Skip to main content
Top

2017 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

8. Empirical Models of Learning Dynamics: A Survey of Recent Developments

Authors : Andrew T. Ching, Tülin Erdem, Michael P. Keane

Published in: Handbook of Marketing Decision Models

Publisher: Springer International Publishing

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

There is now a very large literature on dynamic learning models in marketing. Learning dynamics can be broadly defined as encompassing any process whereby the prior history of a consumer or market affects current utility evaluations (e.g., social learning, search, correlated learning, information spillover, etc.). In the present chapter, we focus on discussing this rapidly growing literature that deals with this broader view of learning dynamics.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
Given habit persistence or learning, past purchase creates exposure to a product, which directly affects a consumer’s perceived utility of a product. In an inventory model, past purchase matters because it affects current inventory, but also, more subtly, because the prices at which past purchases are made affect the reference price of the product.
 
2
In order to implement their model, Erdem and Keane (1996) used the approximate solution methods for dynamic programming models developed in Keane and Wolpin (1994). See Ching et al. (2013) for a complete explanation of the procedure. The simplifying assumptions in Eckstein et al. (1988) allowed them to use the Gittin’s index to find the solution of their model (see Appendix A of Ching et al. 2013).
 
3
For instance, a diaper may hold all of a baby’s urine on some occasions but not on others (depending on how much milk the baby drank), so one use may not fully reveal its quality.
 
4
Note that this is equivalent to say \(I_{it}\) consists of all past signals consumer i has received before he/she makes the purchase at time t, given the Bayesian learning framework.
 
5
Still, heterogeneity in S it may persist over time, because: (i) both brands and consumers are finitely lived, (ii) as people gather more information the value of trial purchases diminishes, and so eventually learning about unfamiliar products will become slow; (iii) there is a flow of new brands and new consumers entering a market.
 
6
Ching et al. (2013) explain how to extend the above basic framework to allow consumers to learn from multiple information sources (such as advertising, word-of-mouth and so on).
 
7
In almost all cases no purchase is also an option. Erdem and Keane (1996) denote the no purchase option as j = 0, and simply set the expected utility of no purchase to \(E\left[ {U_{i0} |S_{it} } \right] = e_{i0t}\).
 
8
card(.) is the cardinality of the set in question. It measures the number of elements in the set.
 
9
Hendrick et al. (2012) propose a similar framework to study how consumers choose a product among J > 2 alternatives. Newberry (2016) extends this framework to study the role of pricing in observational learning using data from an online market for music.
 
10
The models in these papers largely adopt the framework discussed so far, and hence we will not devote space to explicitly discussing their structure.
 
11
The likelihood of their model involves multiple integrals because the explanatory variables include lagged latent dependent variables and serially correlated errors, but they show that the GHK simulator remains tractable for this generalized framework (see Keane 1994).
 
12
Ching (2010b) allows for multiple generic firms. In addition, generic firms’ entry decisions are also endogenous. But since the focus of this chapter is learning, we abstract away the entry decisions when describing the model.
 
13
It is the choice probability of choosing product j multiplied by the total number of potential patients in this market.
 
14
Although this paper does not explicitly model a dynamic game, the dynamic demand model is very useful in evaluating the consequences of Marlboro’s strategic response to the competition of generic brands.
 
15
The basic idea of this model is that players in a game vary in their depth of strategic thinking. A completely naïve player will choose actions by completely ignoring the presence of other players (level zero). A level one player believes that other players will not react to his choice, and his action is the best response with respect to this belief. A level two player believes that all other players are level one, and so on and so forth. This model captures bounded rationality, and can explain players’ behavior in games that cannot be rationalized by standard game theory.
 
16
The efficiency ratio measures how well a drug converts reduced cholesterol levels to reduced heart disease risks.
 
17
Note that the basic idea of search models is that consumers need to compare the expected gain from searching vs. the cost of search. In contrast, standard choice models with learning assume that consumers learn about an attribute by buying the product multiple times because information signals are noisy. These models also assume there are a fixed number of alternatives to choose from. In search models with an unknown price (or attribute) distribution, consumers learn about the parameters that characterize the distribution. For a normal distribution, that would be simply learning its mean and standard deviation. But, for a Dirichlet distribution, a consumer needs to use the whole history of price realizations and the initial parameters that characterize the prior to construct his posterior.
 
