quantify direct and network-based effects of the shocks. Our results show that a positive idiosyncratic technology shock induces large positive direct and network effects on sectoral growth. In terms of the network effect, we find that the shocks propagate mostly downstream the network.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
See, for instance, Acemoglu et al. (2012), who argue that microeconomic idiosyncratic shocks can lead to aggregate fluctuations in the presence of intersectoral input–output linkages, thus placing into question the famous diversification argument of Lucas (1977) that microeconomic shocks would average out and are less likely to have a significant impact on aggregate variables. Similarly, di Giovanni et al. (2014) investigated the role of individual firms in international business cycle comovement and showed that direct linkages on comovement at the micro-level has significant macro-implications. For more works in terms of the role of idiosyncratic/microeconomic shocks in macro-fluctuations, see Shea (2002), Horvath (1998), Horvath (2000), Dupor (1999), Carvalho (2008), Acemoglu et al. (2010), Gabaix (2011), Carvalho and Gabaix (2013), Johnson (2014), and Atalay (2017).
 
2
Foerster et al. (2011) considered a structural model similar to Long and Plosser (1983) and found that the role of idiosyncratic productivity shocks increased considerably after the mid-1980s, explaining half of the quarterly variation in industrial production.
 
3
A summary of AAK’s theoretical model is presented in Sect. 2.
 
4
For example: only contemporaneous regressors (\(p=q=0\)), only lags (\(p=q=1\)), and both contemporaneous and lagged variables (\(p=0\) and \(q=1\)).
 
5
Real value added is calculated by dividing the nominal value added by the corresponding shipments deflator.
 
6
In Sect. 7.2.6, we conduct a robustness check where we exclude the indirect own effects from donwstream measure, thus \(Down_{i,t}= \sum _{j\ne i} l_{ij} Idio_{j,t}\).
 
7
In Sect. 7.2.6, we conduct a robustness check where we exclude the indirect own effects from upstream measure, thus \(Up_{i,t}= \sum _{j\ne i} t_{ji}Idio_{j,t}\).
 
8
See Foerster et al. (2011)’s Equation 11 and discussions therein.
 
9
In Sect. 7.2.3, we provide a discussion when using the industry-level TFP changes as idiosyncratic changes without filtering out the part driven by the aggregate factor.
 
10
See Barauskaite and Nguyen (forthcoming) for a discussion about the role of the intersectoral network in propagating aggregate TFP shocks.
 
11
“Use” table (U) is a matrix that represents how much each commodity is being used by industries and final consumers. This matrix is presented as a commodities–industries relation. “Make” table (M) is a matrix that represents value of each commodity produces by each industry. This matrix carries the dimension of the industries-by-commodities. Neither the “Make” table nor the “Use” table is necessarily square; they are presented in different dimensions, which implies that the same commodity can be made and used in more than one industry.
 
12
The TFP from the NBER–CES database measures is not adjusted for capital utilization, as mentioned in Bartlesman and Gray (1996). An alternative approach is to obtain a measure of TFP that controls for aggregation effects, varying utilization of capital and labor, nonconstant returns and imperfect competition. See, for example, Basu et al. (2006) and Fernald (2014) for discussions.
 
13
Alternatively, one can estimate the VAR model in levels. The main purpose of this exercise is to construct instruments for endogenous variables in (2). Such an aim does not necessarily require us to take into account long-run relations between variables in the VAR model. We choose to estimate the VAR in growth because the idiosyncratic TFP measure in (2) is in the growth form. This choice could be problematic only if it results in weak instruments. However, as shown below, this is not the problem that we encounter.
 
14
See Ramey (2016) for a discussion of different identifications of technology shocks.
 
15
The impulse response functions to an unexpected positive TFP shock to each of 385 sectors can be found in the working paper version.
 
16
As mentioned above, in order to deal with the problem of endogeneity, Acemoglu et al. (2016a) suppress the contemporaneous effects of shocks and analyze only the lagged effects of shocks on the sectoral production.
 
17
Using the Wooldridge (1995)’s robust score test and a robust regression-based test also results in a strong rejection of the null hypothesis that \(Idio_{i,t}\), \(Down_{i,t}\), and \(Up_{i,t}\) are exogenous.
 
18
AAK consider a smaller sample 1991–2009. Our findings remain when using this sample, as shown in “Appendix 7.2.4”.
 
19
In future research, we would like to provide a rigorous rationale for this empirical feature.
 
20
F statistics are again substantially greater than the rule of thumb of 10, indicating that these instruments are relevant and do not seem to be weak.
 
