Skip to main content
Top
Published in: International Tax and Public Finance 4/2018

05-02-2018

Optimal income taxation and migration

Authors: Valeria De Bonis, Luca Spataro

Published in: International Tax and Public Finance | Issue 4/2018

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We tackle the issue of optimal dynamic taxation of capital income in an economy with disconnection as in Weil (J Public Econ 38:183–198, 1989), generated by migration and intra-family altruism. We show that, when the government aims at correcting such a disconnection using time-varying weights in the social welfare function, then there is room for nonzero capital income taxation, both in the short and in the long run.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
See Atkeson et al. (1999) and Chari et al. (1999).
 
2
The difference between the government and individuals’ discount rates can be explained in terms of myopia of the latter, or of political instability, where a government takes into account that it might lose office and therefore values the future less than individuals do (see Grossman and Van Huyck 1988).
 
3
By the same reasoning, the asymmetry disappears in the special case of logarithmic utility function, since the anticipated policy path does not affect current individual choices and, thus, the cumulative distortionary effect of taxes is ruled out (see also Lansing 1999 and Reinhorn 2013). For a recent discussion on nonzero taxation of capital income, see also Straub and Werning (2014).
 
4
Another extension of the basic framework aimed at obtaining a positive taxation of capital consists in the introduction of uncertainty. However, even if Zhu (1992) points out that in such a case the capital income tax may be nonzero in the long run, Chari et al. (1994) show via simulations that the average value of the optimal capital income tax is very close to zero. Other authors have explored the role of market incompleteness in stochastic environments: Chari and Kehoe (1999), for example, consider an economy with state contingent returns on debt acting as shock absorbers. They show that if the government cannot issue bonds with state contingent returns, capital income taxes can be chosen to overcome this problem. More recently, on the role of idiosyncratic uncertainty and private information in invalidating the Chamley–Judd result, see Golosov et al. (2003), Kocherlakota (2005) and Albanesi and Sleet (2006).
 
5
See Atkinson and Sandmo (1980) and Erosa and Gervais (2002).
 
6
The relevance of the “disconnectedness” of the economy has been firstly analysed by Weil (1989) in the context of the validity of the Ricardian equivalence proposition.
 
7
For a presentation of this model in continuous time, see Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1999), chapter 9.
 
8
See, for instance, Razin et al. (2002) and Occhino (2008) on fiscal incentives and the relationship between migration and welfare policies; Solé-Auró and Crimmins (2008) on the differences in consumption patterns of natives and immigrants; Czaika and Parsons (2017) for a recent contribution on the effects of international policy agreements on the characteristics of immigrants; and Bell and Eiser (2016) for the effects of the interplay of migration and fiscal policies on the performance of labour markets.
 
9
For example, Ramsey (1928) considered constant discounting unacceptable from an ethical standpoint; see, among others, Bernheim (1989), Michel (1990) and Caplin and Lehay (2004).
 
10
A notable exception is the work by Farhi and Werning (2005), who obtain a time-varying social discount rate by assuming that the government values future generations directly and not simply through the altruism of the current generation and in the absence of an OLG framework. See also Spataro and De Bonis (2008) for an analysis of the issue in the context of a perpetual youth economy.
 
11
For a general analysis of the taxation of savings and, in particular, inheritance taxes in a similar framework, see De Bonis and Spataro (2010).
 
12
To see this, consider period 0: the dynasty of the natives consists of 1 native (the founder, born in period − 1) and n children, so that \({{P}}_{-1,0} = (1 +n)\) and the dynasties of the first immigrants are formed by \({{P}}_{0,0} = \alpha (1+n)\) individuals, with \({{N}}_{0} = (1 + \alpha ) (1+n)\). In period 1, the dynasty of natives is formed by the founder, n children and \(n (1+ n)\) nephews, such that \({{P}}_{-1,1} = (1+n)^{2}\). In the same period 1, the dynasties of the first immigrants are formed by \(\alpha (1+ n)\) founders and \(\alpha (1+ n) n\) children, so that \({{P}}_{0,1} = \alpha (1 + n)^{2}\), while new immigrants have entered the economy, equal to a fraction \(\alpha \) of the previous period population and their current children, i.e. \({{P}}_{1,1} = \alpha (1 + \alpha ) (1 +n)^{2}\), so that \({{N}}_{1}= (1 + \alpha )^{2} (1+ n)^{2}\). Generalizing, we end up with the above expressions for \({{P}}_{\mathrm{s,t}.}\) and \({{N}}_{\mathrm{t}}\).
 
