Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 3/2018

17-06-2017 | Original Research

Disposition effect and analyst forecast dispersion

Author: Daniela Vesselinova Balkanska

Published in: Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting | Issue 3/2018

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Behavioral finance theories posit that behavioral biases are more pronounced when there is higher information uncertainty about fundamentals. This paper examines the relation between the disposition effect, the tendency to ride losses and realize gains, and dispersion in financial analysts’ earnings forecasts for a sample of large U.S. discount brokerage accounts from January 1991 to December 1996. I find that the disposition effect is exacerbated in stocks with higher analyst forecast dispersion. In particular, the disposition effect is 10% in stocks in the highest forecast dispersion quintile and not significant in the lowest forecast dispersion quintile. The driving factor behind these findings is investors’ higher propensity to realize gains when facing higher information uncertainty. The results are robust to controlling for firm size, analyst coverage, idiosyncratic volatility, turnover, and past market-adjusted returns. The results provide supportive evidence for a behavioral bias explanation of the disposition effect consistent with mean-reversion beliefs for winners and loss actualization avoidance for losers.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
There is an on going debate in the literature as to whether dispersion in analyst earnings forecasts captures differences of opinion or parameter uncertainty. See, for example, Johnson (2004).
 
2
Other measures of differences of opinion include breadth of ownership (Chen et al. 2002) and the institutional ratio (Hobbs et al. 2017). I do not use these measures as they are only available quarterly.
 
3
Higher heterogeneity of beliefs could thus simply imply that mean reversion beliefs are more extreme and these erroneous expectations take longer to be corrected. For example, suppose that there are two sets of investors holding rational or mean-reversion beliefs. In this setting, as the dispersion in beliefs increases, so does the fraction of mean-reversion investors (up to one half of the total number of investors.) Thus, it is plausible to expect stronger mean reversion beliefs or slower updating of investor beliefs when there is higher heterogeneity of beliefs.
Among behavioral finance models focusing on the importance of disagreement for mispricing, Hong and Stein (1999) derive momentum in a setting where information diffuses gradually across heterogeneous agents.
It is also possible that higher order beliefs could cause slower incorporation of information and updating of investors’ beliefs. A higher order beliefs setup could be useful to study the effect of disagreement on the disposition effect. This setup has been used by Makarov and Rytchkov (2012), for example, to model heterogeneous beliefs and the momentum anomaly, predicting stronger momentum for stocks with higher belief heterogeneity.
 
4
The reverse disposition effect in their paper is obtained using the historical purchase price as the reference price, which is the approach followed in this paper. A low disposition effect is obtained in their paper when using the ever high price as the reference price.
 
5
More recent studies find opposite results, e.g. Coval et al. (2005), Kaniel et al. (2008), and document that individual investor trading improves stock liquidity (Wang and Zhang 2015).
 
6
Li and Yang (2008) model prospect theory preferences in a full equilibrium setting in which investors hold heterogeneous beliefs about the dividend growth rate and time variation in beliefs is important.
 
7
Gomes (2005) finds that the optimal portfolio choice with loss averse investors is consistent with the disposition effect, but he does not consider the initial investment decision. Barberis and Xiong (2008) and Hens and Vlcek (2011) model the trading behavior of an investor with prospect theory preferences, taking into account the initial decision. In a partial equilibrium setting, Barberis and Xiong (2008) find that prospect theory cannot explain the ex-post disposition effect for short time horizons, as the equity premium must be relatively high for loss averse investors to invest initially in the stock.
 
8
Based on the psychological literature on entrapment, escalating commitment, and sunk cost, Zuchel (2001) also suggests that the disposition effect and investors’ reluctance to realize losses in particular could be explained based on cognitive dissonance stemming from self-justification. In order to avoid cognitive dissonance, investors may irrationally prefer to hold losers to justify their initial purchase decision. Reluctant to close mental accounts at a loss, investors could become entrapped in a losing situation if they believe they are close to breaking even.
 
9
With regard to beliefs about future reversals, there are also some studies (Ji et al. 2001) which argue that Asians have a stronger tendency to expect reversal of fortune than do Westerners, suggesting that the effects considered in this study may operate differently across cultures.
 
