Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Empirical Economics 3/2024

28-08-2023

Oil price shocks and macroeconomic dynamics: How important is the role of nonlinearity?

Authors: Inwook Hwang, Jaebeom Kim

Published in: Empirical Economics | Issue 3/2024

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This study examines the state-dependent effects of crude oil price shocks on the US aggregate economy. Using a smooth transition vector autoregressive model, we assess the effects of normalized supply and demand shocks in the global oil market over the different phases of the business cycle. Our findings show that the link between oil prices and macroeconomic dynamics is nonlinear and that structural shocks in the oil market conditional on recessions have a greater and more persistent contractionary impact on macroeconomic variables including industrial production, employment, and consumer price inflation. Forecast error variance decomposition confirms that oil prices have much stronger stagflationary effects during recessions.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
This index is available at Baumeister’s website (https://​sites.​google.​com/​site/​cjsbaumeister/​research).
 
2
The RAC series is available monthly starting in January 1974 and going back one more year following (Barsky and Kilian 2002), which allows us to include the first oil shock during October 1973 through March 1974.
 
3
They use the US GDP as the output. However, due to the data unavailability at monthly frequency, we use employment and industrial production as plausible substitutes to GDP.
 
4
The main goal is to describe the transition between different phases of the business cycle as accurate as possible in our model. For this purpose, we use 12 month moving average terms. The transition indicator with 12 months reflects well our goal than other terms over the observed frequencies of the US NBER-recessions. Details for this issue are available upon request.
 
5
The smoothness parameter \(\gamma \) is calibrated as defined by the “NBER based Recession Indicators for the United States from Peak through Trough” (https://​fred.​stlouisfed.​org/​series/​USRECM). In the full sample, there are 78 recession indicators over 552 observations (that is, 78/552 \( \cong \) 14%). Then, “recessions” are defined as periods in which \(F (z_{t}) \ge \) 0.86 so that the probability of being in a recession is sufficiently high, and \(\gamma \) is calibrated in order that Pr(\(F (z_{t})\) \( \ge \) 0.86) \( \cong \) 14%, implying \(\gamma =\) 2.0.
 
6
Figure 1 plots the transition by our logistic function \(F (z_{t})\). \(F (z_{t})\) is highly correlated with NBER-recession indicator, and shows that high realization of \(F (z_{t})\) easily takes over threshold value \(F (z_{t}) \ge 0.86\) which is over each of the six NBER-recession episodes. The Pearson correlation coefficient between two data sets is \(r =0.45\) with associated p value = 0.00.
 
7
We use 20,000 draws for our baseline and robustness estimates and drop the first 80% draws to maintain the adequate acceptance rates of candidate draws. For details, refer to Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012).
 
8
The lag selection is consistent with previous literature (e.g., see (Rahman and Serletis 2010; Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2012; Caggiano et al. 2014)).
 
9
For details, see Appendix 7.1.
 
10
For robustness, we consider different orderings of the second block, \(X_{2 t}\), and confirm that variations on the orderings are reasonable and markedly robust. The results are available upon request.
 
11
We appreciate the anonymous referee to point out this issue. To identify the structural shocks for the US-variable block, we also estimate four-variable models that contain only one of the US variables at a time and confirm that an absence of interaction between US macroeconomic variables somewhat weakens the contractionary effects of oil price shocks during recessionary periods. However, it does not substantially change the results from the baseline estimates (See Fig. 6). Further, we also run variations on the different orderings of the second block, \(X_{2 t}\) (See Sect. 5.3).
 
12
According to Kilian (2009), this residual is related with a precautionary demand for oil with high uncertainty because the more uncertain the global crude oil market, the higher the amount of precautionary demand of oil.
 
13
Following Kilian (2009), we normalize three structural shocks to represent to raise the real price of oil, implying that two demand-driven shocks are positive, while a supply shock is negative.
 
14
Global demand shocks have direct and indirect effects on the US economy through raising the price of oil. As shown in Kilian (2009), both effects on the aggregate economy are of opposite signs and the adverse effect of higher oil prices makes the aggregate demand shock contractionary with a delay. This delay is explained by two dynamic responses: (1) as global activity rises, the aggregate demand shock stimulates the US economic activity, and (2) the real price of oil increases and then output growth declines over time.
 
