Skip to main content
Top

2019 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

24. Global Public Goods and Governance for Addressing Sustainability

Author : Inge Kaul

Published in: The Palgrave Handbook of Development Economics

Publisher: Springer International Publishing

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Underprovision of global public goods (GPGs) such as climate change, mitigation, financial stability, global health or cyber security, today threatens development in the North and in the South and, thereby, also global—economic, social and environmental—sustainability. This chapter shows that myriad corrective actions by state and nonstate actors are underway. However, the sum of those actions often does not add up to what is required to resolve global challenges. Provision gaps arise, persist and exacerbate, even in policy fields in which existential risks exist. While many factors come into play, including psychological, behavioral, organizational and macro-economic and geopolitical ones, an important one, which, moreover, could be corrected directly, is the current lack of a systematic theory and practice of global public policy. The chapter suggests an agenda for future research and debate aimed at constructing the building blocks of a new branch of public policy that offers well-founded advice on how to combine individual state and nonstate actor interests, including national sovereignty concerns, while meeting the adequate provision requirements of global public goods. New thinking along the lines could offer analytical lenses through which to look at current policymaking realities, better understand the impediments and facilitators of GPG provision and, perhaps, spark willingness among policymakers to choose new policy paths—realizing that those actually lead to enhanced interdependence management, development and global sustainability. By implication, a major responsibility for fostering governance for global sustainability rests with social-science scholars.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
2
For the history of the notion of public goods, see Desai (2003) and Pickhardt (2006). For the contributions that, in a decisive way, formed the conventional theories of public goods, see, among others, Buchanan (1965), Musgrave (1959), and Samuelson (1954, 1955). While some of the textbooks on public economics and finance by now mention the concept of GPGs, they usually do not discuss the implications of the existence of these types of goods for the conventional public goods theory. See, for example, Cullis and Jones (2009) and Stiglitz and Rosengard (2015). However, a wealth of valuable insights on GPGs and their provision is available in scholarly publications across a wide range of disciplines, notably in studies on environmental and natural resource economics, global health, knowledge and intellectual property, as well as international security, especially terrorism. See, for example: Atkinson (2006), Barrett (2007), Costanza et al. (2015), Kaul (2016), Kaul et al. (19992003), Kaul and Conceição (2006), Nordhaus (2006), Sandler (2004), Sandmo (2000, 2007), Stern (2007, 2015), and Stiglitz (2014). A comprehensive overview of the social science literature published between the early 1970s and 2015/2016, explicitly employing the analytical lens of public goods for the examination of the phenomena referred to here as GPGs (though perhaps employing terms such as international or transnational public goods or global commons), is presented in the work of Kaul et al. (2016).
 
3
The term “provision” refers to both the political (negotiation or decision-making) side and the operational (implementation or production) side of the generation or maintenance of GPGs. In many instances, both sides are closely intertwined. However, in the following, when a statement refers primarily to only one side of the provision process, the term “political decision-making” or “production” will be used.
 
4
Based on Hirshleifer (1983), three main types of so-called production technologies are being distinguished: (1) summation technology, which is given, when each input adds to the overall availability of the good (e.g., climate change mitigation); (2) weakest-link technology, in the case of which the smallest contribution determines the good’s overall availability (e.g., dyke construction or terrorism control by way of passenger screening at airports); and (3) best-shot-technology, where one single contribution (e.g., the discovery of a new vaccine by one inventor) determines the good’s availability. See, for a more detailed discussion on this topic, for example, Cornes and Sandler (1996). However, important is to add that, frequently, GPG provision depends on the availability of inputs that each follow one or the other production technology and, not uncommonly, even, in themselves, a combination of these technologies, as discussed in Kaul and Conceição (2006).
 
5
Some public goods, including GPGs, such as the global knowledge stock, lend themselves to gradual and continuous improvement. By contrast, other public goods generate expected benefits (or stop generating costs) only if their requirements for systematic integrity or other standards of adequate provision are met. Thus, effective international cooperation is particularly critical in the case of these latter public goods. For example, climate change mitigation depends on achieving defined reductions in global CO2 emissions by defined target dates. For a discussion on different types of adequacy standards, see, among others, Barrett (2007), Conceição (2003), Costanza and Mageau (1999), and Rockström et al. (2009).
 
6
The assumption of individual actor being tempted to free ride in the presence of public goods dates back to a thought experiment in David Hume’s Treatise of Human Nature ([1739] 2015) what would happen to the provision of public goods if all actors were rational and pure selfish individuals. By implication it follows that they would most likely wait and see whether others provide the good, hoping that they themselves might be able to enjoy the good for free once it is available. But if many or all act in this way, the good (assuming it is not a best-shot good) is likely to be underprovided or not available at all. Hence the assumed rational actors would in due course realize that they are “rational fools” (Sen 1977:317). However, over time, this assumption has been treated as if it were a well-established fact, despite mounting evidence showing that many individual –state and nonstate –actors have, as Sen (2007) says, plural affiliations, identities and, hence, mixed motivations –in the presence of private goods and public goods. Some may even be “pure cooperators.” See, on the evolution of the thinking about the behavior of states in international cooperation, also Kaul et al. (2016), notably Section II.
 
