Skip to main content
Top

2019 | Book

Irving Fisher

insite
SEARCH

About this book

Acclaimed by Joseph Schumpeter as ‘The greatest economist the United States has ever produced’, this book examines the life and work of American economist and statistician Irving Fisher (1867–1947). Fisher’s reputation suffered for decades after his incorrect predictions for the stock market in October 1929 and the impact of Keynesian macroeconomics, but the importance of his work came to be recognized through the advocacy of many prestigious scholars including Milton Friedman, Hyman Minsky and James Tobin. With pivotal contributions including his Debt-Deflation Theory, Fisher Diagram and Ideal Index Number, his research in neoclassical economics influenced policymaking in his own day as well as during the recent financial crisis. This volume will be of interest to all those interested in the twentieth century transformation of economics.

Table of Contents

Frontmatter
Chapter 1. Economic Scientist, Economic and Social Reformer
Abstract
Economic Scientist, Economic and Social Reformer: An overview of the career and contributions of Irving Fisher (1867–1947) of Yale, an outstanding scientific economist whose reputation within the discipline of economics has recovered from his varied efforts at social reform (prohibition of alcohol, a new world map projection, dietary reform, a new calendar, eugenics) and being spectacularly wrong about the stock market in October 1929.
Robert W. Dimand
Chapter 2. Indifference Curves and a Hydraulic Model of General Equilibrium
Abstract
Indifference Curves and a Hydraulic Model of General Equilibrium examines Fisher’s Mathematical Investigations in the Theory of Value and Prices (Yale PhD dissertation 1891, published 1892) which not only independently reinvented general equilibrium analysis before Fisher read Walras or Edgeworth (hence Robert Dorfman’s view that the thesis should have been rejected for unnecessary duplication of existing literature) but also introduced ordinal utility and indifference curves and constructed a hydraulic model to simulate the determination of equilibrium prices and quantities (justifying Paul Samuelson’s verdict that it was “the greatest Ph.D. dissertation ever written in economics”).
Robert W. Dimand
Chapter 3. Revitalizing the Quantity Theory of Money: From the Fisher Relation to the Fisher Equation
Abstract
Revitalizing the Quantity Theory of Money: From the Fisher Relation to the Fisher Equation traces Fisher’s revitalization of the quantity theory of money from Appreciation and Interest (1896) to The Purchasing Power of Money (1911a, with Harry G. Brown), as Fisher upheld the quantity theory (with money neutral in the long run but not the short run) against populist bimetallists (who saw long-run real benefits from increasing the quantity of money, e.g. William Jennings Bryan) and their hard-money opponents (who denied that the price level was determined by the amount of money, e.g. J. L. Laughlin of the University of Chicago): the 1896 “Fisher relation” between interest rates in any two standards (real and nominal interest, uncovered interest arbitrage parity between two currencies, the expectations theory of the term structure of interest rates) and the 1911 equation of exchange or “Fisher equation” (MV + MM′ = PT, first presented by Fisher with different notation in the Economic Journal in 1897, but drawing on an earlier single-velocity equation of exchange by Simon Newcomb, to whose memory Fisher 1911 was dedicated).
Robert W. Dimand
Chapter 4. The Fisher Diagram and the Neoclassical Theory of Interest and Capital
Abstract
The Fisher Diagram and the Neoclassical Theory of Interest and Capital: After Fisher’s recovery from tuberculosis, he wrote developed the neoclassical theory of interest and capital in The Nature of Capital and Income (1906) and The Rate of Interest (1907) (later combined as The Theory of Interest, 1930), emphasizing the time pattern of expected income, the concept of present discounted value, and the role of the interest rate in equilibrating investment and saving, balancing impatience to spend with opportunity to earn interest, as shown in the “Fisher diagram” (the two-period consumption-smoothing diagram on Fisher [The Rate of Interest, Macmillan, New York, 1907, p. 409]). The Fisher diagram’s depiction of the terms of trade between consumption in two periods inspired fundamental diagrams in risk analysis (terms of trade between consumption in two states of the world) and international trade theory, while his identification of the present discounted value of expected lifetime income as the relevant budget constraint for consumption decisions (assuming perfect credit markets) led to the Friedman permanent-income and Modigliani-Ando-Brumberg life-cycle theories of consumption. Ironically, given the neoclassical emphasis of Fisher’s work on interest and capital, his 1907 demonstration of the possibility of multiple solutions for Boehm-Bawerk’s average period of production was a precursor of capital paradoxes that emerged fifty or sixty years later in the Cambridge capital theory controversies.
Robert W. Dimand
Chapter 5. Taming the “Dance of the Dollar”: From the Compensated Dollar to 100% Money
Abstract