15
It reflects the fact that the Fed conducts monetary policy to influence the availability and cost of credit in the economy after economic shocks affect macroeconomic variables such as consumer price, labor market indicator, and output (e.g., see (Caggiano et al. 2014, 2017; Nodari 2014)).
 
Literature
go back to reference Auerbach AJ, Gorodnichenko Y (2012) Measuring the output responses to fiscal policy. Am Econ J Econ Pol 4(2):1–27CrossRef Auerbach AJ, Gorodnichenko Y (2012) Measuring the output responses to fiscal policy. Am Econ J Econ Pol 4(2):1–27CrossRef
go back to reference Barsky RB, Kilian L (2002) Do we really know that oil caused the great stagflation? A monetary alternative. NBER Macroecon Annu 16:137–183CrossRef Barsky RB, Kilian L (2002) Do we really know that oil caused the great stagflation? A monetary alternative. NBER Macroecon Annu 16:137–183CrossRef
go back to reference Baumeister C, Hamilton JD (2019) Structural interpretation of vector autoregressions with incomplete identification: Revisiting the role of oil supply and demand shocks. American Economic Review 109(5):1873–1910CrossRef Baumeister C, Hamilton JD (2019) Structural interpretation of vector autoregressions with incomplete identification: Revisiting the role of oil supply and demand shocks. American Economic Review 109(5):1873–1910CrossRef
go back to reference Bernanke BS (1983) Irreversibility, uncertainty, and cyclical investment. Quart J Econ 98:85–106CrossRef Bernanke BS (1983) Irreversibility, uncertainty, and cyclical investment. Quart J Econ 98:85–106CrossRef
go back to reference Burbidge J, Harrison A (1984) Testing for the effects of oil-price rises using vector autoregressions. Int Econ Rev 25(2):459–484CrossRef Burbidge J, Harrison A (1984) Testing for the effects of oil-price rises using vector autoregressions. Int Econ Rev 25(2):459–484CrossRef
go back to reference Caggiano G, Castelnuovo E, Figueres JM (2017) Economic policy uncertainty and unemployment in the United States: A nonlinear approach. Econ Lett 151:31–34CrossRef Caggiano G, Castelnuovo E, Figueres JM (2017) Economic policy uncertainty and unemployment in the United States: A nonlinear approach. Econ Lett 151:31–34CrossRef
go back to reference Caggiano G, Castelnuovo E, Groshenny N (2014) Uncertainty shocks and unemployment dynamics in US recessions. J Monet Econ 67:78–92CrossRef Caggiano G, Castelnuovo E, Groshenny N (2014) Uncertainty shocks and unemployment dynamics in US recessions. J Monet Econ 67:78–92CrossRef
go back to reference Choi S, Furceri D, Loungani P, Mishra S, Poplawski-Ribeiro M (2018) Oil prices and inflation dynamics: evidence from advanced and developing economies. J Int Money Finance 82:71–96CrossRef Choi S, Furceri D, Loungani P, Mishra S, Poplawski-Ribeiro M (2018) Oil prices and inflation dynamics: evidence from advanced and developing economies. J Int Money Finance 82:71–96CrossRef
go back to reference Darby MR (1982) The price of oil and world inflation and recession. Am Econ Rev 72(4):738–751 Darby MR (1982) The price of oil and world inflation and recession. Am Econ Rev 72(4):738–751
go back to reference Davis SJ, Haltiwanger J (2001) Sectoral job creation and destruction responses to oil price changes. J Monet Econ 48:465–512CrossRef Davis SJ, Haltiwanger J (2001) Sectoral job creation and destruction responses to oil price changes. J Monet Econ 48:465–512CrossRef
go back to reference Gao L, Kim H, Saba R (2014) How do oil price shocks affect consumer prices? Energy Econ 45:313–323CrossRef Gao L, Kim H, Saba R (2014) How do oil price shocks affect consumer prices? Energy Econ 45:313–323CrossRef