18
This is in contrast to static models, where the current expected utilities, \(E[U(Q_{jt}^{E} ,P_{jt} )|I_{t} ]\), alone determines choice probabilities.
 
19
In labor economics, researchers may argue that wages capture much of the current payoff. Or, researchers can control current payoffs in a lab experiment (e.g., Houser et al. 2004).
 
20
Each sub-problem can be characterized as follows. A consumer either chooses a fixed reward in each period forever, or chooses brand j this period. If he/she chooses brand j this period, a noisy quality signal about brand j will be revealed, and then the consumer faces these two choices again next period. The reasons the index method provides significant computational gains are: (a) it reduces the size of the state space from N J to J × N, where N is the number of state points associated with each alternative, and (b) solving for the index strategy for J optimal stopping problems is much less costly compared with solving one J dimensional dynamic programming problem.
 
21
To see this, compare Eq. (8.28) with Eqs. (8.29)–(8.30). Clearly, the GK approach amounts to choosing a parameterization for the \(G(j,0,I_{t} )\) function.
 
22
Another example is that the advent of internet retailing has made it possible to do comparison shopping from home, thus arguably reducing the costs of gathering information. An interesting hypothesis is that this change in the environment may have caused consumers to engage in more comparison shopping.
 
23
One way to interpret our argument is that only structural models attempt to predict what decision rules consumers will adopt in a new environment (indeed, this is precisely what structural models are designed to do). But that doesn’t mean their predictions will necessarily be correct. It is important to keep in mind the point that a structural model is only invariant to all conceivable environmental changes if it is perfectly correctly specified—that is, if it is in fact the “true model.” As all models are ultimately false (as they are simplifications), a completely policy invariant model is an aspirational goal, not a reality. The best we can do in practice is to incrementally validate a structural model by showing that it predicts well across a range of policy environments. This may give us confidence in using the model to predict in a new environment. But we can never be certain that the new environment won’t be the one that reveals the flaw in the model! As a practical matter, the best we can hope for is to build structural models we are confident in using for certain types of policy predictions, but perhaps not for others (i.e., it is perfectly possible that a structural model can reliably predict responses to some types of policy changes but not others—just as we see with commonly used models in the physical sciences and engineering). See Keane (2010) for further discussion of these issues.
 
24
Interestingly, higher-income borrowers learn twice as fast, and forget twice as slowly, as lower-income borrowers.
 
25
An exception is Yang and Ching (2014) who develop and estimate a consumer life-cycle model to explain the adoption decision of a new technology.
 
26
CEK’s work was originally motivated by the observation that brand choice conditional on category purchase is very sensitive to price, while the decision to make a purchase in a category is quite insenitive to price. CEK showed that these seemingly contradictory facts could be explained if consumers only occasionally look at (i.e., consider) a category.
 
27
In the optimal solution consumers should consider a category in every period regardless of their inventory. Even if inventory is high, a low enough price would make it optimal to stock up even more.
 