13
See Stiglitz (2015) for a review.
 
14
See Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980); the alternative “dual” approach takes prices and tax rates as control variables (see, for instance, Chamley 1986).
 
15
As for the first dynasty, the implementability constraint takes the form: \(\sum \limits _{t=s}^\infty {({\frac{1+n}{1+\beta }})}^{t-s} ({U_{c_{s,t}} c_{s,t} + U_{l_{s,t}} l_{s,t}}) = U_{c_{0,0}} (1+\tilde{r}_{0,0}) {\bar{k}}_{-1}.\)
 
16
In our model, thus, the reference point in the government maximization problem is the utility of the dynasties. The dynastic dimension of income has been recently put forward in the context of the distributional effects of taxation (Piketty 2014; Atkinson 2015; Kanbur and Stiglitz 2015; Halvorsen and Thoresen 2017). Even if our framework is very simple, since dynasties only differ as for their date of entry into the economy and we adopt an utilitarian welfare function, we contribute to this literature by adding efficiency aspects to the analysis of the taxation of dynastic income.
 
17
We omit the government budget constraint since, by Walras’ law, it is satisfied if the implementability and feasibility constraints hold.
 
18
From now onward, we omit the s and t indicators, whenever this does not cause ambiguity: hence, notation \({{X}}^{+1}\) stands for \({{X}}_{{s}, {t}+1}\).
 
19
This case occurs, for instance, when the utility function is of the form: \(U=\frac{c^{1-\frac{1}{\sigma }}}{1-\frac{1}{\sigma }} +V(l)\), where \(H_c =-\frac{1}{\sigma }\).
 
20
Generally speaking, differences in weight can be connected to different characteristics of natives and immigrants, and of different generations of immigrants; this would be of relevance for the choice of taxation instruments other than capital income taxation.
 