7
In fact, offering effective and efficient incentives to states is of special importance, because, if they hesitate to cooperate and contribute, they might underprovide the incentives that nonstate actors require to overcome their respective private-business or other personal interest hurdles and dual—state and nonstate—actor failure might occur. The terms “private-business” and “personal interest” hurdles do not imply that nonstate actors pursue only selfish economic interests as the rational-choice actors in the conventional public goods theory are assumed to do. Yet, they may be mixed-motive or pure other-regarding actors. However, even then, their top-priority concerns may, if at all, only partially overlap with the provision requirements of the GPGs that need to be addressed. On the behavioral assumptions underlying individual actor’s willingness to cooperate see, again, the literature review in Kaul et al. (2016) referred to in footnote 2.
 
8
Externalities or spillover effects arise when an individual actor or a group of actors undertakes an action that affects third parties, perhaps even society as a whole for which the latter do not pay or are not being paid for. As Fig. 24.1 shows, externalities may be among the effects that affect the availability of public goods, including GPGs, for better or worse.
 
9
The Google search engine listed in response to the entry “global reports on global challenges” 6.5 million entries in 0.47 seconds and 5.3 million entries in 0.42 seconds in response to “reports on transnational challenges” on 12/05/2018.
 
10
The report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC 2014), for example, presents detailed analyses of a wide range of issues relating to specific facets of climate change mitigation and adaptation. However, while interlinkages are mentioned, each aspect is discussed separately. Yet, it seems that the “need” for a more integrated approach is being realized, judging from the fact that terms such as “orchestration” and “regime complex” are emerging and being applied in a number of GPG-related policy fields. See, for example, the following contributions: Dubash and Florini (2011)—on energy governance; Hale and Roger (2014) and Keohane and Victor (2010)—on climate change; Nye (2014)—on cybersecurity; and Ocampo (2017)—on the provision of global liquidity and macroeconomic policy coordination. In the same vein, Frenk and Moon (2013) and Kickbusch and Szabo (2014) refer to global health as a new policy space to be in an integrated way, across borders.
 
11
See, for an overview of the new fields of diplomacy that have emerged with advancing globalization, Cooper et al. (2013).
 
12
The list of the special representatives of the UN secretary-general can be retrieved from: https://​www.​un.​org/​sg/​en/​content/​other-high-level-appointments/​
 
15
For access to the text of the Agenda, see again footnote 1.
 
16
The text of the Paris Agreement can be retrieved from https://​unfccc.​int/​
 
19
Mention can in this context, for example, be made of the US withdrawal from the Paris Agreement: https://​unfccc.​int/​news/​official-communication-from-the-us-on-its-intention-to-withdraw-from-the-paris-agreement; and Germany’s “jobs first, then climate” policy that led to its delayed exist from coal and the postponement of achieving its declared climate goals: https://​www.​dw.​com/​en/​germanys-coal-exit-jobs-first-then-the-climate/​a-44046848/​
 
20
See, on the now widely advocated reliance on private finance, for example, Bhattacharya et al. (2016), MDBs (2017), OECD (2018), and WBG (2017a, b). For studies arguing for a financing approach based on a more systematic consideration of the role specificity and complementarity between public and private finance for development and the provision of GPGs, see, among others, Development Initiatives (2016), Griffith-Jones and Ocampo (2018), Kaul (2017), Müller (2016), and Oxfam (2018).
 
21
In this context, it is also important to note that, in part, the financing for private-sector incentives comes out of the resources available for official development assistance (ODA). In addition, ODA is increasingly being used to cover a part of the costs that developed—“donor”—countries incur for hosting, in their country, refugees or undertaking civilian reconstruction efforts in developing countries, such as Afghanistan, in which they are involved in military activities (see OECD 2016). In addition, an increasing volume of MDB lending is being allocated to enhanced risk management and strengthening the resilience of local communities to cope with external shocks and other ill-effects resulting from GPG underprovision (see Kaul 2017). These are important initiatives. But, they do not resolve the underlying problem or, if so, then only marginally. Moreover, it would be important to assess whether and to what extent they might undercut or distort national development efforts in poorer developing countries on which effective GPG provision depends, for example, in the fields of communicable disease control or fighting international terrorism.
 
22
See, on this, also the WBG’s Guidance Note on Shadow Price of Carbon in Economic Analysis, dated November 12, 2017, which is based on the report of the High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices (2017). Available at http://​documents.​worldbank.​org/​curated/​en/​6217215199401076​94/​pdf/​2017-Shadow-Price-of-Carbon-Guidance-Note.​pdf/​
 
23
See, on this topic, the MDBs’ joint 2018 report on their climate finance in 2017, which shows (ibid.:5) that 80 percent of their climate finance supports mitigation and only 20 percent adaption, despite the Paris Agreement’s call (in Article 9, para. 4) for aiming to achieve a better balance between mitigation and adaptation. https://​reliefweb.​int/​sites/​reliefweb.​int/​files/​resources/​2017-joint-report-on-mdbs-climate-finance.​pdf
 
24
The principle is enshrined in UNFCCC Article 3(1). See https://​unfccc.​int/​. On the importance of the principle as a negotiation tool, see Brunnée and Streck (2013).
 
