Skip to main content
Top
Published in:
Cover of the book

Open Access 2017 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

60. On Decision-Making

Author : Olivier Serrat

Published in: Knowledge Solutions

Publisher: Springer Singapore

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Decision-making is a stream of inquiry, not an event. Decision-driven organizations design and manage it as such: they match decision-making styles to appropriate techniques and, wherever possible, encourage parties to play roles rife with dissent and debate; decision rights are part of the design.
In a Word Decision-making is a stream of inquiry, not an event. Decision-driven organizations design and manage it as such: they match decision-making styles to appropriate techniques and, wherever possible, encourage parties to play roles rife with dissent and debate; decision rights are part of the design.
https://static-content.springer.com/image/chp%3A10.1007%2F978-981-10-0983-9_60/MediaObjects/372422_1_En_60_Figa_HTML.gif

Decisions, Decisions

A decision is the cognitive process of choosing between possible actions in a situation of uncertainty. By definition, the steps entailed lead to a final choice, that is, the selection of a sequence of activities among several alternative scenarios, based on values and preferences, purportedly resulting in a more optimal outcome.
In view of the resources organizations pool, decision-making permeates all dimensions of corporate life, be they (i) strategic—related to the design of a long-term plan of action to achieve a particular goal, (ii) organizational—related to the way different parts and aspects of a group are arranged to deliver the goal, or (iii) operational—related to the way individuals and groups work on a daily basis to accomplish specific results toward the goal.1 It follows that decision-making is a conditioning ingredient of success in any venture. The stakes are high: organizations that make better, faster, and more effective decisions—both small, routine, and big, one-off decisions—will outrun competitors and outshine peers. Therefore, one might expect that organizations would put copious options on the table and invite sufficient evaluation to make certain the best choice emerges.

On Decision-Making Techniques and Styles …

Inevitably, given the pressing omnipresence of decision situations, the world of organizations is not short of techniques. The main clusters articulate decision-making models, help choose between options, make financial decisions, improve decision-making, organize group decision-making, surface values and preferences, and decide whether to go ahead. Then again, whether the tools at hand are leveraged depends on styles that—born of the typology of the organization and associated configuration2—range from autocratic to unanimity-based decision-making, each with its raison d’être and related pros and cons (Figs. 60.1 and 60.2).

… And What Typically Determines Their Use

Ten primary criteria shape decision-making. These comprise the decision environment 3 that may influence the decision style, the complexity of the decision being made, the value of the decision’s desired outcome, alternative scenarios that have the potential to lead to the desired outcome, the information available to support the decision-making process and cognitive biases to its selection and interpretation, the quality requirements of the decision, the personalities of those involved in decision-making, the time available to conduct the decision-making process, the necessary level of commitment to or acceptance of the decision, and the impact on valued relationships that the choice of decision style may have.
It’s not hard to make decisions when you know what your values are.
—Roy Disney
Sure enough, several of these criteria can hold at the same time and amplify one another. Assuming organizations do not eschew problem analysis to rush decision-making—a big, hairy, and audacious hypothesis,4 that, four recurring themes regularly conspire to warp decisions. They have to do with bounded rationality, cognitive bias, personality, and free will. First, the information at hand, the information-processing ability of the mind, and what time is available bear strongly on decision-making. (Bounded rationality does not often conduce optimal decisions by “maximizers;” again and again, “satisficers” reach for what solution is good enough.) Second, cognitive biases creep into decision-making processes. (A select list includes anchoring and adjustment, attribution asymmetry, choice-supportive bias, framing bias, groupthink, incremental decision-making and escalating commitment, optimism or wishful thinking, premature termination of search for evidence, inertia, recency, repetition bias, role fulfillment, selective perception, selective search for evidence, source credibility bias, and underestimates of uncertainty and the illusion of control.) Third, personality profiles color cognitive styles. (Psychological traits revealed by the Myers–Briggs Type Indicator along four bipolar dimensions—extroversion and introversion, sensing and intuiting, thinking and feeling, and judging and perceiving—correlate with decision-making styles. In any organization, the predominance of one psychological type will sway approaches to decision-making. What is more, national or cross-cultural peculiarities exist across entire societies.) Fourth, advances in social neuroscience increasingly question whether and in what sense rational agents exercise control over their actions or decisions, thereby testing the easy presumption of free will. What hopes, after that, are there for better decision-making?