go back to reference Granger CWJ, Teräsvirta T (1993) Modeling nonlinear economic relationships. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef Granger CWJ, Teräsvirta T (1993) Modeling nonlinear economic relationships. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef
go back to reference Hamilton JD (1983) Oil and the macroeconomy since world war II. J Polit Econ 91(2):228–248CrossRef Hamilton JD (1983) Oil and the macroeconomy since world war II. J Polit Econ 91(2):228–248CrossRef
go back to reference Hamilton JD (1988) A neoclassical model of unemployment and the business cycle. J Polit Econ 96(3):593–617CrossRef Hamilton JD (1988) A neoclassical model of unemployment and the business cycle. J Polit Econ 96(3):593–617CrossRef
go back to reference Hamilton JD (2011) Nonlinearities and the macroeconomic effects of oil prices. Macroecon Dyn 15(S3):364–378CrossRef Hamilton JD (2011) Nonlinearities and the macroeconomic effects of oil prices. Macroecon Dyn 15(S3):364–378CrossRef
go back to reference Herrera AM, Lagalo LG, Wada T (2011) Oil price shocks and industrial production: Is the relationship linear? Macroecon Dyn 15(S3):472–497CrossRef Herrera AM, Lagalo LG, Wada T (2011) Oil price shocks and industrial production: Is the relationship linear? Macroecon Dyn 15(S3):472–497CrossRef
go back to reference Hooker MA (1996) What happened to the oil price-macroeconomy relationship? J Monet Econ 38(2):195–213CrossRef Hooker MA (1996) What happened to the oil price-macroeconomy relationship? J Monet Econ 38(2):195–213CrossRef
go back to reference Hooker MA (2002) Are oil shocks inflationary? Asymmetric and nonlinear specifications versus changes in regime. J Money Credit Bank 34(2):540–561CrossRef Hooker MA (2002) Are oil shocks inflationary? Asymmetric and nonlinear specifications versus changes in regime. J Money Credit Bank 34(2):540–561CrossRef
go back to reference Jurado K, Ludvigson SC, Ng S (2015) Measuring uncertainty. Am Econ Rev 105(3):1177–1216CrossRef Jurado K, Ludvigson SC, Ng S (2015) Measuring uncertainty. Am Econ Rev 105(3):1177–1216CrossRef
go back to reference Hwang I, Kim J (2021) Oil price shocks and the US stock market: a nonlinear approach. J Empir Finance 64:23–36CrossRef Hwang I, Kim J (2021) Oil price shocks and the US stock market: a nonlinear approach. J Empir Finance 64:23–36CrossRef
go back to reference Kilian L (2009) Not all oil price shocks are alike: disentangling demand and supply shocks in the crude oil market. Am Econ Rev 99(3):1053–1069CrossRef Kilian L (2009) Not all oil price shocks are alike: disentangling demand and supply shocks in the crude oil market. Am Econ Rev 99(3):1053–1069CrossRef
go back to reference Kilian L, Park C (2009) The impact of oil price shocks on the US stock market. Int Econ Rev 50(4):1267–1287CrossRef Kilian L, Park C (2009) The impact of oil price shocks on the US stock market. Int Econ Rev 50(4):1267–1287CrossRef
go back to reference Kilian L, Vigfusson RJ (2011) Nonlinearities in the oil price-output relationship. Macroecon Dyn 15(S3):337–363CrossRef Kilian L, Vigfusson RJ (2011) Nonlinearities in the oil price-output relationship. Macroecon Dyn 15(S3):337–363CrossRef
go back to reference Kilian L, Vigfusson RJ (2017) The role of oil price shocks in causing U.S. recessions. J Money Credit Bank 49(8):1747–1777CrossRef Kilian L, Vigfusson RJ (2017) The role of oil price shocks in causing U.S. recessions. J Money Credit Bank 49(8):1747–1777CrossRef
go back to reference Kilian L, Zhou X (2018) Modeling fluctuations in the global demand for commodities. J Int Money Financ 88:54–78CrossRef Kilian L, Zhou X (2018) Modeling fluctuations in the global demand for commodities. J Int Money Financ 88:54–78CrossRef
