Skip to main content
Top
Published in: The Review of International Organizations 3/2016

03-07-2015

Enduring trade disputes: Disguised protectionism and duration and recurrence of international trade disputes

Author: Moonhawk Kim

Published in: The Review of International Organizations | Issue 3/2016

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Why do some WTO trade disputes endure and recur while others do not? States have difficulty resolving trade conflicts when they involve certain types of trade-restrictive domestic regulations. While such regulations vary in their extent of legitimacy—fulfilling non-trade domestic regulatory objectives and availability of less trade-restrictive options—complainant states cannot always distinguish legitimate barriers from illegitimate ones. In such scenarios of disguised protectionism, which I argue is most prevalent with policies involving WTO’s Sanitary and Phytosanitary (SPS) Agreement, disputants confront difficulties concluding their disputes. Disputes last longer and are more likely to recur. I test the argument against a data set of WTO disputes structured in an innovative manner—one that links together related and recurring disputes into single conflicts. Both an event history analysis of conflict duration and a count analysis of conflict recurrence using this data strongly support this argument.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
See Leitner and Lester (2015) and the preceding annual pieces for descriptive summaries of trade disputes at the WTO.
 
2
“China–U.S. Trade Dispute Has Broad Implications,” The New York Times, September 15, 2009.
 
3
I thank Leslie Johns for suggesting this framework for casting the two types. The formulation is also similar to Carrubba (2005), in which two countries have different costs to compliance.
 
4
The existence of alternative policies that are multilaterally more acceptable as a component of legitimacy is similar to Pelc (2010).
 
5
Alternatively, the complainants’ discount factor can be specified so that they choose to settle now rather than engage in a drawn-out bargaining against the sincere type.
 
6
A contrasting approach would be to have different time horizons and discount values for the bargainers (e.g., Cramton 1984).
 
7
The parameter that captures the uncertainty in Grossman and Perry (1986b) is a probability distribution F(r) bounded by r l , a low reservation value assessment of the respondent type by the complainant and r h , a high reservation value. The information precision is decreasing in the distance between the bounds.
 
8
“Understanding the WTO Agreement on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures.” World Trade Organization (WTO). https://​www.​wto.​org/​english/​tratop_​e/​sps_​e/​spsund_​e.​htm. Accessed May 12, 2015.
 
9
Accordingly, this is different from Bown and Reynolds (2015), who identify common disputes based on repeating patterns of complainant-disputed policy.
 
10
The results of these robustness checks are available on the journal’s website.
 
12
The results of these robustness checks are available on the journal’s website.
 
13
For the EU, the rounded average Polity score among the evolving membership does not fall below 10.
 
14
An alternative approach would track changes in respondents’ policy, which can mark the start of a conflict a la Bown and Reynolds (2015).
 