10
The irrational belief in mean reversion in their model works in the domain of losses.
 
11
See Barber and Odean (2000) for details on the large discount brokerage dataset.
 
12
Results in this paper are similar using the summary statistics from the I/B/E/S U.S. Summary History files.
 
13
I also correct some errors in the classification of purchases and sales based on the sign of the quantities traded. The sales or purchase price for the aggregated transactions is the weighted average price.
 
14
The average purchase price, for example, is used by Odean (1998) and Ranguelova (2001). LIFO is used by Goetzmann and Massa (2008). FIFO, which is motivated by U.S. tax practice, is used by Frazzini (2006) and Kaustia (2010).
 
15
There are 231,456,050 observations for which CRSP data is available.
 
16
Due to availability of I/B/E/S data, the large discount brokerage portfolio holding sample is reduced by 28% to 165,844,122 observations.
 
17
The standard error for the difference in the proportions PGR and PLR is:
\( se = sqrt(PGR \times (1 - PGR)/(nRG + nPG) + PLR \times (1 - PLR)/(nRL + nPL)), \)
where nRG, nPG, nRL, nPL are the number of realized gains, paper gains, realized losses and paper losses.
 
18
Results in the paper are similar using the residuals from a Fama–French three factor model regression.
 
20
Grinblatt and Keloharju (2001) find that the propensity to sell a stock is related to returns over the past month.
 
21
For the sake of brevity, Table 2 reports the statistical significance of the difference between dispersion quintile 5 (high) and quintile 1 (low) only. The full results are available upon request.
 
22
Since smaller stocks have lower analyst coverage, the I/B/E/S data is effectively restricted to larger stocks.
 
24
T-statistics for the differences in PGR, PLR and PGR-PLR across all forecast dispersion quintiles are available upon request.
 
25
Unlike Ranguelova (2001), I find that the small stocks in my sample do not exhibit a reverse disposition effect.
 
26
For the sake of brevity, Table 3 reports the statistical significance of the difference between dispersion quintile 5 (high) and quintile 1 (low) only. The full results are available upon request. The differences are positive but insignificant between D1 and D2 in the bottom size quintile, between D1 and D2 in the second size quintile, D2 and D3 in the fourth size quintile, and D2 and D3 in the top size quintile.
 
27
The results are robust to using the analyst coverage measure.
 
28
Quintile differences are insignificant for dispersion quintiles D2 and D3 in the second, third and fourth coverage quintiles. For the sake of brevity, Table 4 reports the statistical significance of the difference between dispersion quintile 5 (high) and quintile 1 (low) only. The full results are available upon request.
 
29
For the purpose of brevity, Table 5 reports the statistical significance of the difference between dispersion quintile 5 (high) and quintile 1 (low) only. The full results are available upon request.
 
30
The differences in PGR across dispersion quintile are significant for 17 out of 20 cases, except for D3–D2 for V1, D3–D2 for V2, and D2–D1 for V4.
 
31
For the sake of brevity, Table 6 reports the statistical significance of the difference between dispersion quintile 5 (high) and quintile 1 (low) only. The full results are available upon request.
 