21
Real sectoral output is calculated by dividing the nominal sectoral shipment value by the corresponding shipments deflator.
 
22
Excluding the lagged dependent variable does not alter our results.
 
23
Kose et al. (2003), Del Negro and Otrok (2008), and Mumtaz et al. (2011) also use this type of model to investigate the common dynamic properties of business-cycle fluctuations across countries. Meanwhile, Barauskaite and Nguyen (forthcoming) use this model to obtain the aggregate TFP shocks from sectoral TFP series.
 
24
Equivalently, one can permute rows and columns of input–output matrices.
 
25
The coefficients of time dummies and intercept are also centered around 0. Given that these coefficients are not of any interests, we do not show them.
 
26
Overidentified models are those that have the number of instruments exceeding the number of endogenous regressors.
 
27
The robust score test statistic is a version of Sargan’s test statistic for robust estimator of variance.
 
Literature
go back to reference Acemoglu D, Ozdaglar A, Tahbaz-Salehi A (2010) Cascades in networks and aggregate volatility. National Bureau of Economic Research, CambridgeCrossRef Acemoglu D, Ozdaglar A, Tahbaz-Salehi A (2010) Cascades in networks and aggregate volatility. National Bureau of Economic Research, CambridgeCrossRef
go back to reference Acemoglu D, Carvalho VM, Ozdaglar A, Tahbaz-Salehi A (2012) The network origins of aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 80(5):1977–2016CrossRef Acemoglu D, Carvalho VM, Ozdaglar A, Tahbaz-Salehi A (2012) The network origins of aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 80(5):1977–2016CrossRef
go back to reference Acemoglu D, Akcigit U, Kerr W (2016a) Networks and the macroeconomy: an empirical exploration. NBER Macroecon Annu 30(1):273–335CrossRef Acemoglu D, Akcigit U, Kerr W (2016a) Networks and the macroeconomy: an empirical exploration. NBER Macroecon Annu 30(1):273–335CrossRef
go back to reference Acemoglu D, Autor D, Dorn D, Hanson GH, Price B (2016b) Import competition and the great US employment sag of the 2000s. J Labor Econ 34(S1):S141–S198CrossRef Acemoglu D, Autor D, Dorn D, Hanson GH, Price B (2016b) Import competition and the great US employment sag of the 2000s. J Labor Econ 34(S1):S141–S198CrossRef
go back to reference Atalay E (2017) How important are sectoral shocks? Am Econ J Macroecon 9(4):254–80CrossRef Atalay E (2017) How important are sectoral shocks? Am Econ J Macroecon 9(4):254–80CrossRef
go back to reference Bai J, Ng S (2002) Determining the number of factors in approximate factor models. Econometrica 70(1):191–221CrossRef Bai J, Ng S (2002) Determining the number of factors in approximate factor models. Econometrica 70(1):191–221CrossRef
go back to reference Banbura M, Giannone D, Reichlin L (2010) Large Bayesian vector auto regressions. J Appl Econom 25(1):71–92CrossRef Banbura M, Giannone D, Reichlin L (2010) Large Bayesian vector auto regressions. J Appl Econom 25(1):71–92CrossRef
go back to reference Barauskaite K, Nguyen ADM. Intersectoral network-based channel of aggregate TFP shocks. Int J Finance Econ (forthcoming) Barauskaite K, Nguyen ADM. Intersectoral network-based channel of aggregate TFP shocks. Int J Finance Econ (forthcoming)
go back to reference Barrot J-N, Sauvagnat J (2016) Input specificity and the propagation of idiosyncratic shocks in production networks. Q J Econ 131(3):1543–1592CrossRef Barrot J-N, Sauvagnat J (2016) Input specificity and the propagation of idiosyncratic shocks in production networks. Q J Econ 131(3):1543–1592CrossRef
go back to reference Bartlesman E, Gray WB (1996) The NBER manufacturing productivity database Bartlesman E, Gray WB (1996) The NBER manufacturing productivity database
go back to reference Basu S, Fernald JG, Kimball MS (2006) Are technology improvements contractionary? Am Econ Rev 96(5):1418–1448CrossRef Basu S, Fernald JG, Kimball MS (2006) Are technology improvements contractionary? Am Econ Rev 96(5):1418–1448CrossRef
go back to reference Boehm CE, Flaaen A, Pandalai-Nayar N (2019) Input linkages and the transmission of shocks: firm-level evidence from the 2011 Tohoku earthquake. Rev Econ Stat 101(1):60–75CrossRef Boehm CE, Flaaen A, Pandalai-Nayar N (2019) Input linkages and the transmission of shocks: firm-level evidence from the 2011 Tohoku earthquake. Rev Econ Stat 101(1):60–75CrossRef
go back to reference Carvalho VM (2007) Aggregate fluctuations and the network structure of intersectoral trade, Manuscript, Univ. Chicago Carvalho VM (2007) Aggregate fluctuations and the network structure of intersectoral trade, Manuscript, Univ. Chicago