Literature
go back to reference Agarwal, Sumit, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson. 2013. Learning in the credit market. Working paper. Agarwal, Sumit, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson. 2013. Learning in the credit market. Working paper.
go back to reference Aguirregabiria, V., and P. Mira. 2007. Sequential estimation of dynamic discrete games. Econometrica 75 (1): 1–53.CrossRef Aguirregabiria, V., and P. Mira. 2007. Sequential estimation of dynamic discrete games. Econometrica 75 (1): 1–53.CrossRef
go back to reference Chan, T., J. Li, and L. Pierce. 2014. Learning from peers: Knowledge transfer and sales force productivity growth. Marketing Science 33 (4): 463–484. Chan, T., J. Li, and L. Pierce. 2014. Learning from peers: Knowledge transfer and sales force productivity growth. Marketing Science 33 (4): 463–484.
go back to reference Che, Hai, Tülin Erdem, and T. Sabri Öncü. 2015. Consumer learning and evolution of consumer brand preferences. Quantitative Marketing and Economics 13 (3): 173–202.CrossRef Che, Hai, Tülin Erdem, and T. Sabri Öncü. 2015. Consumer learning and evolution of consumer brand preferences. Quantitative Marketing and Economics 13 (3): 173–202.CrossRef
go back to reference Chen, T., B. Sun, and V. Singh. 2009. An empirical investigation of the dynamic effect of marlboro’s permanent pricing shift. Marketing Science 28 (4): 740–758.CrossRef Chen, T., B. Sun, and V. Singh. 2009. An empirical investigation of the dynamic effect of marlboro’s permanent pricing shift. Marketing Science 28 (4): 740–758.CrossRef
go back to reference Ching, A.T. 2010a. Consumer learning and heterogeneity: dynamics of demand for prescription drugs after patent expiration. International Journal of Industrial Organization 28 (6): 619–638.CrossRef Ching, A.T. 2010a. Consumer learning and heterogeneity: dynamics of demand for prescription drugs after patent expiration. International Journal of Industrial Organization 28 (6): 619–638.CrossRef
go back to reference Ching, A.T. 2010b. A dynamic oligopoly structural model for the prescription drug market after patent expiration. International Economic Review 51 (4): 1175–1207.CrossRef Ching, A.T. 2010b. A dynamic oligopoly structural model for the prescription drug market after patent expiration. International Economic Review 51 (4): 1175–1207.CrossRef
go back to reference Ching, A., T. Erdem, and M. Keane. 2009. The Price Consideration Model of Brand Choice. Journal of Applied Econometrics 24 (3): 393–420.CrossRef Ching, A., T. Erdem, and M. Keane. 2009. The Price Consideration Model of Brand Choice. Journal of Applied Econometrics 24 (3): 393–420.CrossRef
go back to reference Ching, A.T., T. Erdem, and M. Keane. 2013. Learning Models: An Assessment of Progress, Challenges and New Developments. Marketing Science 32 (6): 913–938. Ching, A.T., T. Erdem, and M. Keane. 2013. Learning Models: An Assessment of Progress, Challenges and New Developments. Marketing Science 32 (6): 913–938.
go back to reference Ching, A.T., T. Erdem, and M. Keane. 2014a. A Simple method to Estimate the Roles of Learning, Inventories and Category Consideration in Consumer Choice. Journal of Choice Modelling 13: 60–72. Ching, A.T., T. Erdem, and M. Keane. 2014a. A Simple method to Estimate the Roles of Learning, Inventories and Category Consideration in Consumer Choice. Journal of Choice Modelling 13: 60–72.
go back to reference Ching, A.T., T. Erdem, and M. Keane. 2014b. How much do consumers know about the quality of products? Evidence from the diaper market. Working paper, Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto. Ching, A.T., T. Erdem, and M. Keane. 2014b. How much do consumers know about the quality of products? Evidence from the diaper market. Working paper, Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto.
go back to reference Ching, A.T., R. Clark, I. Horstmann, and H. Lim. 2016. The effects of publicity on demand: the case of anti-cholesterol drugs. Marketing Science 35 (1): 158–181. Ching, A.T., R. Clark, I. Horstmann, and H. Lim. 2016. The effects of publicity on demand: the case of anti-cholesterol drugs. Marketing Science 35 (1): 158–181.