Toward Decision-Driven Organizations

“It is hard to imagine a more stupid or more dangerous way of making decisions than by putting those decisions in the hands of people who pay no price for being wrong,” Thomas Sowell reasons. Indeed, many organizations treat decision-making as an event, the performance of which is more often than not the prerogative of a few—not necessarily best equipped—where there is obdurate proclivity for formal authority.5
Most discussions of decision making assume that only senior executives make decisions or that only senior executives’ decisions matter. This is a dangerous mistake.
—Peter Drucker
To enrich decisions in the majority of decision-making styles, two related concerns should be concurrently raised and addressed:
  • Quoting Isaac Azimov, “It is change, continuing change, inevitable change, that is the dominant factor in society today. No sensible decision can be made any longer without taking into account not only the world as it is, but the world as it will be …” Too often, decision-making is considered an exercise in advocacy; it is, rather, a process of inquiry. How might decision-making encompass the larger organizational context, organizational knowledge, inter- and intraorganizational relationships, and external environment that ultimately determine the success of a selected course of action?
  • Decision rights 6 are a vital but insufficiently understood component of organizational design. Who is empowered to make what types of decisions has profound effects on day-to-day performance; and yet, allocating decision rights to maximize that can be controversial and therefore difficult. To deepen the decision-making process, one should assign single point responsibility and accountability along a more delineated continuum of inputs, outputs, and outcomes. Where should decision rights be lodged in an organization and can one describe and assign more precise decision-making roles?

On Decision-Making as a Process

Decision-making is where thinking and doing overlap. For that to happen profitably in an organization, a decision must be logically consistent with what the parties to it know, want, and agree they can do. Nothing, then, could do decision-making a greater disservice than to treat it as a single, isolated event, not the clearly defined process it inherently is or rather should be.
Helpfully, David Garvin and Michael Roberto compare advocacy and inquiry approaches to decision-making. Advocacy tends to push a single solution. To make a compelling case for the proposal they hope to sell, proponents assert positives and downplay negatives; they offer no alternatives—instead, a go-no-go decision on the option is forced. The pitfalls of advocacy are many: reliance on one solution precludes the chance to explore alternatives; personalities come into play and disagreements grow fractious, probably antagonistic; behind-the-scenes maneuvering comes into play; the solution inevitably produces winners and losers—losers, to the extent they can, continue to fight the decision in the execution phase, thereby stretching decision cycle time.7 In contrast, the goal of inquiry is to reach agreement on a course of action. Because people hold diverse interests, inquiry makes convictions visible for testing; generates multiple alternatives; evaluates feasibility according to well-defined criteria using a range of techniques; fosters collaboration to work through differences of ideas, concepts, and assumptions; and helps arrive at an agreeable solution. Rather than suppress dissent and debate, inquiry encourages constructive conflict, consideration, and closure with perceived fairness; patently, it produces decisions of higher quality—decisions that not only advance an organization’s objectives but are also reached in a timely manner and can be implemented effectively.
Painting is something that takes place among the colors, and … one has to leave them alone completely, so that they can settle the matter among themselves. Their intercourse: this is the whole of painting. Whoever meddles, arranges, injects his human deliberation, his wit, his advocacy, his intellectual agility in any way, is already disturbing and clouding their activity.
—Rainer Maria Rilke