go back to reference Carvalho VM (2008) Aggregate fluctuations and the network structure of intersectoral trade. The University of Chicago, Chicago Carvalho VM (2008) Aggregate fluctuations and the network structure of intersectoral trade. The University of Chicago, Chicago
go back to reference Canova F, De Nicolo G (2002) Monetary disturbances matter for business fluctuations in the g-7. J Monet Econ 49(6):1131–1159CrossRef Canova F, De Nicolo G (2002) Monetary disturbances matter for business fluctuations in the g-7. J Monet Econ 49(6):1131–1159CrossRef
go back to reference Carvalho V, Gabaix X (2013) The great diversification and its undoing. Am Econ Rev 103(5):1697–1727CrossRef Carvalho V, Gabaix X (2013) The great diversification and its undoing. Am Econ Rev 103(5):1697–1727CrossRef
go back to reference Carvalho, VM, Nirei M, Saito Y, Tahbaz-Salehi, A (2016) Supply chain disruptions: evidence from the great east Japan earthquake. Columbia Business School Research Paper, (17–5) Carvalho, VM, Nirei M, Saito Y, Tahbaz-Salehi, A (2016) Supply chain disruptions: evidence from the great east Japan earthquake. Columbia Business School Research Paper, (17–5)
go back to reference Del Negro M, Otrok C (2008) Dynamic factor models with time-varying parameters: measuring changes in international business cycles. FRB of New York Staff Report, p 326 Del Negro M, Otrok C (2008) Dynamic factor models with time-varying parameters: measuring changes in international business cycles. FRB of New York Staff Report, p 326
go back to reference di Giovanni J, Levchenko AA, Mejean I (2014) Firms, destinations, and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 82(4):1303–1340CrossRef di Giovanni J, Levchenko AA, Mejean I (2014) Firms, destinations, and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 82(4):1303–1340CrossRef
go back to reference Dupor B (1999) Aggregation and irrelevance in multi-sector models. J Monet Econ 43:391–409CrossRef Dupor B (1999) Aggregation and irrelevance in multi-sector models. J Monet Econ 43:391–409CrossRef
go back to reference Faust J (1998) The robustness of identified var conclusions about money. In: Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy, vol 49. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 207–244 Faust J (1998) The robustness of identified var conclusions about money. In: Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy, vol 49. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 207–244
go back to reference Fernald J (2014) Productivity and potential output before, during, and after the great recession. National Bureau of Economic Research, CambridgeCrossRef Fernald J (2014) Productivity and potential output before, during, and after the great recession. National Bureau of Economic Research, CambridgeCrossRef
go back to reference Foerster AT, Sarte P-DG, Watson MW (2011) Sectoral versus aggregate shocks: a structural factor analysis of industrial production. J Polit Econ 119(1):1–38CrossRef Foerster AT, Sarte P-DG, Watson MW (2011) Sectoral versus aggregate shocks: a structural factor analysis of industrial production. J Polit Econ 119(1):1–38CrossRef
go back to reference Gabaix X (2011) The granular origins of aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 79(3):733–772CrossRef Gabaix X (2011) The granular origins of aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 79(3):733–772CrossRef
go back to reference Hopenhayn HA (1992) Entry, exit, and firm dynamics in long run equilibrium. Econometrica 60(5):1127–1150CrossRef Hopenhayn HA (1992) Entry, exit, and firm dynamics in long run equilibrium. Econometrica 60(5):1127–1150CrossRef
go back to reference Horvath M (1998) Cyclicality and sectoral linkages: aggregate fluctuations from independent sectoral shocks. Rev Econ Dyn 1(4):781–808CrossRef Horvath M (1998) Cyclicality and sectoral linkages: aggregate fluctuations from independent sectoral shocks. Rev Econ Dyn 1(4):781–808CrossRef
go back to reference Horvath M (2000) Sectoral shocks and aggregate fluctuations. J Monet Econ 45(1):69–106CrossRef Horvath M (2000) Sectoral shocks and aggregate fluctuations. J Monet Econ 45(1):69–106CrossRef
go back to reference Johnson RC (2014) Trade in intermediate inputs and business cycle comovement. Am Econ J Macroecon 6(4):39–83CrossRef Johnson RC (2014) Trade in intermediate inputs and business cycle comovement. Am Econ J Macroecon 6(4):39–83CrossRef
go back to reference Jovanovic B (1982) Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica 50(3):649–670CrossRef Jovanovic B (1982) Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica 50(3):649–670CrossRef