go back to reference Ching, A.T., and M. Ishihara. 2010. The effects of detailing on prescribing decisions under quality uncertainty. Quantitative Marketing and Economics 8 (2): 123–165.CrossRef Ching, A.T., and M. Ishihara. 2010. The effects of detailing on prescribing decisions under quality uncertainty. Quantitative Marketing and Economics 8 (2): 123–165.CrossRef
go back to reference Ching, A.T., and H. Lim 2016. A Structural analysis of correlated learning and late-mover advantages: The case of statins. Working paper, Rotman School of Management, U of Toronto. Ching, A.T., and H. Lim 2016. A Structural analysis of correlated learning and late-mover advantages: The case of statins. Working paper, Rotman School of Management, U of Toronto.
go back to reference Davis, L. 2004. The effect of health risk on housing values: evidence from a cancer cluster. American Economic Review 94 (5): 1693–1704. Davis, L. 2004. The effect of health risk on housing values: evidence from a cancer cluster. American Economic Review 94 (5): 1693–1704.
go back to reference De los Santos, B., A. Hortacsu, M. R. Wildenbeest. 2013. Search with learning. Working paper, Kelley School of Business, Indiana University. De los Santos, B., A. Hortacsu, M. R. Wildenbeest. 2013. Search with learning. Working paper, Kelley School of Business, Indiana University.
go back to reference Dzyabura, D., and J.R. Hauser. 2011. Active Machine Learning for Consideration Heuristics. Marketing Science 30 (5): 801–819.CrossRef Dzyabura, D., and J.R. Hauser. 2011. Active Machine Learning for Consideration Heuristics. Marketing Science 30 (5): 801–819.CrossRef
go back to reference Eckstein, Z., D. Horsky, and Y. Raban. 1988. An empirical dynamic model of brand choice. Working paper 88, University of Rochester. Eckstein, Z., D. Horsky, and Y. Raban. 1988. An empirical dynamic model of brand choice. Working paper 88, University of Rochester.
go back to reference Erdem, T. 1998. An empirical analysis of umbrella branding. Journal of Marketing Research 35 (3): 339–351.CrossRef Erdem, T. 1998. An empirical analysis of umbrella branding. Journal of Marketing Research 35 (3): 339–351.CrossRef
go back to reference Erdem, T., and M. Keane. 1996. Decision-making under uncertainty: capturing dynamic brand choice processes in turbulent consumer goods markets. Marketing Science 15 (1): 1–20.CrossRef Erdem, T., and M. Keane. 1996. Decision-making under uncertainty: capturing dynamic brand choice processes in turbulent consumer goods markets. Marketing Science 15 (1): 1–20.CrossRef
go back to reference Erdem, T., M. Keane, S. Oncu, and J. Strebel. 2005. Learning about computers: an analysis of information search and technology choice. Quantitative Marketing and Economics 3 (3): 207–246.CrossRef Erdem, T., M. Keane, S. Oncu, and J. Strebel. 2005. Learning about computers: an analysis of information search and technology choice. Quantitative Marketing and Economics 3 (3): 207–246.CrossRef
go back to reference Erdem, T., M. Keane, and B. Sun. 2008. A dynamic model of brand choice when price and advertising signal product quality. Marketing Science 27 (6): 1111–1125.CrossRef Erdem, T., M. Keane, and B. Sun. 2008. A dynamic model of brand choice when price and advertising signal product quality. Marketing Science 27 (6): 1111–1125.CrossRef
go back to reference Gabaix, X., and D. Laibson. 2000. A boundedly rational decision algorithm. American Economic Review 90 (2): 433–438.CrossRef Gabaix, X., and D. Laibson. 2000. A boundedly rational decision algorithm. American Economic Review 90 (2): 433–438.CrossRef
go back to reference Gallaghier, J. 2014. Learning about an infrequent event: evidence from flood insurance take-up in the United States. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 6 (3): 206–233. Gallaghier, J. 2014. Learning about an infrequent event: evidence from flood insurance take-up in the United States. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 6 (3): 206–233.