15
TRIMs has the lowest maximum number of provisions cited—4—and the fewest cases of positive counts.
 
Literature
go back to reference Allee, T. (2004). Legal incentives and domestic rewards: The selection of trade disputes for GATT/WTO dispute resolution. Allee, T. (2004). Legal incentives and domestic rewards: The selection of trade disputes for GATT/WTO dispute resolution.
go back to reference Allee, T. (2005). The political and economic value of GATT/WTO dispute initiation. In In 2005 annual meeting of the american political science association. Washington, DC: American Political Science Association. Allee, T. (2005). The political and economic value of GATT/WTO dispute initiation. In In 2005 annual meeting of the american political science association. Washington, DC: American Political Science Association.
go back to reference Allee, T. L., & Huth, P. K. (2006). Legitimizing dispute settlement: international legal rulings as dometic political cover. American Political Science Review, 100(2), 219–234.CrossRef Allee, T. L., & Huth, P. K. (2006). Legitimizing dispute settlement: international legal rulings as dometic political cover. American Political Science Review, 100(2), 219–234.CrossRef
go back to reference Barton, J., et al. (2006). The evolution of the trade regime: Politics, law and economics of the GATT and WTO. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Barton, J., et al. (2006). The evolution of the trade regime: Politics, law and economics of the GATT and WTO. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Beaulieu, E., & Gaisford, J. (2002). Labour and environmental standards: the ‘lemons problem’ in international trade policy. World Economy, 25(1), 59–78.CrossRef Beaulieu, E., & Gaisford, J. (2002). Labour and environmental standards: the ‘lemons problem’ in international trade policy. World Economy, 25(1), 59–78.CrossRef
go back to reference Bechtel, M. M., & Sattler, T. (2015). What is litigation in the world trade organization worth? International Organization. Bechtel, M. M., & Sattler, T. (2015). What is litigation in the world trade organization worth? International Organization.
go back to reference Bernauer, T. (2003). Genes, trade, and regulation: The seeds of conflict in food biotechnology. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Bernauer, T. (2003). Genes, trade, and regulation: The seeds of conflict in food biotechnology. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Bown, C. P. (2004). On the economic success of GATT/WTO dispute settlement. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(3), 811–823.CrossRef Bown, C. P. (2004). On the economic success of GATT/WTO dispute settlement. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(3), 811–823.CrossRef
go back to reference Bown, C. P., & Reynolds, K. M. (2014). Trade flows and trade disputes. Washington, DC: World Bank Development Research Group. Policy Research Working Paper.CrossRef Bown, C. P., & Reynolds, K. M. (2014). Trade flows and trade disputes. Washington, DC: World Bank Development Research Group. Policy Research Working Paper.CrossRef
go back to reference Bown, C. P., & Reynolds, K. M. (2015). Trade agreements and enforcement: Evidence from WTO dispute settlement. Washington, DC: World Bank Group—Development Research Group—Trade; International Integration Team. Policy Research Working Paper. Bown, C. P., & Reynolds, K. M. (2015). Trade agreements and enforcement: Evidence from WTO dispute settlement. Washington, DC: World Bank Group—Development Research Group—Trade; International Integration Team. Policy Research Working Paper.
go back to reference Bureau, J. C., Marette, S., & Schiavina, A. (1998). Non-tariff trade barriers and consumers’ information: the case of the EU-US trade dispute over beef. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 25(4), 437–462.CrossRef Bureau, J. C., Marette, S., & Schiavina, A. (1998). Non-tariff trade barriers and consumers’ information: the case of the EU-US trade dispute over beef. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 25(4), 437–462.CrossRef
go back to reference Busch, M. L., & Pelc, K. J. (2010). The politics of judicial economy at the world trade organization. International Organization, 64(2), 257–279.CrossRef Busch, M. L., & Pelc, K. J. (2010). The politics of judicial economy at the world trade organization. International Organization, 64(2), 257–279.CrossRef