25
Numerous studies on the feasibility and desirability of various types of global taxes and other innovative sources and instruments to mobilize additional public finance have been undertaken. See, for example: Atkinson (2005), Kaul and Conceição (2006), Leading Group (2010), and UNDESA (2012). So far, however, governments have shown limited interest in pursuing these options. For example, as of April 2018, only 26 countries have a national carbon tax (WBG and ECOFYS 2018:8). In fact, like in other policy fields, policy approaches to carbon pricing have also shifted away from promoting global, cooperative arrangements to relying on initiatives taken by individual national and sub-national jurisdiction or firms and, importantly, by appealing to actors’ self-interests. Promoting political support for policy initiatives is important. However, will promises of appropriable individual benefits allow provision gap closure or further reinforce individualistic—rather than mixed-motive or other-regarding—political attitudes and behavior? Also, will reliance on voluntary incremental progress happen fast enough to avoid crossing global tipping points? And what are the implications of leaving matters to individual voluntary change initiatives for compliance with the CBDRRC principle? These and other questions about GPG provision gap closure and global sustainability find only passing, if any mention in some of the newer studies on carbon pricing, which tend to hope for multiple isolated incremental change initiatives to set in motion an upward spiral of ambition and progress over time. See, among others: Cramton et al. (2017), Edenhofer et al. (2015), High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices (2017), and Klenert et al. (2018). Also, despite still rising greenhouse gas emissions (see IEA 2018), limited progress on mobilizing new and additional revenue from measures such as carbon taxes, and actual or perceived fiscal constraints, states, including the G20 member states also still go slow on reducing or eliminating altogether fossil fuel subsidies. See Coady et al. (2017).
 
26
On existential and nonexistential risks, see Bostrom (2013), GCF (2017), and World Economic Forum (2018).
 
27
The cascade approach is to ensure that only, if all other efforts fail, public and concessional finance will be used. See, for a graphic presentation of the approach, WBG (2017a:6).
 
28
In her comment on this decision, Nancy Birdsall (2018:2) states that this is not big money but a breakthrough, as this decision “opens the door to continued and increasing annual transfers for a set of GPGs critical to the development and poverty mission of the Bank (and other MDBs).” But again, the question of how these US$100 million a year (which moreover represent money coming from middle-income countries) compare to the value of the global co-benefits emanating from GPG-related activities in developing countries, benefitting both, North and South, arises. This perspective on GPGs as “being good for developing countries” is, as noted, correct but only capturing half the story, because these goods are in many cases also good for developed countries. See, for this perspective (i.e., GPGs being good for the development of developing countries), also CGD (2016).
 
29
The G7 includes Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, United Kingdom, United States and the European Union.
 
30
For detailed information about the composition and functioning of the G20, as well as a listing of its policy statements and reports, see the G20 Information Centre’s website at: http://​www.​g20.​utoronto.​ca/​about.​html/​
 
31
About the BRICS and their 2018 summit in South Africa, see http://​www.​brics2018.​org.​za/​
 
32
For the WEF’s initiatives, agenda and reports, see https://​www.​weforum.​org/​
 
33
See https://​wsf2018.​org/​en/​ for more details about the history and activities of the Forum
 
34
See, for information about the preparations for the 2018 G20 Summit, https://​www.​g20.​org/​en
 
35
See https://​un.​org/​ (to be amended; UN website is under maintenance).
 
36
See, on these global trends, among others: Bremmer (2012) and Rachman (2017).
 
37
Pathway analysis is an approach already being used by scholars in the field of earth system governance “seeking to advance understanding of the governance processes by which to steer human behavior in a way that maintains safe and stable conditions for human well-being on planet earth” (Biermann 2014:25). For an overview of the literature in this field, see besides Biermann (ibid.) also Patterson et al. (2017).
 
38
On different conceptualizations of subsidiarity, see Føllesdal (2014), and on applying the principle of subsidiarity to determining the balance between centralization and decentralization in designing public-policy initiatives, see, for example, Jachtenfuchs and Krisch (2016) and Wyplosz (2015).
 
39
To address these legitimacy issues that Bodansky (2012) raises would require clearly defined norms and targets, as well as indicators and measurements. Interestingly, the use of such tools has rapidly proliferated in recent years, as seen from the extensive reporting and monitoring requirements set forth in the 2030 Agenda (paragraphs 72–91 of UN resolution A/RES/70/1 mentioned in footnote 1) and in the Paris Agreement (Articles 13–14 of the document mentioned in footnote 15).
 
40
Before leaving this discussion about sovereignty, it is important to mention that the concepts proposed here differ from the notion of “sovereignty as responsibility” and the so-called R2 principle. According to this principle, states have the responsibility to protect their populations against atrocities such as genocide, ethnic cleansing or other severe human-rights violations; and if a state fails to provide such protection, the international community has a responsibility to help prevent or halt such violations. The R2P notion originated from the 2001 report of the International Commission on Intervention and State Sovereignty (ICISS 2001) and was endorsed by the UN General Assembly in its resolution A/60/L.1 of September 15, 2005. For more details, see also Thakur and Maley (2015) and http://​www.​globalr2p.​org/​about_​r2p/​
 
42
This 20-member commission of independent experts chaired by Joseph E. Stiglitz was appointed by the president of the United Nations General Assembly in 2008 to assist member states in their deliberations on the world financial and economic crisis. Its 2009 report is available at: http://​www.​un.​org/​ga/​econcrisissummit​/​docs/​FinalReport_​CoE.​pdf/​
 