go back to reference Geweke, J., and M. Keane. 2000. Bayesian inference for dynamic discrete choice models without the need for dynamic programming. In Simulation based inference and econometrics: methods and applications, eds. Mariano, Schuermann and Weeks, 100–131. Cambridge University Press. Geweke, J., and M. Keane. 2000. Bayesian inference for dynamic discrete choice models without the need for dynamic programming. In Simulation based inference and econometrics: methods and applications, eds. Mariano, Schuermann and Weeks, 100–131. Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Geweke, J., and M. Keane. 2001. Computationally Intensive Methods for Integration in Econometrics. In Handbook of econometrics: vol. 5, Heckman, J.J., and E.E. Leamer eds., Elsevier Science B.V., 3463–3568. Geweke, J., and M. Keane. 2001. Computationally Intensive Methods for Integration in Econometrics. In Handbook of econometrics: vol. 5, Heckman, J.J., and E.E. Leamer eds., Elsevier Science B.V., 3463–3568.
go back to reference Gittins, J., and D. Jones. 1974. A dynamic allocation index for the sequential design of experiments. In Progress in Statistics, ed. J. Gani, K. Sarkadi, and I. Vince, 241–266. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Gittins, J., and D. Jones. 1974. A dynamic allocation index for the sequential design of experiments. In Progress in Statistics, ed. J. Gani, K. Sarkadi, and I. Vince, 241–266. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
go back to reference Godlonton, S., and R.L. Thornton. 2013. Learning from others’ HIV testing: updating beliefs and responding to risk. American Review Papers and Proceedings 103 (3): 439–444.CrossRef Godlonton, S., and R.L. Thornton. 2013. Learning from others’ HIV testing: updating beliefs and responding to risk. American Review Papers and Proceedings 103 (3): 439–444.CrossRef
go back to reference Guadagni, P.M., and John D.C. Little. 1983. A logit model of brand choice calibrated on scanner data. Marketing Science 2 (3): 203–238.CrossRef Guadagni, P.M., and John D.C. Little. 1983. A logit model of brand choice calibrated on scanner data. Marketing Science 2 (3): 203–238.CrossRef
go back to reference Hauser, J.R., G.L. Urban, G. Liberali, and M. Braun. 2009. Website Morphing. Marketing Science. 28 (2): 202–223.CrossRef Hauser, J.R., G.L. Urban, G. Liberali, and M. Braun. 2009. Website Morphing. Marketing Science. 28 (2): 202–223.CrossRef
go back to reference Heckman, J.J. 1981. Statistical models for discrete choice panel data. In Structural analysis of discrete data with econometric applications, eds. Manski, C.F., and D. McFadden, 114–178. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Heckman, J.J. 1981. Statistical models for discrete choice panel data. In Structural analysis of discrete data with econometric applications, eds. Manski, C.F., and D. McFadden, 114–178. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
go back to reference Hendrick, K., A. Sorensen, and T. Wiseman. 2012. Observational learning and demand for search goods. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 4 (1): 1–31. Hendrick, K., A. Sorensen, and T. Wiseman. 2012. Observational learning and demand for search goods. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 4 (1): 1–31.
go back to reference Ho, T.-H., S.-E. Park, and X. Su. 2015. A bayesian level-k model in n-person games. Working paper. Ho, T.-H., S.-E. Park, and X. Su. 2015. A bayesian level-k model in n-person games. Working paper.
go back to reference Houser, D., M. Keane, and K. McCabe. 2004. Behavior in a dynamic decision problem: an analysis of experimental evidence using a bayesian type classification algorithm. Econometrica 72 (3): 781–822.CrossRef Houser, D., M. Keane, and K. McCabe. 2004. Behavior in a dynamic decision problem: an analysis of experimental evidence using a bayesian type classification algorithm. Econometrica 72 (3): 781–822.CrossRef
go back to reference Howard, R.A. 1966. Information Value Theory. IEEE Transactions on System Science and Cybernetics 2 (1): 22–26.CrossRef Howard, R.A. 1966. Information Value Theory. IEEE Transactions on System Science and Cybernetics 2 (1): 22–26.CrossRef