go back to reference Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2000). Bargaining in the shadow of the law: early settlement in GATT/WTO disputes. Fordham International Law Journal, 24(1–2), 158–172. Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2000). Bargaining in the shadow of the law: early settlement in GATT/WTO disputes. Fordham International Law Journal, 24(1–2), 158–172.
go back to reference Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2002). Testing international trade law: Empirical studies of GATT/WTO dispute settlement. In D. L. M. Kennedy & J. D. Southwick (Eds.), The political economy of international trade law: Essays in honor of robert e. hudec (pp. 457–481). New York: Cambridge University Press. Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2002). Testing international trade law: Empirical studies of GATT/WTO dispute settlement. In D. L. M. Kennedy & J. D. Southwick (Eds.), The political economy of international trade law: Essays in honor of robert e. hudec (pp. 457–481). New York: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2003). Developing countries and general agreement on tariffs and trade/World trade organization dispute settlement. Journal of World Trade, 37(4), 719–735. Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2003). Developing countries and general agreement on tariffs and trade/World trade organization dispute settlement. Journal of World Trade, 37(4), 719–735.
go back to reference Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2006). Three’s a crowd: third parties and WTO dispute settlement. World Politics, 58(3), 446–477.CrossRef Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2006). Three’s a crowd: third parties and WTO dispute settlement. World Politics, 58(3), 446–477.CrossRef
go back to reference Carrubba, C. J. (2005). Courts and compliance in international regulatory regimes. Journal of Politics, 67(3), 669–689.CrossRef Carrubba, C. J. (2005). Courts and compliance in international regulatory regimes. Journal of Politics, 67(3), 669–689.CrossRef
go back to reference Chaudoin, S. (2014). Audiences features and the strategic timing of trade disputes. International Organization, 68(1), 1–35.CrossRef Chaudoin, S. (2014). Audiences features and the strategic timing of trade disputes. International Organization, 68(1), 1–35.CrossRef
go back to reference Chaudoin, S., Kucik, J., & Pelc, K. J. (2013). Do WTO disputes actually increase trade? Chaudoin, S., Kucik, J., & Pelc, K. J. (2013). Do WTO disputes actually increase trade?
go back to reference Cleves, M. et al. (2008). An introduction to survival analysis using stata. Second. Stata Press. Cleves, M. et al. (2008). An introduction to survival analysis using stata. Second. Stata Press.
go back to reference Cramton, P. C. (1984). Bargaining with incomplete information: an infinite-horizon model with two-sided uncertainty. Review of Economic Studies, 51(4), 579–593.CrossRef Cramton, P. C. (1984). Bargaining with incomplete information: an infinite-horizon model with two-sided uncertainty. Review of Economic Studies, 51(4), 579–593.CrossRef
go back to reference Davis, C. L. (2012). Why adjudicate? Enforcing trade rules in the WTO. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Davis, C. L. (2012). Why adjudicate? Enforcing trade rules in the WTO. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Davis, C. L., & Bermeo, S. B. (2009). Who files? Developing country participation in GATT/WTO adjudication. Journal of Politics, 71(3), 1033–1049.CrossRef Davis, C. L., & Bermeo, S. B. (2009). Who files? Developing country participation in GATT/WTO adjudication. Journal of Politics, 71(3), 1033–1049.CrossRef
go back to reference Davis, C. & Shirato, Y. (2007). Firms, governments, and WTO adjudication. 59(2): 274–313. Davis, C. & Shirato, Y. (2007). Firms, governments, and WTO adjudication. 59(2): 274–313.
go back to reference Elsig, M., & Stucki, P. (2012). Low-income developing countries and WTO litigation. 19(2), 292–316. Elsig, M., & Stucki, P. (2012). Low-income developing countries and WTO litigation. 19(2), 292–316.
go back to reference Esty, D. C. (1994). Greening the GATT: Trade, environment, and the future. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. Esty, D. C. (1994). Greening the GATT: Trade, environment, and the future. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.
go back to reference Fattore, C. (2013). The influence of legal capacity on WTO dispute duration. International Trade Journal, 27(5), 450–464.CrossRef Fattore, C. (2013). The influence of legal capacity on WTO dispute duration. International Trade Journal, 27(5), 450–464.CrossRef