43
For a comprehensive overview of social science contributions to GPG-related topics, see Kaul et al. (2016)
 
Literature
go back to reference Atkinson, A. B. (Ed.). (2005). New sources of development finance. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Atkinson, A. B. (Ed.). (2005). New sources of development finance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Atkinson, T. (2006). Global public finance. Oxonomics, 1(1), 2–4. Atkinson, T. (2006). Global public finance. Oxonomics, 1(1), 2–4.
go back to reference Barrett, S. (2007). Why cooperate? The incentive to supply global public goods. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Barrett, S. (2007). Why cooperate? The incentive to supply global public goods. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Bhattacharya, A., Meltzer, J. P., Oppenheim, J., Qureshi, Z., & Stern, N. (2016). Delivering on sustainable infrastructure for better development and better climate. Washington, DC: Brookings. Bhattacharya, A., Meltzer, J. P., Oppenheim, J., Qureshi, Z., & Stern, N. (2016). Delivering on sustainable infrastructure for better development and better climate. Washington, DC: Brookings.
go back to reference Biermann, F. (2014). Earth system governance; world politics in the anthropocene. Cambridge, MA/London: The MIT Press. Biermann, F. (2014). Earth system governance; world politics in the anthropocene. Cambridge, MA/London: The MIT Press.
go back to reference Blended Finance Taskforce. (2018). Better finance better world. Consultation paper of the blended finance taskforce. London: Business & Sustainable Development Commission/SYSTEMIQ. Blended Finance Taskforce. (2018). Better finance better world. Consultation paper of the blended finance taskforce. London: Business & Sustainable Development Commission/SYSTEMIQ.
go back to reference Bodansky, D. (2012). What’s in a concept? Global public goods, international law, and legitimacy. European Journal of International Law, 23(3), 651–668. Bodansky, D. (2012). What’s in a concept? Global public goods, international law, and legitimacy. European Journal of International Law, 23(3), 651–668.
go back to reference Bosselmann, K. (2017). The principle of sustainability: Transforming law and governance (2nd ed.). London/New York: Routledge. Bosselmann, K. (2017). The principle of sustainability: Transforming law and governance (2nd ed.). London/New York: Routledge.
go back to reference Bostrom, N. (2013). Existential risk prevention as global priority. Global Policy, 1(4), 15–31. Bostrom, N. (2013). Existential risk prevention as global priority. Global Policy, 1(4), 15–31.
go back to reference Bremmer, I. (2012). Every nation for itself: Winners and losers in a g-zero world. London: Portfolio/Penguin. Bremmer, I. (2012). Every nation for itself: Winners and losers in a g-zero world. London: Portfolio/Penguin.
go back to reference Brunnée, J., & Streck, C. (2013). The UNFCCC as a negotiating forum: Towards common but differentiated responsibilities. Climate Policy, 13(5), 589–607. Brunnée, J., & Streck, C. (2013). The UNFCCC as a negotiating forum: Towards common but differentiated responsibilities. Climate Policy, 13(5), 589–607.
go back to reference Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32(125), 1–14. Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32(125), 1–14.
go back to reference Center for Global Development. (2016). Multilateral development banking for this century’s development challenges. Five recommendations to shareholders of the old and new Multilateral Development Banks. Report of the high level panel on the future of development banking. Washington, DC: Center for Global development. Center for Global Development. (2016). Multilateral development banking for this century’s development challenges. Five recommendations to shareholders of the old and new Multilateral Development Banks. Report of the high level panel on the future of development banking. Washington, DC: Center for Global development.
go back to reference Coady, D., Parry, I., Sears, L., & Shang, B. (2017). How large are global fossil fuel subsidies? World Development, 91, 11–27. Coady, D., Parry, I., Sears, L., & Shang, B. (2017). How large are global fossil fuel subsidies? World Development, 91, 11–27.
go back to reference Conceição, P. (2003). Assessing the provision of global public goods. In I. Kaul, P. Conceição, K. Le Goulven, & R. U. Mendoza (Eds.), Providing global public goods: Managing globalization (pp. 152–184). New York: Oxford University Press. Conceição, P. (2003). Assessing the provision of global public goods. In I. Kaul, P. Conceição, K. Le Goulven, & R. U. Mendoza (Eds.), Providing global public goods: Managing globalization (pp. 152–184). New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Cooper, A. F., Heine, J., & Thakur, R. (Eds.). (2013). The oxford handbook of modern diplomacy. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Cooper, A. F., Heine, J., & Thakur, R. (Eds.). (2013). The oxford handbook of modern diplomacy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities, public goods and club goods (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities, public goods and club goods (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Costanza, R., & Mageau, M. (1999). What is a healthy system? Aquatic Ecology, 33, 105–115. Costanza, R., & Mageau, M. (1999). What is a healthy system? Aquatic Ecology, 33, 105–115.
go back to reference Costanza, R., Cumberland, J. H., Daly, H., Goodland, R., Norgaard, R. B., Kubiszewski, I., & Franco, C. (2015). An introduction to ecological economics. Boca Raton: CRC Press. Costanza, R., Cumberland, J. H., Daly, H., Goodland, R., Norgaard, R. B., Kubiszewski, I., & Franco, C. (2015). An introduction to ecological economics. Boca Raton: CRC Press.
go back to reference Cramton, P., MacKay, D. J. C., Ochsenfels, A., & Stoft, S. (Eds.). (2017). Global carbon pricing. The path to climate cooperation. Cambridge, MA/London: The MIT Press. Cramton, P., MacKay, D. J. C., Ochsenfels, A., & Stoft, S. (Eds.). (2017). Global carbon pricing. The path to climate cooperation. Cambridge, MA/London: The MIT Press.