go back to reference Huang, G., H. Luo, and J. Xia. 2015. Invest in information or wing it? A model of dynamic pricing with seller learning. Working paper, Carnegie Mello University. Huang, G., H. Luo, and J. Xia. 2015. Invest in information or wing it? A model of dynamic pricing with seller learning. Working paper, Carnegie Mello University.
go back to reference Hummel, P., and B. Knight. 2015. Sequential or simultaneous elections? A Welfare Analysis. International Economic Review 56 (3): 851–887. Hummel, P., and B. Knight. 2015. Sequential or simultaneous elections? A Welfare Analysis. International Economic Review 56 (3): 851–887.
go back to reference Keane, M. 1994. A computationally practical simulation estimator for panel data. Econometrica 62 (1): 95–116.CrossRef Keane, M. 1994. A computationally practical simulation estimator for panel data. Econometrica 62 (1): 95–116.CrossRef
go back to reference Keane, M. 2010. Structural versus atheoretic approaches to econometrics. Journal of Econometrics 156 (1): 3–20.CrossRef Keane, M. 2010. Structural versus atheoretic approaches to econometrics. Journal of Econometrics 156 (1): 3–20.CrossRef
go back to reference Keane, M. 2015. Panel data discrete choice models of consumer demand. In Oxford handbook of panel data, ed. Baltagi, B., Chapter 18, pp. 548–582 Oxford University Press. Keane, M. 2015. Panel data discrete choice models of consumer demand. In Oxford handbook of panel data, ed. Baltagi, B., Chapter 18, pp. 548–582 Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Keane, M., and S. Thorp. 2016. Complex decision making: the roles of cognitive limitations, cognitive decline and aging. In Handbook of the economics of population aging, Vol. 1B, J. Piggott, and A. Woodland, eds., Elsevier Science B.V., pp. 661-709. Keane, M., and S. Thorp. 2016. Complex decision making: the roles of cognitive limitations, cognitive decline and aging. In Handbook of the economics of population aging, Vol. 1B, J. Piggott, and A. Woodland, eds., Elsevier Science B.V., pp. 661-709.
go back to reference Keane, M., and K. Wolpin. 1994. The solution and estimation of discrete choice dynamic programming models by simulation: monte carlo evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics 76 (4): 648–672.CrossRef Keane, M., and K. Wolpin. 1994. The solution and estimation of discrete choice dynamic programming models by simulation: monte carlo evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics 76 (4): 648–672.CrossRef
go back to reference Ketcham, J.D., C. Lucabell, E.J. Miravete, and M.C. Roebuck. 2012. Sinking, swimming, or learning to swim in medicare Part D. American Economic Review 102 (6): 2639–2673.CrossRef Ketcham, J.D., C. Lucabell, E.J. Miravete, and M.C. Roebuck. 2012. Sinking, swimming, or learning to swim in medicare Part D. American Economic Review 102 (6): 2639–2673.CrossRef
go back to reference Ketcham, J.D., C. Lucabell, and C.A. Powers. 2015a. Paying attention or paying too much in medicare Part D. American Economic Review 105 (1): 204–233. Ketcham, J.D., C. Lucabell, and C.A. Powers. 2015a. Paying attention or paying too much in medicare Part D. American Economic Review 105 (1): 204–233.
go back to reference Ketcham, J.D., N.V. Kuminoff, and C.A. Powers. 2015b. Estimating the heterogeneous welfare effects of choice architecture: an application to the medicare prescription drug insurance market. Working paper, Arizona State University. Ketcham, J.D., N.V. Kuminoff, and C.A. Powers. 2015b. Estimating the heterogeneous welfare effects of choice architecture: an application to the medicare prescription drug insurance market. Working paper, Arizona State University.
go back to reference Knight, B., and N. Schiff. 2010. Momentum and social learning in presidential primaries. Journal of Political Economy 118 (6): 1110–1150.CrossRef Knight, B., and N. Schiff. 2010. Momentum and social learning in presidential primaries. Journal of Political Economy 118 (6): 1110–1150.CrossRef