32
Differences in adjacent forecast dispersion quintile PGR are insignificant for D4–D3 for T1, D3–D2 for T2, T4 and T5.
 
Literature
go back to reference Andreassen P (1988) Explaining the price-volume relationship: the difference between price changes and changing prices. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 41(3):371–496CrossRef Andreassen P (1988) Explaining the price-volume relationship: the difference between price changes and changing prices. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 41(3):371–496CrossRef
go back to reference Barber B, Odean T (2000) Trading is hazardous to your wealth: the common stock investment performance of individual investors. J Financ 55(2):773–806CrossRef Barber B, Odean T (2000) Trading is hazardous to your wealth: the common stock investment performance of individual investors. J Financ 55(2):773–806CrossRef
go back to reference Barberis N, Xiong W (2008) What drives the disposition effect? An analysis of a long-standing preference-based explanation. J Financ 64(2):751–784CrossRef Barberis N, Xiong W (2008) What drives the disposition effect? An analysis of a long-standing preference-based explanation. J Financ 64(2):751–784CrossRef
go back to reference Barberis N, Xiong W (2012) Realization utility. J Financ Econ 104(2):251–271CrossRef Barberis N, Xiong W (2012) Realization utility. J Financ Econ 104(2):251–271CrossRef
go back to reference Ben-David I, Doukas J, Hirshleifer D (2009) Uncertainty and trading strategies of institutional investors. Working paper Ben-David I, Doukas J, Hirshleifer D (2009) Uncertainty and trading strategies of institutional investors. Working paper
go back to reference Chen J, Hong H, Stein J (2002) Breadth of ownership and stock returns. J Financ Econ 66(2–3):171–205CrossRef Chen J, Hong H, Stein J (2002) Breadth of ownership and stock returns. J Financ Econ 66(2–3):171–205CrossRef
go back to reference Choe H, Kho Kho B-C, Stulz R (1999) Do foreign investors destabilize stock markets? The Korean experience in 1997. J Financ Econ 54(2):227–264CrossRef Choe H, Kho Kho B-C, Stulz R (1999) Do foreign investors destabilize stock markets? The Korean experience in 1997. J Financ Econ 54(2):227–264CrossRef
go back to reference Coval J, Shumway T (2005) Do behavioral biases affect prices? J Financ 60(1):1–34CrossRef Coval J, Shumway T (2005) Do behavioral biases affect prices? J Financ 60(1):1–34CrossRef
go back to reference Coval J, Hirshleifer D, Shumway T (2005) Can individual investors beat the market? Working paper Coval J, Hirshleifer D, Shumway T (2005) Can individual investors beat the market? Working paper
go back to reference Daniel K, Hirshleifer D, Subrahmanyam A (1998) Investor psychology and security market under- and overreactions. J Financ 53(6):1839–1885CrossRef Daniel K, Hirshleifer D, Subrahmanyam A (1998) Investor psychology and security market under- and overreactions. J Financ 53(6):1839–1885CrossRef
go back to reference Dhar R, Zhu N (2006) Up close and personal: investor sophistication and the disposition effect. Manag Sci 52(5):726–740CrossRef Dhar R, Zhu N (2006) Up close and personal: investor sophistication and the disposition effect. Manag Sci 52(5):726–740CrossRef
go back to reference Diether K, Malloy C, Scherbina A (2002) Differences of opinion and the cross-section of stock returns. J Financ 57(5):2113–2141CrossRef Diether K, Malloy C, Scherbina A (2002) Differences of opinion and the cross-section of stock returns. J Financ 57(5):2113–2141CrossRef
go back to reference Einhorn H (1980) Overconfidence in judgment. New Dir Methodol Soc Behav Sci 4:1–16 Einhorn H (1980) Overconfidence in judgment. New Dir Methodol Soc Behav Sci 4:1–16
go back to reference Feng L, Seasholes M (2005) Do investor sophistication and trading experience eliminate behavioral biases in financial markets. Review of Finance 9(3):305–351CrossRef Feng L, Seasholes M (2005) Do investor sophistication and trading experience eliminate behavioral biases in financial markets. Review of Finance 9(3):305–351CrossRef
go back to reference Frazzini A (2006) The disposition effect and underreaction to news. J Financ 61(4):2017–2046CrossRef Frazzini A (2006) The disposition effect and underreaction to news. J Financ 61(4):2017–2046CrossRef
go back to reference Genesove D, Mayer C (2001) Loss aversion and seller behavior: evidence from the housing market. Quart J Econ 116(4):1233–1260CrossRef Genesove D, Mayer C (2001) Loss aversion and seller behavior: evidence from the housing market. Quart J Econ 116(4):1233–1260CrossRef