go back to reference Goldstein, J. L., & Steinberg, R. H. (2009). Regulatory shift: The rise of judicial liberalization at the WTO. In W. Mattli & N. Woods (Eds.), The politics of global regulation (pp. 211–241). Princeton: Princeton University Press. Goldstein, J. L., & Steinberg, R. H. (2009). Regulatory shift: The rise of judicial liberalization at the WTO. In W. Mattli & N. Woods (Eds.), The politics of global regulation (pp. 211–241). Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Grinols, E. L., & Perrelli, R. (2006). The WTO impact on international trade disputes: an event history analysis. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4), 613–624.CrossRef Grinols, E. L., & Perrelli, R. (2006). The WTO impact on international trade disputes: an event history analysis. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4), 613–624.CrossRef
go back to reference Grossman, S. J., & Perry, M. (1986a). Perfect sequential equilibrium. Journal of Economic Theory, 39(1), 97–119.CrossRef Grossman, S. J., & Perry, M. (1986a). Perfect sequential equilibrium. Journal of Economic Theory, 39(1), 97–119.CrossRef
go back to reference Grossman, S. J., & Perry, M. (1986b). Sequential bargaining under asymmetric information. Journal of Economic Theory, 39(1), 120–154.CrossRef Grossman, S. J., & Perry, M. (1986b). Sequential bargaining under asymmetric information. Journal of Economic Theory, 39(1), 120–154.CrossRef
go back to reference Guzman, A., & Simmons, B. A. (2002). To settle or empanel? An empirical analysis of litigation and settlement at the world trade organization. Journal of Legal Studies, 31(1), S205–S235.CrossRef Guzman, A., & Simmons, B. A. (2002). To settle or empanel? An empirical analysis of litigation and settlement at the world trade organization. Journal of Legal Studies, 31(1), S205–S235.CrossRef
go back to reference Guzman, A. T., & Simmons, B. A. (2005). Power plays and capacity constraints: the selection of defendants in world trade organization disputes. Journal of Legal Studies, 34(2), 557–598.CrossRef Guzman, A. T., & Simmons, B. A. (2005). Power plays and capacity constraints: the selection of defendants in world trade organization disputes. Journal of Legal Studies, 34(2), 557–598.CrossRef
go back to reference Hobbs, J. E., Kerr, W. A., & Phillips, P. W. B. (2001). Identity preservation and international trade: signaling quality across national boundaries. Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 49(4), 567–579.CrossRef Hobbs, J. E., Kerr, W. A., & Phillips, P. W. B. (2001). Identity preservation and international trade: signaling quality across national boundaries. Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 49(4), 567–579.CrossRef
go back to reference Hofmann, T., & Kim, S. Y. (2010). The domestic politics of compliance: Explaining time-to-compliance in WTO disputes. In In Annual meeting of the american political science association. Washington, DC: American Political Science Association. Hofmann, T., & Kim, S. Y. (2010). The domestic politics of compliance: Explaining time-to-compliance in WTO disputes. In In Annual meeting of the american political science association. Washington, DC: American Political Science Association.
go back to reference Horn, H. & Mavroidis, P. C. (2013.) The WTO dispute settlement data set 1995–2011: User’s guide. 3.0. Horn, H. & Mavroidis, P. C. (2013.) The WTO dispute settlement data set 1995–2011: User’s guide. 3.0.
go back to reference Hudec, R. E. (1993). Enforcing international trade law: The evolution of the modern GATT legal system. Salem: Butterworth Legal Publishers. Hudec, R. E. (1993). Enforcing international trade law: The evolution of the modern GATT legal system. Salem: Butterworth Legal Publishers.
go back to reference Johns, L. & Pelc, K. J. (2014). Fear of crowds in WTO disputes: Why don’t more countries participate? Johns, L. & Pelc, K. J. (2014). Fear of crowds in WTO disputes: Why don’t more countries participate?
go back to reference Kerr, W. A. (1999). International trade in transgenic food products: a new focus for agricultural trade disputes. World Economy, 22(2), 245–259.CrossRef Kerr, W. A. (1999). International trade in transgenic food products: a new focus for agricultural trade disputes. World Economy, 22(2), 245–259.CrossRef