go back to reference Koulayev, S. 2013. Search with dirichlet priors: estimation and implications for consumer demand. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 31 (2): 226–239.CrossRef Koulayev, S. 2013. Search with dirichlet priors: estimation and implications for consumer demand. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 31 (2): 226–239.CrossRef
go back to reference Larcom, S., F. Rauch, and T. Willems. 2015. The benefits of forced experimentation: striking evidence from the London underground network. Working paper, University of Oxford. Larcom, S., F. Rauch, and T. Willems. 2015. The benefits of forced experimentation: striking evidence from the London underground network. Working paper, University of Oxford.
go back to reference Lee, J.Y., and D.R. Bell. 2013. Neighborhood social capital and social learning for experience attributes of products. Marketing Science 32 (6): 960–976.CrossRef Lee, J.Y., and D.R. Bell. 2013. Neighborhood social capital and social learning for experience attributes of products. Marketing Science 32 (6): 960–976.CrossRef
go back to reference Lin, S., J. Zhang, and J.R. Hauser. 2015. Learning from experience, Simply. Marketing Science 34 (1): 1–19. Lin, S., J. Zhang, and J.R. Hauser. 2015. Learning from experience, Simply. Marketing Science 34 (1): 1–19.
go back to reference Liu, Y., and M. Ishihara. 2015. Causal impact of online reviews on durable goods adoption: the case of the U.S. Video-Game market. Working paper, Stern School of Business, NYU. Liu, Y., and M. Ishihara. 2015. Causal impact of online reviews on durable goods adoption: the case of the U.S. Video-Game market. Working paper, Stern School of Business, NYU.
go back to reference Liu, X., J.H. Kagel, and L.F. Lee. 2012. Learning from peers in signaling game experiments. Journal of Applied Econometrics 27: 1037–1058.CrossRef Liu, X., J.H. Kagel, and L.F. Lee. 2012. Learning from peers in signaling game experiments. Journal of Applied Econometrics 27: 1037–1058.CrossRef
go back to reference Lovett, M.J., and R. Staelin. 2016. The role of paid, earned, and owned media in building entertainment brands: reminding, informing, and enhancing enjoyment. Marketing Science 35 (1): 142–157.CrossRef Lovett, M.J., and R. Staelin. 2016. The role of paid, earned, and owned media in building entertainment brands: reminding, informing, and enhancing enjoyment. Marketing Science 35 (1): 142–157.CrossRef
go back to reference Malmendier, U., and S. Nagel. 2011. Depression babies: do microeconomic experiences affect risk-taking? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (1): 373–416. Malmendier, U., and S. Nagel. 2011. Depression babies: do microeconomic experiences affect risk-taking? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (1): 373–416.
go back to reference Milgrom, P., and J. Roberts. 1982. Limit pricing and entry under incomplete information: an equilibrium analysis. Econometrica 50 (2): 443–459.CrossRef Milgrom, P., and J. Roberts. 1982. Limit pricing and entry under incomplete information: an equilibrium analysis. Econometrica 50 (2): 443–459.CrossRef
go back to reference Newberry, P.W. 2016. An empirical study of observational learning. RAND Journal of Economics 47 (2): 394–432.CrossRef Newberry, P.W. 2016. An empirical study of observational learning. RAND Journal of Economics 47 (2): 394–432.CrossRef
go back to reference Roberts, J., and G. Urban. 1988. Modelling multiattribute utility, risk, and belief dynamics for new consumer durable brand choice. Management Science 34 (2): 167–185.CrossRef Roberts, J., and G. Urban. 1988. Modelling multiattribute utility, risk, and belief dynamics for new consumer durable brand choice. Management Science 34 (2): 167–185.CrossRef
go back to reference Roos, J.M.T., C.F. Mela, and R. Shachar. 2015. The effect of links and excerts on internet news consumption. Working paper, Rotterdam School of Management, Erasmus University. Roos, J.M.T., C.F. Mela, and R. Shachar. 2015. The effect of links and excerts on internet news consumption. Working paper, Rotterdam School of Management, Erasmus University.
