Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Dynamic Games and Applications 2/2018

21-04-2017

Intertemporal Non-separability and Dynamic Oligopoly

Authors: Curtis Eberwein, Ted To

Published in: Dynamic Games and Applications | Issue 2/2018

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We construct a framework for modeling dynamic Cournot oligopoly. We consider models where utility maximizing consumers give rise to demand functions that depend on current and prior period prices. Future demand depends on the current price and consumers, and firms must take this into account when making their decisions. Focusing on problems that yield dynamic demand functions that are linear in current and prior period price, we characterize the unique Markov perfect equilibrium in linear strategies. We then demonstrate the applicability of our framework through a series of practical examples.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
It is straightforward to allow for heterogeneity of consumers (we provide two such examples) provided that conditions ensuring nonnegativity of consumption are satisfied.
 
2
Given quadratic utility functions, there will generally exist an equilibrium with “policy functions” that are linear in the state. We focus on such equilibria.
 
3
It is straightforward to allow for i.i.d. idiosyncratic shocks, i.e., \(c_{it}={\bar{c}}+\varepsilon _{it}\). In this case, rather than taking rival outputs as given, firms must form beliefs over the distribution over rival outputs.
 
4
Note that we have specified the problem as one where in equilibrium, rival outputs are functions of the prior period price and an individual firm maximizes discounted expected profits through choice of price. Equivalently, we could invert (1) to get \(p_t(x_t^i+X_t^{-i},p_{t-1})\) and specify an individual firm’s problem more traditionally as:
$$\begin{aligned} V^i(p_{t-1},c_t)=\max _{x_t^i}[(p_t(x_t^i+X_t^{-i}(p_{t-1},c_t ),p_{t-1})-c_t)x_t^i+\beta E_tV^i(p_t,c_{t+1})]. \end{aligned}$$
In equilibrium, for every \(i, x_t^i\) is a best response to \(X_t^{-i}\) (i.e., \(x_t^i\) solves the Bellman equation) and \(X_t^{-i}=\sum _{j\ne i}x_t^j\).
 
5
With more complicated shocks and additional information and behavioral assumptions to ensure solvability, prices can be shown to follow more complicated stochastic processes. We examine one such extension in “Appendix 2.”
 
6
As shown in the prior section, given linear consumer demand, expected prices will indeed have this form. Linearity of demand will be verified shortly.
 
7
This system is a subset of the system of equations used in Appendix 1 to prove Theorem 1. It is important to bear in mind that this is an artificial system of equations. For example, application of stability conditions to establish properties of the solution (i.e., the correspondence principle in macroeconomics) would be a mistake since stability in the artificial system is meaningless.
 
8
It is straightforward to introduce a cost to holding inventory. Suppose for example that inventory decays by the factor \(\delta \) so that the following budget constraint becomes: \(p_t(i_{t+1}-\delta i_t+y_t)+w_t\le {\bar{w}}\).
 
9
This can easily be derived from the fact that \((N-1)^2\ge 0\).
 
10
The case where \(d<0\) is analogous but requires \(\lambda =-\sqrt{(2q-1)/\beta }\).
 
Literature
1.
go back to reference Becker GS, Murphy KM (1988) A theory of rational addiction. J Polit Econ 96(4):675–700CrossRef Becker GS, Murphy KM (1988) A theory of rational addiction. J Polit Econ 96(4):675–700CrossRef
2.
go back to reference Bils M, Klenow PJ (2004) Some evidence on the importance of sticky prices. J Polit Econ 112(5):947–985CrossRef Bils M, Klenow PJ (2004) Some evidence on the importance of sticky prices. J Polit Econ 112(5):947–985CrossRef
4.
5.
go back to reference Carlton DW (1986) The rigidity of prices. Am Econ Rev 76:637–658 Carlton DW (1986) The rigidity of prices. Am Econ Rev 76:637–658
6.
go back to reference Caucutt EM, Ghosh M, Kelton CM (1999) Durability versus concentration as an explanation for price inflexibility. Rev Ind Organ 14:27–50CrossRef Caucutt EM, Ghosh M, Kelton CM (1999) Durability versus concentration as an explanation for price inflexibility. Rev Ind Organ 14:27–50CrossRef
7.
go back to reference Cooper R, Haltiwanger J (1990) Inventories and the propagation of sectoral shocks. Am Econ Rev 80(1):170–190 Cooper R, Haltiwanger J (1990) Inventories and the propagation of sectoral shocks. Am Econ Rev 80(1):170–190
8.
go back to reference Driskill R (1997) Durable-goods monopoly, increasing marginal cost and depreciation. Economica 64(253):137–154CrossRef Driskill R (1997) Durable-goods monopoly, increasing marginal cost and depreciation. Economica 64(253):137–154CrossRef
9.
go back to reference Driskill R (2001) Durable goods oligopoly. Int J Ind Organ 19(3–4):391–413CrossRef Driskill R (2001) Durable goods oligopoly. Int J Ind Organ 19(3–4):391–413CrossRef
10.
11.
go back to reference Dudine P, Hendel I, Lizzeri A (2006) Storable good monopoly: the role of commitment. Am Econ Rev 96(5):1706–1719CrossRef Dudine P, Hendel I, Lizzeri A (2006) Storable good monopoly: the role of commitment. Am Econ Rev 96(5):1706–1719CrossRef
12.
go back to reference Fethke G, Jagannathan R (1996) Habit persistence, heterogeneous tastes, and imperfect competition. J Econ Dyn Control 20:1193–1207CrossRefMATH Fethke G, Jagannathan R (1996) Habit persistence, heterogeneous tastes, and imperfect competition. J Econ Dyn Control 20:1193–1207CrossRefMATH
13.
go back to reference Hall RE (1988) Intertemporal substitution in consumption. J Polit Econ 96:339–357CrossRef Hall RE (1988) Intertemporal substitution in consumption. J Polit Econ 96:339–357CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Intertemporal Non-separability and Dynamic Oligopoly
Authors
Curtis Eberwein
Ted To
Publication date
21-04-2017
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Dynamic Games and Applications / Issue 2/2018
Print ISSN: 2153-0785
Electronic ISSN: 2153-0793
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-017-0220-z

Other articles of this Issue 2/2018

Dynamic Games and Applications 2/2018 Go to the issue

Premium Partner