Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Journal of Business Ethics 2/2016

09-05-2015

Political Connectedness, Corporate Governance, and Firm Performance

Authors: Polona Domadenik, Janez Prašnikar, Jan Svejnar

Published in: Journal of Business Ethics | Issue 2/2016

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In this paper, we present and test a theory of how political connectedness (often linked to political corruption) affects corporate governance and productive efficiency of firms. Our model predicts that underdeveloped democratic institutions that do not punish political corruption result in political connectedness of firms that in turn has a negative effect on performance. We test this prediction on an almost complete population of Slovenian joint-stock companies with 100 or more employees. Using the data on supervisory board structure, together with balance sheet and income statement data for 2000–2010, we show that a higher share of politically connected supervisory board members leads to lower productivity.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
The term “environment” refers to the nature of monitoring and punishments, as well as to economic decisions in which the bureaucrats participate (Banerjee et al. 2012).
 
2
The quality of institutions in this paper resembles an approach of Bhattacharyya and Hodler (2010) that compares probability p of electing new politicians in the next period with probability q of not being able to replace the incumbent elite with the new elite if people do not support the incumbents anymore. As we discuss below, a small difference between p and q signals underdeveloped democratic institutions as people’s vote has little impact on the probability that the new elite will come to office, while a large difference implies that the incumbents are likely to stay in office only if the people want them to stay.
 
3
Faccio (2006) assembled a database of 20,202 publicly traded firms in 47 countries. She identified a firm to be politically connected if at least one of its large shareholders (controlling more than 10 percent of voting shares) or one of its top officers (CEO, president or vice-president) was a member of parliament, a minister, or a person closely related to a top politician or political party. Slightly less than 3 percent of firms in the total sample were identified as being politically connected. However, there is a high cross country variation. In Russia, for example, 86.75 percent of the market capitalization was represented by politically connected firms.
 
4
More generally, with the fall of the communist regime, Central European transition countries moved virtually overnight into the ranks of the most open economies in the world, thus defying the widely accepted infant industry thesis that firms in emerging market economies require a long period of protection before being able to face world competition.
 
5
The most recent findings by the Slovenian anti-corruption agency, based on a case-by-case investigation, point to systemic corruption risks mostly related to the privileged position of SOEs in the Slovenian economy, particularly when it comes to access to finance and investment opportunities. The European Commission warns that the distortion of market principles and rent-seeking practices threaten to block the privatization process (European Commission 2014).
 
6
We describe the privatization process in more detail in Chapter 4.
 
7
The previous (Yugoslav) economic system of self-management was based on social ownership. The firms belonged to society as a whole, but were managed by workers of self-managed enterprises on the principle of one person one voice. See Prašnikar and Svejnar (1993) for details.
 
8
In this context, they treat legal corruption as arising when the elite prefers to hide corruption from the population and the costs of hiding are a so-called investment in “legal barriers.” Investment in legal barriers and “insurrections” crucially depends on accountability and initial inequality among the population. It can be proven that, in the case of low initial inequality, legal corruption arises in the case of low accountability. In this case, the legal barriers arise in every period as well. On the other hand, in the same case of low initial inequality but high accountability (for example, like in Scandinavian countries), legal corruption and legal barriers do not arise and the economy stays in this equilibrium.
 
9
Gill and Kharas (2007) and Lee and Oh (2007), for example, look at the arbitrariness of corruption in East Asia and note that Indonesia and the Philippines were particularly affected by political corruption that occurred during and after the lengthy dictatorships.
 
10
Collins (1998) reports that some forms of corruptive practices can already be found in 3000 B.C. What has changed during history is the form of corruptive practices. However, the historical perspective shows that the ethical reform of corruption is important as some of the action solutions taken against corruption have been as problematic as corruption from the ethical perspective (Nielsen 2003).
 
11
For the sake of simplicity, we also exclude the concept of corruptive income based on natural resources. Resource income largely depends on a country's resource abundance and our model is designed for a country that is not rich in natural resources.
 
12
As noted by Bhattacharyya and Hodler (2010), there are different motives for why the incumbent elite also cares about the people’s welfare and the performance of the economy. First, the economic conditions in general determine the salary of the incumbent elite, and second, the status and influence of the elite in the international community depends on the welfare of citizens.
 
13
In fact, a third model of privatization was also proposed by Ribnikar and Prašnikar that favors the idea of converting all assets of socially owned firms into preferential shares of retirement funds. New owners were to invest funds in firms and acquire governance power. All three models are described in details in Prašnikar and Svejnar (1993).
 
14
In 2002, Sandoz took over Lek, a pharmaceutical company that was one of the largest firms in Slovenia. Although this takeover worked well for the company, speculations that the existing management team reaped substantial rewards by trading on the basis of internal information have never been dispelled. The prevalent position taken by politicians was not to privatize the most successful Slovenian companies to foreigners, if not necessary.
 
15
The Law did not apply to enterprises providing special public services, banks and insurance companies, enterprises engaged in the organization of gambling, enterprises that were transformed under the Law on Cooperatives, enterprises that were transformed under the forestry legislation, and firms in the process of bankruptcy.
 