Literature
go back to reference Albanesi, S., & Sleet, C. (2006). Dynamic optimal taxation with private information. Review of Economic Studies, 73, 1–30.CrossRef Albanesi, S., & Sleet, C. (2006). Dynamic optimal taxation with private information. Review of Economic Studies, 73, 1–30.CrossRef
go back to reference Atkeson, A., Chari, V. V., & Kehoe, P. J. (1999). Taxing capital income: A bad idea. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 23, 3–17. Atkeson, A., Chari, V. V., & Kehoe, P. J. (1999). Taxing capital income: A bad idea. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 23, 3–17.
go back to reference Atkinson, A. B. (2015). Inequality: What can be done. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRef Atkinson, A. B. (2015). Inequality: What can be done. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Atkinson, A. B., & Sandmo, A. (1980). Welfare implications of the taxation of savings. The Economic Journal, 90, 529–549.CrossRef Atkinson, A. B., & Sandmo, A. (1980). Welfare implications of the taxation of savings. The Economic Journal, 90, 529–549.CrossRef
go back to reference Atkinson, A. B., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1980). Lectures on public economics. London: McGraw-Hill. Atkinson, A. B., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1980). Lectures on public economics. London: McGraw-Hill.
go back to reference Barro, R. J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1999). Economic growth. Cambridge: The MIT Press. Barro, R. J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1999). Economic growth. Cambridge: The MIT Press.
go back to reference Bell, N. F., & Eiser, D. (2016). Migration and fiscal policy as factors explaining the labour-market resilience of UK regions to the great recession. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 9(1), 197–215.CrossRef Bell, N. F., & Eiser, D. (2016). Migration and fiscal policy as factors explaining the labour-market resilience of UK regions to the great recession. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 9(1), 197–215.CrossRef
go back to reference Bernheim, B. D. (1989). Intergenerational altruism, dynastic equilibria and social welfare. Review of Economic Studies, 56, 119–128.CrossRef Bernheim, B. D. (1989). Intergenerational altruism, dynastic equilibria and social welfare. Review of Economic Studies, 56, 119–128.CrossRef
go back to reference Caplin, A., & Lehay, J. (2004). The social discount rate. Journal of Political Economy, 112, 1257–1268.CrossRef Caplin, A., & Lehay, J. (2004). The social discount rate. Journal of Political Economy, 112, 1257–1268.CrossRef
go back to reference Chamley, C. (1986). Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica, 54, 607–622.CrossRef Chamley, C. (1986). Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica, 54, 607–622.CrossRef
go back to reference Chari, V. V., Christiano, L. J., & Kehoe, P. J. (1994). Optimal fiscal policy in a business cycle model. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 617–652.CrossRef Chari, V. V., Christiano, L. J., & Kehoe, P. J. (1994). Optimal fiscal policy in a business cycle model. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 617–652.CrossRef
go back to reference Chari, V. V., & Kehoe, P. J. (1999). Optimal fiscal and monetary policy. In J. B. Taylor & M. Woodford (Eds.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Vol. 1, pp. 1670–1745). Amsterdam: North-Holland. Chari, V. V., & Kehoe, P. J. (1999). Optimal fiscal and monetary policy. In J. B. Taylor & M. Woodford (Eds.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Vol. 1, pp. 1670–1745). Amsterdam: North-Holland.
go back to reference Czaika, M., & Parsons, C. R. (2017). The gravity of high-skilled migration policies. Demography, 54(2), 603–630.CrossRef Czaika, M., & Parsons, C. R. (2017). The gravity of high-skilled migration policies. Demography, 54(2), 603–630.CrossRef
go back to reference De Bonis, V., & Spataro, L. (2005). Taxing capital income as pigouvian correction: The role of discounting the future. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 9, 469–477.CrossRef De Bonis, V., & Spataro, L. (2005). Taxing capital income as pigouvian correction: The role of discounting the future. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 9, 469–477.CrossRef
go back to reference De Bonis, V., & Spataro, L. (2010). Social discounting, migration and optimal taxation of savings. Oxford Economic Papers, 62, 603–623.CrossRef De Bonis, V., & Spataro, L. (2010). Social discounting, migration and optimal taxation of savings. Oxford Economic Papers, 62, 603–623.CrossRef
go back to reference de la Croix, D., & Michel, P. (2002). A theory of economic growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef de la Croix, D., & Michel, P. (2002). A theory of economic growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Erosa, A., & Gervais, M. (2002). Optimal taxation in life-cycle economies. Journal of Economic Theory, 105, 338–369.CrossRef Erosa, A., & Gervais, M. (2002). Optimal taxation in life-cycle economies. Journal of Economic Theory, 105, 338–369.CrossRef
go back to reference Farhi, E., & Werning, I. (2005). Inequality, social discounting and estate taxation. NBER Working Paper 1148. Farhi, E., & Werning, I. (2005). Inequality, social discounting and estate taxation. NBER Working Paper 1148.
go back to reference Garriga, C. (2003). Optimal fiscal policy in overlapping generations models. New York: Mimeo. Garriga, C. (2003). Optimal fiscal policy in overlapping generations models. New York: Mimeo.
go back to reference Golosov, M., Kocherlakota, N., & Tsyvinski, A. (2003). Optimal indirect and capital taxation. Review of Economic Studies, 70, 569–587.CrossRef Golosov, M., Kocherlakota, N., & Tsyvinski, A. (2003). Optimal indirect and capital taxation. Review of Economic Studies, 70, 569–587.CrossRef
go back to reference Grossman, H. I., & Van Huyck, J. B. (1988). Sovereign debt as a contingent claim: Excusable default, repudiation, and reputation. American Economic Review, 78(5), 1088. Grossman, H. I., & Van Huyck, J. B. (1988). Sovereign debt as a contingent claim: Excusable default, repudiation, and reputation. American Economic Review, 78(5), 1088.