go back to reference Koop G, Potter S (1999) Dynamic asymmetries in U.S. unemployment. J Bus Econ Stat 17(3):298–312 Koop G, Potter S (1999) Dynamic asymmetries in U.S. unemployment. J Bus Econ Stat 17(3):298–312
go back to reference Lee K, Ni S (2002) On the dynamic effects of oil price shocks: a study using industry level data. J Monet Econ 49(4):823–852CrossRef Lee K, Ni S (2002) On the dynamic effects of oil price shocks: a study using industry level data. J Monet Econ 49(4):823–852CrossRef
go back to reference Ludvigson SC, Ma S, Ng S (2021) Uncertainty and business cycles: Exogenous impulse or endogenous response? Am Econ J Macroecon 13(4):369–410CrossRef Ludvigson SC, Ma S, Ng S (2021) Uncertainty and business cycles: Exogenous impulse or endogenous response? Am Econ J Macroecon 13(4):369–410CrossRef
go back to reference Mork KA (1989) Oil and the macroeconomy when prices go up and down: An extension of Hamilton’s results. J Polit Econ 97(3):740–744CrossRef Mork KA (1989) Oil and the macroeconomy when prices go up and down: An extension of Hamilton’s results. J Polit Econ 97(3):740–744CrossRef
go back to reference Morley J, Piger J (2012) The asymmetric business cycle. Rev Econ Stat 94(1):208–221CrossRef Morley J, Piger J (2012) The asymmetric business cycle. Rev Econ Stat 94(1):208–221CrossRef
go back to reference Nodari G (2014) Financial regulation policy uncertainty and credit spreads in the US. J Macroecon 41:122–132CrossRef Nodari G (2014) Financial regulation policy uncertainty and credit spreads in the US. J Macroecon 41:122–132CrossRef
go back to reference Pindyck RS (1991) Irreversibility, uncertainty, and investment. J Econ Literat 29(3):1110–1148 Pindyck RS (1991) Irreversibility, uncertainty, and investment. J Econ Literat 29(3):1110–1148
go back to reference Rahman S, Serletis A (2010) The asymmetric effects of oil price and monetary policy shocks: a nonlinear VAR approach. Energy Econ 32:1460–1466CrossRef Rahman S, Serletis A (2010) The asymmetric effects of oil price and monetary policy shocks: a nonlinear VAR approach. Energy Econ 32:1460–1466CrossRef
go back to reference Teräsvirta T, Yang Y (2014) Linearity and misspecification tests for vector smooth transition regression models. CREATES Research Papers, 2014-04 Teräsvirta T, Yang Y (2014) Linearity and misspecification tests for vector smooth transition regression models. CREATES Research Papers, 2014-04
go back to reference Van Dijk D, Teräsvirta T, Franses PH (2002) Smooth transition autoregressive models–A survey of recent developments. Econom Rev 21(1):1–47MathSciNetCrossRef Van Dijk D, Teräsvirta T, Franses PH (2002) Smooth transition autoregressive models–A survey of recent developments. Econom Rev 21(1):1–47MathSciNetCrossRef
go back to reference Zhu H, Su X, You W, Ren Y (2017) Asymmetric effects of oil price shocks on stock returns: evidence from a two-stage Markov regime-switching approach. Appl Econ 49(25):2491–2507CrossRef Zhu H, Su X, You W, Ren Y (2017) Asymmetric effects of oil price shocks on stock returns: evidence from a two-stage Markov regime-switching approach. Appl Econ 49(25):2491–2507CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Oil price shocks and macroeconomic dynamics: How important is the role of nonlinearity?
Authors
Inwook Hwang
Jaebeom Kim
Publication date
28-08-2023
Publisher
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Published in
Empirical Economics / Issue 3/2024
Print ISSN: 0377-7332
Electronic ISSN: 1435-8921
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-023-02484-w

Other articles of this Issue 3/2024

Empirical Economics 3/2024 Go to the issue

Premium Partner