go back to reference Rothschild, M. 1974. Searching for lowest price when the distributino of prices is unknown. Journal of Political Economy 82 (4): 689–711.CrossRef Rothschild, M. 1974. Searching for lowest price when the distributino of prices is unknown. Journal of Political Economy 82 (4): 689–711.CrossRef
go back to reference Sauer, Robert M. 2015. Does it pay for women to volunteer? International Economic Review 56 (2): 537–564.CrossRef Sauer, Robert M. 2015. Does it pay for women to volunteer? International Economic Review 56 (2): 537–564.CrossRef
go back to reference Sudhir, K., and N. Yang. 2015. Exploiting the choice-consumption mismatch: A new approach to disentagle state dependence and heterogenity. Working paper. Sudhir, K., and N. Yang. 2015. Exploiting the choice-consumption mismatch: A new approach to disentagle state dependence and heterogenity. Working paper.
go back to reference Szymanowski, M., and E. Gijsbrechts. 2012. Consumption-based cross-brand learning: are private labels really private? Journal of Marketing Research. XLIX (April), 231–246. Szymanowski, M., and E. Gijsbrechts. 2012. Consumption-based cross-brand learning: are private labels really private? Journal of Marketing Research. XLIX (April), 231–246.
go back to reference Tehrani, Shervin S., and A.T. Ching. 2016. A heuristic approach to explore: value of perfect information. Working paper, Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto. Tehrani, Shervin S., and A.T. Ching. 2016. A heuristic approach to explore: value of perfect information. Working paper, Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto.
go back to reference Wei, Y. 2015. Imitation versus innovation: product similarity network in the motion picture industry. Working paper, University of Pennsylvania. Wei, Y. 2015. Imitation versus innovation: product similarity network in the motion picture industry. Working paper, University of Pennsylvania.
go back to reference Whittle, P. 1988. Restless bandits: activity allocation in a changing world. Journal of Applied Probability 25 (2): 287–298.CrossRef Whittle, P. 1988. Restless bandits: activity allocation in a changing world. Journal of Applied Probability 25 (2): 287–298.CrossRef
go back to reference Wu, C., H. Che, T.Y. Chan, and X. Lu. 2015. The economic value of online reviews. Marketing Science 34 (5): 739–754.CrossRef Wu, C., H. Che, T.Y. Chan, and X. Lu. 2015. The economic value of online reviews. Marketing Science 34 (5): 739–754.CrossRef
go back to reference Yang, B., and A.T. Ching. 2014. Dynamics of consumer adoption of financial innovation: the case of ATM cards. Management Science 60 (4): 903–922.CrossRef Yang, B., and A.T. Ching. 2014. Dynamics of consumer adoption of financial innovation: the case of ATM cards. Management Science 60 (4): 903–922.CrossRef
go back to reference Yang, N. 2016. Learning in retail entry. Working paper, McGill University. Yang, N. 2016. Learning in retail entry. Working paper, McGill University.
go back to reference Zhang, J. 2010. The sound of silence: observational learning in the U.S. kidney market. Marketing Science 29 (2): 315–335.CrossRef Zhang, J. 2010. The sound of silence: observational learning in the U.S. kidney market. Marketing Science 29 (2): 315–335.CrossRef
go back to reference Zhao, Y., S. Yang, V. Narayan, and Y. Zhao. 2013. Modeling consumer learning from online product reviews. Marketing Science 32 (1): 153–169.CrossRef Zhao, Y., S. Yang, V. Narayan, and Y. Zhao. 2013. Modeling consumer learning from online product reviews. Marketing Science 32 (1): 153–169.CrossRef
go back to reference Zou, D. 2014. Intertemporal pricing of new products: incentivizing consumer learning and inertia. Working paper, Booth School of Business, University of Chicago. Zou, D. 2014. Intertemporal pricing of new products: incentivizing consumer learning and inertia. Working paper, Booth School of Business, University of Chicago.
Metadata
Title
Empirical Models of Learning Dynamics: A Survey of Recent Developments
Authors
Andrew T. Ching
Tülin Erdem
Michael P. Keane
Copyright Year
2017
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-56941-3_8

Premium Partner