go back to reference Kose MA, Otrok C, Whiteman CH (2003) International business cycles: world, region, and country-specific factors. Am Econ Rev 93(4):1216–1239CrossRef Kose MA, Otrok C, Whiteman CH (2003) International business cycles: world, region, and country-specific factors. Am Econ Rev 93(4):1216–1239CrossRef
go back to reference Long JB, Plosser CI (1983) Real business cycles. J Polit Econ 91(1):39–69CrossRef Long JB, Plosser CI (1983) Real business cycles. J Polit Econ 91(1):39–69CrossRef
go back to reference Lucas RE (1977) Understanding business cycles. In: Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy, vol 5. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 7–29 Lucas RE (1977) Understanding business cycles. In: Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy, vol 5. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 7–29
go back to reference Mumtaz H, Simonelli S, Surico P (2011) International comovements, business cycle and inflation: a historical perspective. Rev Econ Dyn 14(1):176–198CrossRef Mumtaz H, Simonelli S, Surico P (2011) International comovements, business cycle and inflation: a historical perspective. Rev Econ Dyn 14(1):176–198CrossRef
go back to reference Ozdagli A, Weber M (2017) Monetary policy through production networks: evidence from the stock market. National Bureau of Economic Research, CambridgeCrossRef Ozdagli A, Weber M (2017) Monetary policy through production networks: evidence from the stock market. National Bureau of Economic Research, CambridgeCrossRef
go back to reference Peersman G (2005) What caused the early millennium slowdown? evidence based on vector autoregressions. J Appl Econom 20(2):185–207CrossRef Peersman G (2005) What caused the early millennium slowdown? evidence based on vector autoregressions. J Appl Econom 20(2):185–207CrossRef
go back to reference Pozzi A, Schivardi F (2016) Demand or productivity: what determines firm growth? RAND J Econ 47(3):608–630CrossRef Pozzi A, Schivardi F (2016) Demand or productivity: what determines firm growth? RAND J Econ 47(3):608–630CrossRef
go back to reference Ramey VA (2016) Macroeconomic shocks and their propagation. In: Taylor JB, Uhlig H (eds) Handbook of macroeconomics, vol 2A. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 71–162 Ramey VA (2016) Macroeconomic shocks and their propagation. In: Taylor JB, Uhlig H (eds) Handbook of macroeconomics, vol 2A. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 71–162
go back to reference Rubio-Ramirez JF, Waggoner DF, Zha T (2010) Structural vector autoregressions: theory of identification and algorithms for inference. Rev Econ Stud 77(2):665–696CrossRef Rubio-Ramirez JF, Waggoner DF, Zha T (2010) Structural vector autoregressions: theory of identification and algorithms for inference. Rev Econ Stud 77(2):665–696CrossRef
go back to reference Shea J (2002) Complementarities and comovements. J Money Credit Bank 34:412–433CrossRef Shea J (2002) Complementarities and comovements. J Money Credit Bank 34:412–433CrossRef
go back to reference Staiger D, Stock JH (1997) Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments. Econometrica 65(3):557–586CrossRef Staiger D, Stock JH (1997) Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments. Econometrica 65(3):557–586CrossRef
go back to reference Uhlig H (2005) What are the effects of monetary policy on output? results from an agnostic identification procedure. J Monet Econ 52(2):381–419CrossRef Uhlig H (2005) What are the effects of monetary policy on output? results from an agnostic identification procedure. J Monet Econ 52(2):381–419CrossRef
go back to reference Wooldridge JM (1995) Score diagnostics for linear models estimated by two stage least squares. In: Advances in econometrics and quantitative economics: essays in honor of Professor CR Rao, pp 66–87 Wooldridge JM (1995) Score diagnostics for linear models estimated by two stage least squares. In: Advances in econometrics and quantitative economics: essays in honor of Professor CR Rao, pp 66–87
Metadata
Title
Direct and network effects of idiosyncratic TFP shocks
Authors
Kristina Barauskaite
Anh Dinh Minh Nguyen
Publication date
08-01-2021
Publisher
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Published in
Empirical Economics / Issue 6/2021
Print ISSN: 0377-7332
Electronic ISSN: 1435-8921
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-020-02009-9

Other articles of this Issue 6/2021

Empirical Economics 6/2021 Go to the issue