go back to reference Goetzmann W, Massa M (2008) Disposition matters: volume, volatility and price impact of a behavioral bias. J Portf Manag 34(2):103–125CrossRef Goetzmann W, Massa M (2008) Disposition matters: volume, volatility and price impact of a behavioral bias. J Portf Manag 34(2):103–125CrossRef
go back to reference Gomes F (2005) Portfolio choice and trading volume with loss averse investors. J Bus 78(2):675–706CrossRef Gomes F (2005) Portfolio choice and trading volume with loss averse investors. J Bus 78(2):675–706CrossRef
go back to reference Griffin D, Tversky A (1992) The weighting of evidence and the determinants of confidence. Cogn Psychol 24(3):411–435CrossRef Griffin D, Tversky A (1992) The weighting of evidence and the determinants of confidence. Cogn Psychol 24(3):411–435CrossRef
go back to reference Grinblatt M, Han B (2005) Prospect theory, mental accounting and momentum. J Financ Econ 78(2):311–339CrossRef Grinblatt M, Han B (2005) Prospect theory, mental accounting and momentum. J Financ Econ 78(2):311–339CrossRef
go back to reference Grinblatt M, Keloharju M (2001) What makes investors trade? J Financ 56(2):589–616CrossRef Grinblatt M, Keloharju M (2001) What makes investors trade? J Financ 56(2):589–616CrossRef
go back to reference Hens T, Vlcek M (2011) Does prospect theory explain the disposition effect? J Behav Financ 12(3):141–157CrossRef Hens T, Vlcek M (2011) Does prospect theory explain the disposition effect? J Behav Financ 12(3):141–157CrossRef
go back to reference Hobbs J, Lee H, Singh V (2017) New evidence on the effect of belief heterogeneity on stock returns. Rev Quant Financ Acc 48(2):289–309CrossRef Hobbs J, Lee H, Singh V (2017) New evidence on the effect of belief heterogeneity on stock returns. Rev Quant Financ Acc 48(2):289–309CrossRef
go back to reference Hong H, Stein J (1999) A unified theory of underreaction, momentum trading and overreaction in asset markets. J Financ 54(6):2143–2184CrossRef Hong H, Stein J (1999) A unified theory of underreaction, momentum trading and overreaction in asset markets. J Financ 54(6):2143–2184CrossRef
go back to reference Hong H, Lim T, Stein J (2000) Bad news travels slowly: size, analyst coverage and the profitability of momentum strategies. J Financ 55(1):265–295CrossRef Hong H, Lim T, Stein J (2000) Bad news travels slowly: size, analyst coverage and the profitability of momentum strategies. J Financ 55(1):265–295CrossRef
go back to reference Hung M-W, Yu H-Y (2006) A heterogeneous model of disposition effect. Appl Econ 38(18):2147–2157CrossRef Hung M-W, Yu H-Y (2006) A heterogeneous model of disposition effect. Appl Econ 38(18):2147–2157CrossRef
go back to reference Ji L-J, Nisbett R, Su Y (2001) Culture, change, and prediction. Psychol Sci 12(6):450–456CrossRef Ji L-J, Nisbett R, Su Y (2001) Culture, change, and prediction. Psychol Sci 12(6):450–456CrossRef
go back to reference Jiang G, Lee C, Zhang Y (2005) Information uncertainty and expected returns. Rev Acc Stud 10(2):185–221CrossRef Jiang G, Lee C, Zhang Y (2005) Information uncertainty and expected returns. Rev Acc Stud 10(2):185–221CrossRef
go back to reference Jin L, Scherbina A (2011) Inheriting losers. Rev Financ Stud 24(3):786–820CrossRef Jin L, Scherbina A (2011) Inheriting losers. Rev Financ Stud 24(3):786–820CrossRef
go back to reference Johnson T (2004) Forecast dispersion and the cross section of expected returns. J Financ 59(5):1957–1978CrossRef Johnson T (2004) Forecast dispersion and the cross section of expected returns. J Financ 59(5):1957–1978CrossRef
go back to reference Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision making under risk. Econometrica 47(2):263–292CrossRef Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision making under risk. Econometrica 47(2):263–292CrossRef
go back to reference Kaniel R, Saar G, Titman S (2008) Individual investor trading and stock returns. J Financ 63(1):273–310CrossRef Kaniel R, Saar G, Titman S (2008) Individual investor trading and stock returns. J Financ 63(1):273–310CrossRef
go back to reference Kaustia M (2010) Prospect theory and the disposition effect. J Financ Quant Anal 45(3):791–812CrossRef Kaustia M (2010) Prospect theory and the disposition effect. J Financ Quant Anal 45(3):791–812CrossRef
go back to reference Kumar A (2009) Hard-to-value stocks, behavioral biases and informed trading. J Financ Quant Anal 44(6):1375–1401CrossRef Kumar A (2009) Hard-to-value stocks, behavioral biases and informed trading. J Financ Quant Anal 44(6):1375–1401CrossRef