On Decision Rights

Marcia Blenko, Michael Mankins, and Paul Rogers make out six steps in which to (re)organize around decisions. First, organizations should know which decisions have a disproportionate impact on organizational performance—a decision inventory is a prerequisite to that.8 Second, they should determine where those decisions should happen. Third, they should organize the structure of decision nodes around sources of value. Fourth, they should figure out what level of authority decision-makers need, regardless of status, and give it to them. Fifth, they should align other parts of the organizational system, such as processes, data, and information—including their flows, measures, and incentives—to support decision-making and execution. Sixth, they should help managers develop the skills and behaviors necessary to make decisions and translate them into action quickly and well.
The man who is denied the opportunity of taking decisions of importance begins to regard as important the decisions he is allowed to take.
—C. Northcote Parkinson
Decision rights are the coin of the realm. In a small organization, an entrepreneur might know all about his or her business and make every decision with minimal supplementary data and information. However, as the scale and scope of operations grow, an entrepreneur will find it more difficult to decide. In a world of large organizations, one solution to this problem is to convey data and information to whoever possesses decision rights; another is to grant decision rights to whoever holds data and information.9 To strike a balance, modern organizations turn to both solutions10: the falling prices of information and communications technology have cut the costs of transmission and the growingly intense use of these technologies in many organizations confirms they convey more data and information to those with decision rights; at the same time, the common reliance on teams and other collaboration mechanisms implies that organizations are decentralizing decision rights. Naturally, the mix of solutions—and the centralization or decentralization of relationships it implies—is unique to the organization: yet, it is still a rare organization—especially in the public sector—that actually studies the optimal allocation of its stock of decision rights and acts on that knowledge to reap the fullest advantage.
If we can agree that the economic problem of society is mainly one of rapid adaptation to changes in the particular circumstances of time and place, it would seem to follow that the ultimate decisions must be left to the people who are familiar with these circumstances, who know directly of the relevant changes and of the resources immediately available to meet them. We cannot expect that this problem will be solved by first communicating all this knowledge to a central board which, after integrating all knowledge, issues its orders. We must solve it by some form of decentralization.
—Friedrich Hayek
There is more: decentralization is one thing; a more differentiated chain of deliverables for decision-making is another. Establishing what helps pinpoint who and demarcate how. Rogers and Blenko (2006) offered early guidance before the last article cited: advertising a tool of Bain & Company, Inc., they further untangle the decision-making process by identifying various activities that must occur for a decision to be made well. The name of the tool is RAPID: each letter in the acronym stands for an activity associated with decision-making. To begin, someone must “recommend” that a decision be made. Next, “input” will likely be required to inform the decision. Down the road, depending on corporate governance arrangements, one or several persons will formally “agree” to a recommendation before one or several persons wield the authority to “decide”. Subsequently, someone must, of course, “perform” the decision, meaning, execute it. The acronym does not suggest a strict sequence in which the five activities must occur, certainly in the preparatory stages: reality is iterative and RAPID merely happens to be a handy mnemonic. (This writer, for instance, believes that inputs should precede any recommendation, not just follow it, and may actually be required throughout the process.)11 In addition, agents may be assigned more than one activity. (The person recommending the decision may eventually be tasked with carrying it out.)
Paraphrasing Albert Camus, an organization’s value is the sum of the decisions it makes and executes. For sure, even good decisions such as may have been reached with RAPID occasionally engender bad outcomes. But redistributing decision rights because of a bad outcome—even though they were well allocated in the first place—will not help and could make matters worse. One should not confuse a particular outcome with the process itself.
The opinions expressed in this chapter are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Asian Development Bank, its Board of Directors, or the countries they represent.
Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 3.0 IGO license (http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by-nc/​3.​0/​igo/​) which permits any noncommercial use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the Asian Development Bank, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and indicate if changes were made.
Any dispute related to the use of the works of the Asian Development Bank that cannot be settled amicably shall be submitted to arbitration pursuant to the UNCITRAL rules. The use of the Asian Development Bank’s name for any purpose other than for attribution, and the use of the Asian Development Bank’s logo, shall be subject to a separate written license agreement between the Asian Development Bank and the user and is not authorized as part of this CC-IGO license. Note that the link provided above includes additional terms and conditions of the license.
The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder.
Footnotes
1
It follows that problems from suboptimal decision-making—since no organization is perfect—will occur in the same areas: (i) strategy—for example, where decisions are made with too little regard to those who are affected by them; (ii) organization—for instance, where there are overlapping responsibilities between decision-making groups, leading to lack of direction or duplication of effort; and (iii) operations—such as where implementation can prove difficult due to inconsistent factual analysis.
 
2
Mintzberg (1989) circumscribed seven basic types: entrepreneurial, machine, diversified, professional, innovative, missionary, and political. (Undoubtedly, one can find elements of all these forms in any particular organization.)
 