go back to reference Cullis, J., & Jones, P. (2009). Public finance and public choice: Analytical perspectives (3rd ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Cullis, J., & Jones, P. (2009). Public finance and public choice: Analytical perspectives (3rd ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Desai, M. (2003). Public goods: A historical perspective. In I. Kaul, P. Conceição, K. Le Goulven, & R. U. Mendoza (Eds.), Providing global public goods: Managing globalization (pp. 63–77). New York: Oxford University Press. Desai, M. (2003). Public goods: A historical perspective. In I. Kaul, P. Conceição, K. Le Goulven, & R. U. Mendoza (Eds.), Providing global public goods: Managing globalization (pp. 63–77). New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Dubash, N. K., & Florini, A. (2011). Mapping global energy governance. Global Policy, 2(s1), 6–18. Dubash, N. K., & Florini, A. (2011). Mapping global energy governance. Global Policy, 2(s1), 6–18.
go back to reference Edenhofer, O., Jakob, M., Creutzig, F., Flachsland, C., Fuss, S., Kowarsch, M., Lessmann, K., Mattauch, L., Siegmeier, J., & Steckel, J. C. (2015). Closing the emission price gap. Global Environmental Change, 31(3), 132–143. Edenhofer, O., Jakob, M., Creutzig, F., Flachsland, C., Fuss, S., Kowarsch, M., Lessmann, K., Mattauch, L., Siegmeier, J., & Steckel, J. C. (2015). Closing the emission price gap. Global Environmental Change, 31(3), 132–143.
go back to reference Føllesdal, A. (2014). Competing conceptions of subsidiarity. In J. E. Fleming & J. T. Levy (Eds.), Federalism and subsidiarity: Nomos LV (pp. 214–230). New York: New York University Press. Føllesdal, A. (2014). Competing conceptions of subsidiarity. In J. E. Fleming & J. T. Levy (Eds.), Federalism and subsidiarity: Nomos LV (pp. 214–230). New York: New York University Press.
go back to reference Frenk, J., & Moon, S. (2013). Governance challenges in global health. New England Journal of Medicine, 368, 936–942. Frenk, J., & Moon, S. (2013). Governance challenges in global health. New England Journal of Medicine, 368, 936–942.
go back to reference GCF (Global Challenge Foundation). (2017). Global catastrophic risks 2017. Stockholm: GCF. GCF (Global Challenge Foundation). (2017). Global catastrophic risks 2017. Stockholm: GCF.
go back to reference Griffith-Jones, S., & Ocampo, J. A. (Eds.). (2018). The future of national development banks. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Griffith-Jones, S., & Ocampo, J. A. (Eds.). (2018). The future of national development banks. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Haas, R. (2017). World order 2.0: The case for sovereign obligation. Foreign Affairs, 96(1), 2–9. Haas, R. (2017). World order 2.0: The case for sovereign obligation. Foreign Affairs, 96(1), 2–9.
go back to reference Hale, T., & Roger, C. (2014). Orchestration and transnational climate governance. Review of International Organizations, 9(1), 59–82. Hale, T., & Roger, C. (2014). Orchestration and transnational climate governance. Review of International Organizations, 9(1), 59–82.
go back to reference Hale, T., Held, D., & Young, K. (2013). Gridlock: Why global cooperation is failing when we need it most. Cambridge: Polity Press. Hale, T., Held, D., & Young, K. (2013). Gridlock: Why global cooperation is failing when we need it most. Cambridge: Polity Press.
go back to reference Helgenberger, S., & Jänicke, M. (2017). Mobilizing the co-benefits of climate change mitigation: Connecting opportunities with interests in the new energy world of renewables (IASS working paper). Potsdam: Institute for Advanced Sustainability Studies. Helgenberger, S., & Jänicke, M. (2017). Mobilizing the co-benefits of climate change mitigation: Connecting opportunities with interests in the new energy world of renewables (IASS working paper). Potsdam: Institute for Advanced Sustainability Studies.
go back to reference High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices. (2017). Report of the high-level commission on carbon prices. Washington, DC: World Bank. High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices. (2017). Report of the high-level commission on carbon prices. Washington, DC: World Bank.
go back to reference Hirshleifer, J. (1983). From weakest-link to best-shot: The voluntary provision of public goods. Public Choice, 41(3), 371–386. Hirshleifer, J. (1983). From weakest-link to best-shot: The voluntary provision of public goods. Public Choice, 41(3), 371–386.
go back to reference Hume, D. [1739–1740] (2015). A treatise of human nature. Create Space Independent Publishing Platform. Hume, D. [1739–1740] (2015). A treatise of human nature. Create Space Independent Publishing Platform.
go back to reference IEA (International Energy Agency). (2018). Global energy & CO2status report. Paris: IEA/OECD. IEA (International Energy Agency). (2018). Global energy & CO2status report. Paris: IEA/OECD.
go back to reference IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change). (2014). Climate change 2014: Mitigation of climate change. Contribution of working group III to the fifth assessment report of the IPCC. In O. Edenhofer, R. Pichs-Madruga, & Y. Sokona (Eds.), Climate change 2014: Mitigation of climate change. Contribution of working group iii to the fifth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change). (2014). Climate change 2014: Mitigation of climate change. Contribution of working group III to the fifth assessment report of the IPCC. In O. Edenhofer, R. Pichs-Madruga, & Y. Sokona (Eds.), Climate change 2014: Mitigation of climate change. Contribution of working group iii to the fifth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Jachtenfuchs, M., & Krisch, N. (2016). Subsidiarity in global governance. Law and Contemporary Problems, 79(2), 1–26. Jachtenfuchs, M., & Krisch, N. (2016). Subsidiarity in global governance. Law and Contemporary Problems, 79(2), 1–26.