go back to reference Kim, M. (2008). Costly procedures: divergent effects of legalization in the GATT/WTO dispute settlement procedures. International Studies Quarterly, 52(3), 657–686.CrossRef Kim, M. (2008). Costly procedures: divergent effects of legalization in the GATT/WTO dispute settlement procedures. International Studies Quarterly, 52(3), 657–686.CrossRef
go back to reference Kim, M. (2012). Disguised protectionism and linkages to the GATT/WTO. World Politics, 64(3), 426–475.CrossRef Kim, M. (2012). Disguised protectionism and linkages to the GATT/WTO. World Politics, 64(3), 426–475.CrossRef
go back to reference Kono, D. Y. (2006). Optimal obfuscation: democracy and trade policy transparency. American Political Science Review, 100(3), 369–384.CrossRef Kono, D. Y. (2006). Optimal obfuscation: democracy and trade policy transparency. American Political Science Review, 100(3), 369–384.CrossRef
go back to reference Kucik, J., & Pelc, K. J. Forthcoming. Measuring the cost of privacy: A look at the distributional effects of private bargaining. British Journal of Political Science. Kucik, J., & Pelc, K. J. Forthcoming. Measuring the cost of privacy: A look at the distributional effects of private bargaining. British Journal of Political Science.
go back to reference Lawrence, R. Z. (2007). The united states and the WTO dispute settlement system. Washington, DC: Council on Foreign Relations. Council Special Reports. Lawrence, R. Z. (2007). The united states and the WTO dispute settlement system. Washington, DC: Council on Foreign Relations. Council Special Reports.
go back to reference Leitner, K., & Lester, S. (2015). WTO dispute settlement 1995–2014: a statistical analysis. Journal of International Economic Law, 18(1), 203–214.CrossRef Leitner, K., & Lester, S. (2015). WTO dispute settlement 1995–2014: a statistical analysis. Journal of International Economic Law, 18(1), 203–214.CrossRef
go back to reference Licht, A. A. (2011). Change comes with time: substantive interpretation of nonproportional hazards in event history analysis. Political Analysis, 19(2), 227–243.CrossRef Licht, A. A. (2011). Change comes with time: substantive interpretation of nonproportional hazards in event history analysis. Political Analysis, 19(2), 227–243.CrossRef
go back to reference Mansfield, E. D., & Reinhardt, E. (2003). Multilateral determinants of regionalism: the effects of GATT/WTO on the formation of preferential trading arrangements. International Organization, 57(4), 829–862.CrossRef Mansfield, E. D., & Reinhardt, E. (2003). Multilateral determinants of regionalism: the effects of GATT/WTO on the formation of preferential trading arrangements. International Organization, 57(4), 829–862.CrossRef
go back to reference Márquez Peña, J. (2014). MoreClarify: Stata module to estimate quantities of interest through simulation and resampling methods. Márquez Peña, J. (2014). MoreClarify: Stata module to estimate quantities of interest through simulation and resampling methods.
go back to reference Marshall, M. G., & Gurr, T. R. Polity IV project: Political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2012. Marshall, M. G., & Gurr, T. R. Polity IV project: Political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2012.
go back to reference Pelc, K. J. (2009). Seeking escape: the use of escape clauses in international trade agreements. International Studies Quarterly, 53(2), 349–368.CrossRef Pelc, K. J. (2009). Seeking escape: the use of escape clauses in international trade agreements. International Studies Quarterly, 53(2), 349–368.CrossRef
go back to reference Pelc, K. J. (2010). Constraining coercion? Legitimacy and its role in U.S. trade policy, 1975–2000. International Organization, 64(1), 65–96.CrossRef Pelc, K. J. (2010). Constraining coercion? Legitimacy and its role in U.S. trade policy, 1975–2000. International Organization, 64(1), 65–96.CrossRef
go back to reference Pelc, K. J. (2014). The politics of precedent in international law: a social network application. American Political Science Review, 108(3), 547–564.CrossRef Pelc, K. J. (2014). The politics of precedent in international law: a social network application. American Political Science Review, 108(3), 547–564.CrossRef
go back to reference Pervez, F. (2014a). Elections and dropped WTO trade disputes. Pervez, F. (2014a). Elections and dropped WTO trade disputes.
go back to reference Pervez, F. (2015). Waiting for election season: the timing of international trade disputes. Review of International Organizations. Pervez, F. (2015). Waiting for election season: the timing of international trade disputes. Review of International Organizations.