go back to reference Halvorsen, E., & Thoresen, T. O. (2017). Distributional effects of the wealth tax under a lifetime-dynastic income concept. CESifo Working Paper 6614. Halvorsen, E., & Thoresen, T. O. (2017). Distributional effects of the wealth tax under a lifetime-dynastic income concept. CESifo Working Paper 6614.
go back to reference Judd, K. L. (1985). Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics, 28, 59–83.CrossRef Judd, K. L. (1985). Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics, 28, 59–83.CrossRef
go back to reference Judd, K. L. (1999). Optimal taxation and spending in general competitive growth models. Journal of Public Economics, 71, 1–26.CrossRef Judd, K. L. (1999). Optimal taxation and spending in general competitive growth models. Journal of Public Economics, 71, 1–26.CrossRef
go back to reference Kanbur, R., & Stiglitz, J. E. (2015). Dynastic inequality, mobility and equality of opportunity. Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper 10542. Kanbur, R., & Stiglitz, J. E. (2015). Dynastic inequality, mobility and equality of opportunity. Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper 10542.
go back to reference Kocherlakota, N. (2005). Zero expected wealth taxes: A mirrlees approach to dynamic optimal taxation. Econometrica, 73, 1587–1621.CrossRef Kocherlakota, N. (2005). Zero expected wealth taxes: A mirrlees approach to dynamic optimal taxation. Econometrica, 73, 1587–1621.CrossRef
go back to reference Lansing, K. (1999). Optimal redistributive capital taxation in a neoclassical growth model. Journal of Public Economics, 73(3), 423–453.CrossRef Lansing, K. (1999). Optimal redistributive capital taxation in a neoclassical growth model. Journal of Public Economics, 73(3), 423–453.CrossRef
go back to reference Michel, P. (1990). Criticism of the social time-preference hypothesis in optimal growth. Catholique de Louvain—Center for Operations Research and Economics Paper 9039. Michel, P. (1990). Criticism of the social time-preference hypothesis in optimal growth. Catholique de Louvain—Center for Operations Research and Economics Paper 9039.
go back to reference Occhino, F. (2008). Optimal fiscal policy when migration is feasible. B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 8, 1682–1935.CrossRef Occhino, F. (2008). Optimal fiscal policy when migration is feasible. B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 8, 1682–1935.CrossRef
go back to reference Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRef Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Ramsey, F. P. (1927). A contribution to the theory of taxation. Economic Journal, 37, 47–61.CrossRef Ramsey, F. P. (1927). A contribution to the theory of taxation. Economic Journal, 37, 47–61.CrossRef
go back to reference Ramsey, F. P. (1928). A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal, 38, 543–559.CrossRef Ramsey, F. P. (1928). A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal, 38, 543–559.CrossRef
go back to reference Razin, A., Sadka, E., & Swagel, P. (2002). Tax burden and migration: A political economy theory and evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 85, 167–190.CrossRef Razin, A., Sadka, E., & Swagel, P. (2002). Tax burden and migration: A political economy theory and evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 85, 167–190.CrossRef
go back to reference Reinhorn, L. J. (2013). On optimal redistributive capital taxation. New York: mimeo. Reinhorn, L. J. (2013). On optimal redistributive capital taxation. New York: mimeo.
go back to reference Reis, C. (2012). Social discounting and incentive compatible fiscal policy. Journal of Economic Theory, 147, 2469–2482.CrossRef Reis, C. (2012). Social discounting and incentive compatible fiscal policy. Journal of Economic Theory, 147, 2469–2482.CrossRef
go back to reference Solé-Auró, A., & Crimmins, E. M. (2008). Health of immigrants in European countries. International Migration Review, 42(4), 861–876.CrossRef Solé-Auró, A., & Crimmins, E. M. (2008). Health of immigrants in European countries. International Migration Review, 42(4), 861–876.CrossRef
go back to reference Spataro, L., & De Bonis, V. (2008). Accounting for the “disconnectedness” of the economy in OLG models: A case for taxing capital income. Economic Modelling, 25, 411–421.CrossRef Spataro, L., & De Bonis, V. (2008). Accounting for the “disconnectedness” of the economy in OLG models: A case for taxing capital income. Economic Modelling, 25, 411–421.CrossRef
go back to reference Stiglitz, J. E. (2015). In praise of Frank Ramsey’s contribution to the theory of taxation. Economic Journal, 125(583), 235–268.CrossRef Stiglitz, J. E. (2015). In praise of Frank Ramsey’s contribution to the theory of taxation. Economic Journal, 125(583), 235–268.CrossRef
go back to reference Straub, L., & Werning, I. (2014). Positive long run capital taxation: Chamley–Judd revisited. (No. w20441). National Bureau of Economic Research. Straub, L., & Werning, I. (2014). Positive long run capital taxation: Chamley–Judd revisited. (No. w20441). National Bureau of Economic Research.
go back to reference Weil, P. (1989). Overlapping families of infinitely lived agents. Journal of Public Economics, 38, 183–198.CrossRef Weil, P. (1989). Overlapping families of infinitely lived agents. Journal of Public Economics, 38, 183–198.CrossRef
go back to reference Zhu, X. (1992). Optimal fiscal policy in a stochastic growth model. Journal of Economic Theory, 58, 250–289.CrossRef Zhu, X. (1992). Optimal fiscal policy in a stochastic growth model. Journal of Economic Theory, 58, 250–289.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Optimal income taxation and migration
Authors
Valeria De Bonis
Luca Spataro
Publication date
05-02-2018
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
International Tax and Public Finance / Issue 4/2018
Print ISSN: 0927-5940
Electronic ISSN: 1573-6970
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-018-9483-6

Other articles of this Issue 4/2018

International Tax and Public Finance 4/2018 Go to the issue