go back to reference Kaul, I. (2013). Meeting global challenges: Assessing governance readiness. In Hertie School of Governance (Ed.), The governance report. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Kaul, I. (2013). Meeting global challenges: Assessing governance readiness. In Hertie School of Governance (Ed.), The governance report. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Kaul, I. (Ed.). (2016). Global public goods (The international library of critical writings in economics). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Kaul, I. (Ed.). (2016). Global public goods (The international library of critical writings in economics). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
go back to reference Kaul, I. (2017). Providing global public goods: What role for multilateral development banks? London: Overseas Development Institute (ODI). Kaul, I. (2017). Providing global public goods: What role for multilateral development banks? London: Overseas Development Institute (ODI).
go back to reference Kaul, I. (2018a). Enhanced human security: A modernity to be available to all. In T. Meyer & S. de Marques (Eds.), Multiple modernities and good governance (pp. 83–97). London/New York: Routledge. Kaul, I. (2018a). Enhanced human security: A modernity to be available to all. In T. Meyer & S. de Marques (Eds.), Multiple modernities and good governance (pp. 83–97). London/New York: Routledge.
go back to reference Kaul, I., & Blondin, D. (2016). Global public goods and the United Nations. In J. A. Ocampo (Ed.), Global governance and development (pp. 32–65). New York: Oxford University Press. Kaul, I., & Blondin, D. (2016). Global public goods and the United Nations. In J. A. Ocampo (Ed.), Global governance and development (pp. 32–65). New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Kaul, I., & Conceição, P. (Eds.). (2006). The new public finance: Responding to global challenges. New York: Oxford University Press. Kaul, I., & Conceição, P. (Eds.). (2006). The new public finance: Responding to global challenges. New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Kaul, I., Grunberg, I., & Stern, M. A. (Eds.). (1999). Global public goods: International cooperation in the 21st century. New York: Oxford University Press. Kaul, I., Grunberg, I., & Stern, M. A. (Eds.). (1999). Global public goods: International cooperation in the 21st century. New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Kaul, I., Conceição, P., Le Goulven, K., & Mendoza, R. U. (Eds.). (2003). Providing global public goods: Managing globalization. New York: Oxford University Press. Kaul, I., Conceição, P., Le Goulven, K., & Mendoza, R. U. (Eds.). (2003). Providing global public goods: Managing globalization. New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Kaul, I., Blondin, D., & Nahtigal, N. (2016). Understanding global public goods: Where we are and where to next. In I. Kaul (Ed.), Global public goods (The international library of critical writings in economics). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Kaul, I., Blondin, D., & Nahtigal, N. (2016). Understanding global public goods: Where we are and where to next. In I. Kaul (Ed.), Global public goods (The international library of critical writings in economics). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
go back to reference Keohane, R. O., & Victor, D. G. (2010). The regime complex for climate change (Discussion paper 10–33, Harvard project on climate agreements). Cambridge, MA: Belfer Center. Keohane, R. O., & Victor, D. G. (2010). The regime complex for climate change (Discussion paper 10–33, Harvard project on climate agreements). Cambridge, MA: Belfer Center.
go back to reference Kharas, H., & Rogerson, A. (2017). Global development trends and challenges: Horizon 2025 revisited. ODI report. London: Overseas Development Institute. Kharas, H., & Rogerson, A. (2017). Global development trends and challenges: Horizon 2025 revisited. ODI report. London: Overseas Development Institute.
go back to reference Kim, R. E., & Bosselmann, K. (2013). International environmental law in the anthropocene: Towards a purposive system of multilateral environmental agreements. Transnational Environmental Law, 2(2), 285–309. Kim, R. E., & Bosselmann, K. (2013). International environmental law in the anthropocene: Towards a purposive system of multilateral environmental agreements. Transnational Environmental Law, 2(2), 285–309.
go back to reference Klenert, D., Mattauch, L., Combet, E., Edenhofer, O., Hepburn, C., Rafaty, R., & Stern, N. (2018). Making carbon pricing work for citizens. Nature Climate Change, 8, 669–677. Klenert, D., Mattauch, L., Combet, E., Edenhofer, O., Hepburn, C., Rafaty, R., & Stern, N. (2018). Making carbon pricing work for citizens. Nature Climate Change, 8, 669–677.
go back to reference Leading Group on Innovative Financing for Development. (2010). Globalizing solidarity: The case for financial levies. Report of the committee of experts to the task force on international financial transactions and development. Paris: French Ministry of Foreign and European Affairs/Permanent Leading Group Secretariat. Available at: http://www.leadinggroup.org/rubrique69.html/ Leading Group on Innovative Financing for Development. (2010). Globalizing solidarity: The case for financial levies. Report of the committee of experts to the task force on international financial transactions and development. Paris: French Ministry of Foreign and European Affairs/Permanent Leading Group Secretariat. Available at: http://​www.​leadinggroup.​org/​rubrique69.​html/​
go back to reference Mazzucato, M. (2015). The entrepreneurial state: Debunking public vs. private sector myths. New York: Public Affairs. Mazzucato, M. (2015). The entrepreneurial state: Debunking public vs. private sector myths. New York: Public Affairs.