3
The decision environment would be a function of an organization’s organizational context, organizational knowledge, inter- and intraorganizational relationships, and the external environment.
 
4
Manifestly, a problem should first be analyzed with effective questions so that the data and information gathered can afterward inform a course of action.
 
5
In the twenty-first century, many still assume the lines and boxes on an organizational chart are a key determinant of performance. Hierarchy is passé: Hayek (1945) understood that as early as 1945. Rather, an organization’s structure should be in tune with its decisions with consideration to quality, speed, yield, and effort. Blenko et al. (2010) identify 10 drivers that may undermine or support effective decisions, for assessment using a four-point Likert scale from strongly disagree to strongly agree. They are (i) structure (our structure helps—rather than hinders—the decisions most critical to our success); (ii) roles (individuals understand their responsibilities and accountabilities in our most critical decisions); (iii) processes (our processes are designed to produce effective, timely decisions and action); (iv) information (the people in critical decision roles have the data and information they need when and how they need them); (v) measures and incentives (our measures and incentives focus people on making and executing effective decisions); (vi) priorities (people understand their priorities well enough to be able to make and execute the decisions they face); (vii) decision style (we make decisions in a style that is effective, for example, that appropriately balances inclusiveness with momentum); (viii) people (we put our best people in the jobs where they can have the biggest decision impact); (ix) behaviors (our leaders at all levels consistently demonstrate effective decision behaviors); and (x) culture (our culture reinforces prompt, effective decisions and action throughout the organization).
 
6
The term is analogous to property right, namely, the exclusive authority to determine how a resource is used. When decision-makers themselves do not feel the true cost of decisions, incremental poor even if small choices can compound into severely negative outcomes. By attributing unequivocal ownership of decision-making privileges, unambiguous responsibility can be ascribed for what decisions are made. This means that decision-makers can both reap the benefits of a good choice and pay the price of a bad one. Allowing a person's decision rights to fructify based on how well he or she exercises them makes better sense than letting privileges accumulate based on rank or seniority. The key notion is that decision rights should be earned, not granted, yet reviewed and updated routinely.
 
7
Decision cycle refers to the continual use of mental and physical processes exercised by an entity to reach and implement decisions.
 
8
Obviously, these do not all reside at the top. Offices and departments, teams too for that matter, ought to develop then winnow their own lists of critical decisions to ascertain the value at stake and the degree of attention required.
 
9
The costs associated with the first approach stem from (possibly inaccurate) transmission of data and information from the source to the decision-maker and what delays the process occasions. Those of the second approach owe to the risk that data and information are not necessarily aligned with the objectives and motivations of the individual to whom the decision rights are now given.
 
10
Those in favor of centralization usually contend it ensures uniformity in standards, promotes coherence and coordination, minimizes duplication, builds economies of scale, and reduces inequalities. Champions of decentralization think it enhances autonomy and empowerment, augments participation, and fosters creativity and innovation. It stands to reason that one should even out the two.
 
11
One might say that every decision follows from previous decisions and both enables and prevents other future decisions. Consequently, inputs will be required before, during, and after a decision.
 
Literature
go back to reference Blenko M, Mankins M, Rogers P (June 2010) The decision-driven organization. Harvard Business Review 54–62 Blenko M, Mankins M, Rogers P (June 2010) The decision-driven organization. Harvard Business Review 54–62
go back to reference Hayek F (1945) The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review 35(4):519–530 Hayek F (1945) The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review 35(4):519–530
go back to reference Mintzberg H (1989) Mintzberg on management: inside our strange world of organizations. Simon and Schuster Mintzberg H (1989) Mintzberg on management: inside our strange world of organizations. Simon and Schuster
go back to reference Rogers P, Blenko M (January 2006) Who has the D? how clear decision roles enhance organizational performance. Harvard Business Review 53–61 Rogers P, Blenko M (January 2006) Who has the D? how clear decision roles enhance organizational performance. Harvard Business Review 53–61
Metadata
Title
On Decision-Making
Author
Olivier Serrat
Copyright Year
2017
Publisher
Springer Singapore
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-0983-9_60