go back to reference Li Y, Yang L (2008) Prospect theory, the disposition effect and asset prices. Working paper Li Y, Yang L (2008) Prospect theory, the disposition effect and asset prices. Working paper
go back to reference Locke P, Mann S (2005) Professional trader discipline and trade disposition. J Financ Econ 76(2):401–444CrossRef Locke P, Mann S (2005) Professional trader discipline and trade disposition. J Financ Econ 76(2):401–444CrossRef
go back to reference Makarov I, Rytchkov O (2012) Forecasting the forecasts of others: implications for asset pricing. J Econ Theory 147(3):941–966CrossRef Makarov I, Rytchkov O (2012) Forecasting the forecasts of others: implications for asset pricing. J Econ Theory 147(3):941–966CrossRef
go back to reference Muermann A, Volkman J (2006) Regret, pride and the disposition effect. Working paper Muermann A, Volkman J (2006) Regret, pride and the disposition effect. Working paper
go back to reference O’Curry Fogel S, Berry T (2006) The disposition effect and individual investor decisions: the roles of regret and counterfactual alternatives. J Behav Financ 7(2):107–116CrossRef O’Curry Fogel S, Berry T (2006) The disposition effect and individual investor decisions: the roles of regret and counterfactual alternatives. J Behav Financ 7(2):107–116CrossRef
go back to reference Odean T (1998) Are investors reluctant to realize their losses? J Financ 53(5):1775–1798CrossRef Odean T (1998) Are investors reluctant to realize their losses? J Financ 53(5):1775–1798CrossRef
go back to reference Ranguelova E (2001) Disposition effect and firm size: new evidence on individual investor trading activity. Working paper Ranguelova E (2001) Disposition effect and firm size: new evidence on individual investor trading activity. Working paper
go back to reference Shefrin H, Statman M (1985) The disposition to sell winners too early and ride losers too long: theory and evidence. J Financ 40(3):777–790CrossRef Shefrin H, Statman M (1985) The disposition to sell winners too early and ride losers too long: theory and evidence. J Financ 40(3):777–790CrossRef
go back to reference Shumway T, Wu G (2009) Does disposition drive momentum? Working paper Shumway T, Wu G (2009) Does disposition drive momentum? Working paper
go back to reference Talpsepp T, Vlcek M, Wang M (2014) Speculating in gains, waiting in losses: a closer look at the disposition effect. J Behav Exp Financ 2:31–43CrossRef Talpsepp T, Vlcek M, Wang M (2014) Speculating in gains, waiting in losses: a closer look at the disposition effect. J Behav Exp Financ 2:31–43CrossRef
go back to reference Tversky A, Kahneman D (1992) Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty. J Risk Uncert 5(4):297–323CrossRef Tversky A, Kahneman D (1992) Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty. J Risk Uncert 5(4):297–323CrossRef
go back to reference Wang Q, Zhang J (2015) Individual investor trading and stock liquidity. Rev Quant Financ Acc 45(3):485–508CrossRef Wang Q, Zhang J (2015) Individual investor trading and stock liquidity. Rev Quant Financ Acc 45(3):485–508CrossRef
go back to reference Weber M, Camerer C (1998) The disposition effect in securities trading: an experimental analysis. J Econ Behav Organ 33(2):167–184CrossRef Weber M, Camerer C (1998) The disposition effect in securities trading: an experimental analysis. J Econ Behav Organ 33(2):167–184CrossRef
go back to reference Weber M, Welfens F (2008) Splitting the disposition effect: asymmetric reactions towards “selling winners” and “holding losers”. Working paper, University of Mannheim Weber M, Welfens F (2008) Splitting the disposition effect: asymmetric reactions towards “selling winners” and “holding losers”. Working paper, University of Mannheim
go back to reference Zhang F (2006) Information uncertainty and stock returns. J Financ 61(1):105–137CrossRef Zhang F (2006) Information uncertainty and stock returns. J Financ 61(1):105–137CrossRef
go back to reference Zuchel H (2001) What drives the disposition effect? Working paper, University of Mannheim Zuchel H (2001) What drives the disposition effect? Working paper, University of Mannheim
Metadata
Title
Disposition effect and analyst forecast dispersion
Author
Daniela Vesselinova Balkanska
Publication date
17-06-2017
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting / Issue 3/2018
Print ISSN: 0924-865X
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7179
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-017-0648-7

Other articles of this Issue 3/2018

Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 3/2018 Go to the issue