go back to reference Müller, J. (2016). Harnessing private finance to attain public policy goals? How governments try to involve the private sector in times of austerity and what risks this entails. Amsterdam: Centre for Research on Multinational Corporations (SOMO). Müller, J. (2016). Harnessing private finance to attain public policy goals? How governments try to involve the private sector in times of austerity and what risks this entails. Amsterdam: Centre for Research on Multinational Corporations (SOMO).
go back to reference Musgrave, R. A. (1959). Theory of public finance: A study in public economy. New York/London: McGraw-Hill. Musgrave, R. A. (1959). Theory of public finance: A study in public economy. New York/London: McGraw-Hill.
go back to reference Nordhaus, W. D. (2006). Paul Samuelson and global public goods. In M. Szenberg, L. Ramrattan, & A. A. Gottesman (Eds.), Samuelsonian economics and the twenty-first century. New York: Oxford University Press. Nordhaus, W. D. (2006). Paul Samuelson and global public goods. In M. Szenberg, L. Ramrattan, & A. A. Gottesman (Eds.), Samuelsonian economics and the twenty-first century. New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Nye, J. S., Jr. (2014). The regime complex for managing global cyber activities (Global commission on internet governance paper series 1 May 2014). Waterloo/London: Centre for International Governance Innovation/Royal Institute for International Affairs. Nye, J. S., Jr. (2014). The regime complex for managing global cyber activities (Global commission on internet governance paper series 1 May 2014). Waterloo/London: Centre for International Governance Innovation/Royal Institute for International Affairs.
go back to reference Ocampo, J. A. (2016). Global economic and social governance and the United Nations system. In J. A. Ocampo (Ed.), Global governance and development (pp. 3–31). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Ocampo, J. A. (2016). Global economic and social governance and the United Nations system. In J. A. Ocampo (Ed.), Global governance and development (pp. 3–31). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Ocampo, J. A. (2017). Resetting the international monetary non-system. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Ocampo, J. A. (2017). Resetting the international monetary non-system. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). (2018). Making blended finance work for the sustainable development goals. Paris: OECD. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). (2018). Making blended finance work for the sustainable development goals. Paris: OECD.
go back to reference Ostrom, E. (2010, June). Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems. American Economic Review, 100, 641–672. Ostrom, E. (2010, June). Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems. American Economic Review, 100, 641–672.
go back to reference Ostrom, E. (2014). A polycentric approach for coping with climate change. Annals of Economics and Finance, 15(1), 97–134. Ostrom, E. (2014). A polycentric approach for coping with climate change. Annals of Economics and Finance, 15(1), 97–134.
go back to reference Oxfam International. (2018). Climate finance shadow report 2018; assessing progress towards the $ 100 billion commitment. Oxford: Oxfam UK for Oxfam International. Oxfam International. (2018). Climate finance shadow report 2018; assessing progress towards the $ 100 billion commitment. Oxford: Oxfam UK for Oxfam International.
go back to reference Patterson, J., Schulz, K., Vervoort, J., van der Hel, S., Widerberg, O., Adler, C., Hurlbert, M., Anderton, K., Sethi, M., & Barau, A. (2017). Exploring the governance and politics of transformations towards sustainability. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions, 24, 1–16. Patterson, J., Schulz, K., Vervoort, J., van der Hel, S., Widerberg, O., Adler, C., Hurlbert, M., Anderton, K., Sethi, M., & Barau, A. (2017). Exploring the governance and politics of transformations towards sustainability. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions, 24, 1–16.
go back to reference Pickhardt, M. (2006). Fifty years after Samuelson’s ‘the pure theory of public expenditure’: What are we left with? Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 28(4), 439–460. Pickhardt, M. (2006). Fifty years after Samuelson’s ‘the pure theory of public expenditure’: What are we left with? Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 28(4), 439–460.
go back to reference Rachman, G. (2017). Easternisation. London: Vintage. Rachman, G. (2017). Easternisation. London: Vintage.
go back to reference Rockström, J., Steffen, W., Noone, K., Persson, Å., Chapin, F. S., Lambin, E. F., Lenton, T. M., Scheffer, M., Folke, C., Schellnhuber, H. J., Nykvist, B., de Wit, C., Hughes, T., van der Leeuwe, S., Rodhe, H., Sörlin, S., Snyder, P. K., Costanza, R., Svedin, U., Falkenmark, M., Karlberg, L., Corell, R. W., Fabry, V. J., Hansen, J., Walker, B., Liverman, D., Richardson, K., Crutzen, P., & Foley, A. (2009). A safe operating space for humanity. Nature, 461(24 September), 472–475. Rockström, J., Steffen, W., Noone, K., Persson, Å., Chapin, F. S., Lambin, E. F., Lenton, T. M., Scheffer, M., Folke, C., Schellnhuber, H. J., Nykvist, B., de Wit, C., Hughes, T., van der Leeuwe, S., Rodhe, H., Sörlin, S., Snyder, P. K., Costanza, R., Svedin, U., Falkenmark, M., Karlberg, L., Corell, R. W., Fabry, V. J., Hansen, J., Walker, B., Liverman, D., Richardson, K., Crutzen, P., & Foley, A. (2009). A safe operating space for humanity. Nature, 461(24 September), 472–475.
go back to reference Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387–389. Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387–389.
go back to reference Samuelson, P. A. (1955). Diagrammatic exposition of a theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 37(4), 350–356. Samuelson, P. A. (1955). Diagrammatic exposition of a theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 37(4), 350–356.