go back to reference Pollack, M. A., & Shaffer, G. C. (2009). When cooperation fails: The international law and politics of genetically modified foods. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef Pollack, M. A., & Shaffer, G. C. (2009). When cooperation fails: The international law and politics of genetically modified foods. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Putnam, R. D. (1988). Diplomacy and domestic politics: the logic of 2-level games. International Organization, 42(3), 427–460.CrossRef Putnam, R. D. (1988). Diplomacy and domestic politics: the logic of 2-level games. International Organization, 42(3), 427–460.CrossRef
go back to reference Reinhardt, E. (2001). Adjudication without enforcement in GATT disputes. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 45(4), 174–195.CrossRef Reinhardt, E. (2001). Adjudication without enforcement in GATT disputes. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 45(4), 174–195.CrossRef
go back to reference Reynolds, K. M. (2009). Why are so many WTO disputes abandoned? In J. C. Hartigan (Ed.), Trade disputes and the dispute settlement understanding of the WTO (pp. 191–211). Bingley: Emerald Group Publishing. Reynolds, K. M. (2009). Why are so many WTO disputes abandoned? In J. C. Hartigan (Ed.), Trade disputes and the dispute settlement understanding of the WTO (pp. 191–211). Bingley: Emerald Group Publishing.
go back to reference Rodrik, D. (1997). Has globalization gone too far? Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. Rodrik, D. (1997). Has globalization gone too far? Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.
go back to reference Rosendorff, B. P. (2005). Stability and rigidity: politics and design of the WTO’s dispute settlement procedure. American Political Science Review, 99(3), 389–400.CrossRef Rosendorff, B. P. (2005). Stability and rigidity: politics and design of the WTO’s dispute settlement procedure. American Political Science Review, 99(3), 389–400.CrossRef
go back to reference Rossmiller, G. E. (1994). Discussion. In Agricultural trade conflicts and GATT, eds. Giovanni Anania, Colin A. Carter, and Alex F. McCalla. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, p. 262–265. Rossmiller, G. E. (1994). Discussion. In Agricultural trade conflicts and GATT, eds. Giovanni Anania, Colin A. Carter, and Alex F. McCalla. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, p. 262–265.
go back to reference Rubinstein, A. (1982). Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica, 50(1), 97–109.CrossRef Rubinstein, A. (1982). Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica, 50(1), 97–109.CrossRef
go back to reference Rubinstein, A. (1985). A bargaining model with incomplete information about time preferences. Econometrica, 53(5), 1151–1172.CrossRef Rubinstein, A. (1985). A bargaining model with incomplete information about time preferences. Econometrica, 53(5), 1151–1172.CrossRef
go back to reference Ruggie, J. G. (1982). International regimes, transactions, and change: embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order. International Organization, 36(2), 379–415.CrossRef Ruggie, J. G. (1982). International regimes, transactions, and change: embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order. International Organization, 36(2), 379–415.CrossRef
go back to reference Shaffer, G. (2003). How to make the WTO dispute settlement system work for developing countries: Some proactive developing country strategies. Geneva, Switzerland: International Centre for Trade; Sustainable Development (ICTSD). ICTSD Resource Paper. Shaffer, G. (2003). How to make the WTO dispute settlement system work for developing countries: Some proactive developing country strategies. Geneva, Switzerland: International Centre for Trade; Sustainable Development (ICTSD). ICTSD Resource Paper.
Metadata
Title
Enduring trade disputes: Disguised protectionism and duration and recurrence of international trade disputes
Author
Moonhawk Kim
Publication date
03-07-2015
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
The Review of International Organizations / Issue 3/2016
Print ISSN: 1559-7431
Electronic ISSN: 1559-744X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-015-9230-z

Other articles of this Issue 3/2016

The Review of International Organizations 3/2016 Go to the issue