Taming the “Dance of the Dollar”: From the Compensated Dollar to 100% Money: While Fisher argued that money was neutral in the long run, from Fisher (The Purchasing Power of Money. Macmillan, New York, 1911, Chapter IV) onwards he held that in the short run the “so-called business cycle” was really a “dance of the dollar” in transition periods driven by monetary shocks and slow adjustment of inflationary expectations. His 1926 article “A Statistical Relation between Unemployment and Price Changes” was reprinted in the Journal of Political Economy in 1973 (a quarter century after Fisher’s death) as “Lost and Found: I Discovered the Phillips Curve—Irving Fisher.” To stabilize the economy, Fisher campaigned for a “compensated dollar” that would vary the dollar price of gold to hold a price index constant, and, with his political ally Senator Robert L. Owen, managed to insert in the Senate version of the Owen-Glass Bill a mandate for the Federal Reserve to stabilize the price level (but Rep. Carter Glass kept it out of the final version of the Federal Reserve Act).
Robert W. Dimand
Chapter 6. Fighting Money Illusion: The Fisher Ideal Index Number
Abstract
Fighting Money Illusion: The Fisher Ideal Index Number: If governments would not stabilize the price level, Fisher would combat The Money Illusion (the title of his 1928 book) by educating the public about how the purchasing power of money changed. Since governments did not then provide price indices, an Index Number Institute (located in the basement of Fisher’s home) would calculate a weekly wholesale price index, accompanied by a weekly newspaper article by Fisher on price changes, using the “Fisher ideal index” (the geometric mean of the Paasche and Laspeyres indices), the index number formula that Fisher’s Making of Index Numbers (1922) had shown came nearest to satisfying a set of seven statistical criteria chosen by Fisher and that in recent decades has come to be increasingly adopted by governments. Beyond education about price-level fluctuations, Fisher also pioneered indexation, persuading Rand Kardex to issue bonds indexed to Fisher’s price index.
Robert W. Dimand
Chapter 7. Hubris, Nemesis, and Analysis: “Stock Prices Appear to Have Reached a Permanently High Plateau”
Abstract
Hubris, Nemesis, and Analysis: In the 1920s Irving Fisher made a fortune of ten million dollars in the stock market, of which he then lost eleven million, which in the words of John Kenneth Galbraith was “a sizeable sum, even for an economics professor.” Arguing correctly that fluctuations in the purchasing power of money meant that money was not a riskless asset, and that the mistaken perception that government bonds were thus riskless assets unlike stocks would lead to underpricing of stocks relative to bonds, Fisher fervently, memorably and quotably advocated investment in stocks: he famously said that “Stock prices appeared to have reached a permanently high plateau” in October 1929, at the start of an 85% decline in stock prices over three years. Edward Prescott and Ellen McGrattan have controversially argued that, given available statistics, Fisher was justified in his optimism about stock prices; less controversially, Kathryn Dominguez et al. (American Economic Review 78:595–612, 1988) argue that Fisher could not have predicted the policy mistakes that transformed a cyclical downturn into the Great Depression.
Robert W. Dimand
Chapter 8. The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions
Abstract
The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions: During the Great Depression, Fisher provided the Hoover and Roosevelt Administrations with much advice (largely unsolicited) about the need for what Fisher termed reflation. Fisher’s emphasis on monetary policy came to be overshadowed by Keynes’s theory of employment and the Kahn-Keynes multiplier analysis of the effect of fiscal policy. Fisher’s “Debt-Depression Theory of Great Depressions” (Econometrica 1: 337–357, 1933), explaining what had gone wrong, attracted little attention at the time, given the wreckage of Fisher’s reputation, but from 1975 onwards influenced the views of Hyman Minsky, James Tobin, Ben Bernanke and Mervyn King on how to avoid another depression—an influence that had practical relevance for the response of Bernanke and King to the possibility of the collapse of financial intermediation in 2007 and 2008.
Robert W. Dimand
Chapter 9. Changing Economics: Irving Fisher, the Cowles Commission, and the Econometric Society
Abstract
Changing Economics: Fisher, the Cowles Commission, and the Econometric Society: From his simulation model of general equilibrium in the 1890s through his subsequent use of correlation analysis, distributed lags (the Fisher lag with arithmetically decreasing weights), the Fisher relation between real and nominal interest, the Fisher two-period optimal consumption diagram, and index number theory, Fisher’s approach to economics contrasted with the textbooks and journal articles of his mainstream contemporaries (and even more with another alternative to the mainstream, the institutionalist economics of Thorstein Veblen, with whom Fisher shared a dissertation adviser) but later economics came to look increasingly like Fisher’s economics. Two organizations that Fisher helped create, the Cowles Commission for Research in Economics and the Econometric Society (with its journal Econometrica), figured prominently in this transformation of economics.
Robert W. Dimand
Chapter 10. Fisher’s Legacy in Economics
Abstract
Fisher’s Legacy in Economics: This chapter examines Fisher’s scientific legacy in economics. Fisher’s reputation suffered for decades from his stock market debacle and from the impact of Keynesian macroeconomics, but his importance as the outstanding American economic scientist of the first half of the twentieth century came to be recognized through the advocacy of, among others, Maurice Allais, Milton Friedman, Hyman Minsky, Paul Samuelson, and James Tobin (but not, e.g., Friedman’s coauthor Anna Jacobson Schwartz).
Robert W. Dimand
Backmatter
Metadata
Title
Irving Fisher
Author
Prof. Dr. Robert W. Dimand
Copyright Year
2019
Electronic ISBN
978-3-030-05177-8
Print ISBN
978-3-030-05176-1
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05177-8