go back to reference Sandler, T. (2004). Global collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Sandler, T. (2004). Global collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Sandmo, A. (2000). The public economics of the environment. Oxford/New York: Oxford University Press. Sandmo, A. (2000). The public economics of the environment. Oxford/New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Sen, A. (1977). Rational fools: A critique of the behavioral foundations of economic theory. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 6(4), 317–344. Sen, A. (1977). Rational fools: A critique of the behavioral foundations of economic theory. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 6(4), 317–344.
go back to reference Sen, A. (2007). Identity and violence: The illusion of destiny. London: Penguin Books. Sen, A. (2007). Identity and violence: The illusion of destiny. London: Penguin Books.
go back to reference Shaffer, G. (2012). International law and global public goods in a legal pluralist world. European Journal of International Law, 23(3), 669–693. Shaffer, G. (2012). International law and global public goods in a legal pluralist world. European Journal of International Law, 23(3), 669–693.
go back to reference Stern, N. (2007). The economics of climate change: The stern review. Cambridge/New York: Cambridge University Press. Stern, N. (2007). The economics of climate change: The stern review. Cambridge/New York: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Stern, N. (2015). Why are we waiting? The logic, urgency, and promise of tackling climate change. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Stern, N. (2015). Why are we waiting? The logic, urgency, and promise of tackling climate change. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
go back to reference Stiglitz, J. E. (2014). Intellectual property rights, the pool of knowledge, and innovation (NBER working paper series 2014). Cambridge, MA. Stiglitz, J. E. (2014). Intellectual property rights, the pool of knowledge, and innovation (NBER working paper series 2014). Cambridge, MA.
go back to reference Stiglitz, J. E., & Rosengard, J. K. (2015). The economics of the public sector (4th ed., International student ed.). New York: Norton & Company. Stiglitz, J. E., & Rosengard, J. K. (2015). The economics of the public sector (4th ed., International student ed.). New York: Norton & Company.
go back to reference Thakur, R., & Maley, W. (2015). Introduction: Theorising global responsibilities. In R. Thakur & W. Maley (Eds.), Theorising the responsibility to protect (pp. 3–15). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Thakur, R., & Maley, W. (2015). Introduction: Theorising global responsibilities. In R. Thakur & W. Maley (Eds.), Theorising the responsibility to protect (pp. 3–15). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference UNDESA (United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs). (2012). World economic and social survey 2012: In search of new development finance. New York: United Nations. UNDESA (United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs). (2012). World economic and social survey 2012: In search of new development finance. New York: United Nations.
go back to reference UNEP (United Nations Environment Programme). (2017). The emissions gap report 2017. Nairobi: UNEP. UNEP (United Nations Environment Programme). (2017). The emissions gap report 2017. Nairobi: UNEP.
go back to reference WBG (World Bank Group). (2017a). Forward look: A vision for the World Bank group in 2030; progress and challenges (Document DC2017-0002). Washington, DC: World Bank. WBG (World Bank Group). (2017a). Forward look: A vision for the World Bank group in 2030; progress and challenges (Document DC2017-0002). Washington, DC: World Bank.
go back to reference WBG (World Bank Group). (2017b). Maximizing finance for development: Leveraging the private sector for growth and sustainable development (DC2017_0009). Washington, DC: World Bank. WBG (World Bank Group). (2017b). Maximizing finance for development: Leveraging the private sector for growth and sustainable development (DC2017_0009). Washington, DC: World Bank.
go back to reference WBG and ECOFYS. (2018). State and trend of carbon pricing 2018 (May). Washington, DC: WBG. WBG and ECOFYS. (2018). State and trend of carbon pricing 2018 (May). Washington, DC: WBG.
go back to reference WBG-IEG. (2008, September). Annual review of development effectiveness 2008: Shared global challenges (Fast track brief 52607). Washington, DC: World Bank. WBG-IEG. (2008, September). Annual review of development effectiveness 2008: Shared global challenges (Fast track brief 52607). Washington, DC: World Bank.
go back to reference WBG-OED. (2002). The World Bank’s approach to global programs: An independent evaluation. Washington, DC: World Bank. WBG-OED. (2002). The World Bank’s approach to global programs: An independent evaluation. Washington, DC: World Bank.
go back to reference WBG-OED. (2004). Addressing the challenges of globalization: An independent evaluation of the World Bank’s approach to global programs. Washington, DC: World Bank. WBG-OED. (2004). Addressing the challenges of globalization: An independent evaluation of the World Bank’s approach to global programs. Washington, DC: World Bank.
go back to reference WEF (World Economic Forum). (2018). The global risks report 2018. Geneva: World Economic Forum. WEF (World Economic Forum). (2018). The global risks report 2018. Geneva: World Economic Forum.
go back to reference Wyplosz, C. (2015). The centralization-decentralization issue (European economy discussion paper 014). Brussels: European Commission. Wyplosz, C. (2015). The centralization-decentralization issue (European economy discussion paper 014). Brussels: European Commission.
Metadata
Title
Global Public Goods and Governance for Addressing Sustainability
Author
Inge Kaul
Copyright Year
2019
Publisher
Springer International Publishing
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-14000-7_24