16
As reported by the study of Domadenik et al. (2008) that analyzed the ownership structure in 157 big and medium-sized Slovenian firms, slightly more than one-half of those firms were privatized primarily to insiders. The average share ownership was 31 percent by insiders, 34 percent by state and investment funds, 21 percent by other firms, and 13 percent by other owners (banks and direct state ownership).
 
17
This is Abramovitz's famous “measure of our ignorance.”
 
18
Intangible resources in countries with underdeveloped capital and financial markets crucially depend on the ability of firms to generate internal funds. This is especially the case in Slovenia, as shown by Domadenik et al. (2008).
 
19
The correlation between an individual’s wage and productivity is high even when the markets are not perfectly competitive.
 
20
If gender discrimination exists, firm performance would be better off in cases of a more balanced recruitment policy for managers and supervisory board members. Empirical evidence is mixed, ranging from positive effects of diversity management (Carter et al. 2003; Singh and Vinnicombe 2004; Smith et al. 2006) to no effect at all (Kochan et al. 2003).
 
21
Companies were not required to report names of their supervisory board members before 2007, however, and we were hence only able to gather complete information about supervisory board members in 308 firms; 155 of them operated in the tradable sector and 153 in the non-tradable sector. It is important to note at this point that of the 308 companies which had a supervisory board and were used in the analysis, 292 had their own supervisory board. The remaining 16 companies did not have their own supervisory board but were owned and controlled by a parent company with a supervisory board. Thus, for these 16 companies supervisory board data from the parent company were used as a proxy to determine how important business decisions were made. We assumed that political influence from the parent company was also present in the decision-making of the subsidiary company.
 
22
In particular, we carefully checked if any supervisory board members had a political affiliation defined as being a candidate for a local and/or state-level elected position, a member of a political party or continuously expressing public support for a given political party.
 
23
From the AJPES registry, we were able to obtain balance sheet and income statement data for most of the companies, except companies facing compulsory settlement, companies in bankruptcy procedure, and those companies that had undergone a significant organizational change that prevented us from making a consistent panel of financial data.
 
24
Also see Bole et al. (2010) for details.
 
25
OLS estimates may be obtained from the authors upon request.
 
26
The coefficient is statistically significant at the 10 percent level.
 
27
Gupta et al. (2008), for example, show on a panel of Czech data that better performing firms were privatized first and that ignoring this selection leads to a biased estimation of the effects of privatization in existing studies.
 
Literature
go back to reference Acemoglu, D. (2009). When Does Labor Scarcity Encourage Innovation? NBER Working Papers 14809, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. Acemoglu, D. (2009). When Does Labor Scarcity Encourage Innovation? NBER Working Papers 14809, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
go back to reference Agrawal, A., & Knoeber, C. R. (2001). Do some outside directors play a political role? Journal of Law and Economics, 44(1), 179–198.CrossRef Agrawal, A., & Knoeber, C. R. (2001). Do some outside directors play a political role? Journal of Law and Economics, 44(1), 179–198.CrossRef
go back to reference Arellano, M., & Bond, S. R. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277–297.CrossRef Arellano, M., & Bond, S. R. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277–297.CrossRef
go back to reference Banerjee, A. Hanna, R. & Mullainathan, S. (2012). Corruption. MIT Working Paper Series, WP No. 12–08. Banerjee, A. Hanna, R. & Mullainathan, S. (2012). Corruption. MIT Working Paper Series, WP No. 12–08.
go back to reference Banfield, E. (1998). The moral basis of a backward society. Chicago, IL: The Free Press. Banfield, E. (1998). The moral basis of a backward society. Chicago, IL: The Free Press.
go back to reference Bhattacharyya, S., & Hodler, R. (2010). Natural resources, democracy and corruption. European Economic Review, 54, 608–621.CrossRef Bhattacharyya, S., & Hodler, R. (2010). Natural resources, democracy and corruption. European Economic Review, 54, 608–621.CrossRef
go back to reference Blundell, R. W., & Bond, S. R. (2000). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143.CrossRef Blundell, R. W., & Bond, S. R. (2000). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143.CrossRef
go back to reference Bole, V., Prašnikar, J., & Trobec, D. (2010). Accumulated financial debt of firms as an obstacle to firms’ investments. In J. Prašnikar (Ed.), The role of intangible assets in exiting the crisis (pp. 117–130). Ljubljana: Finance. Bole, V., Prašnikar, J., & Trobec, D. (2010). Accumulated financial debt of firms as an obstacle to firms’ investments. In J. Prašnikar (Ed.), The role of intangible assets in exiting the crisis (pp. 117–130). Ljubljana: Finance.
go back to reference Bole, V., Prašnikar, J., & Trobec, D. (2014). Policy measures in the deleveraging process: A macroprudential evaluation. Journal of Policy Modelling, 36(2), 410–432.CrossRef Bole, V., Prašnikar, J., & Trobec, D. (2014). Policy measures in the deleveraging process: A macroprudential evaluation. Journal of Policy Modelling, 36(2), 410–432.CrossRef
go back to reference Carter, D. A., Simkins, B. J., & Simpson, W. G. (2003). Corporate governance, board diversity, and firm value. The Financial Review, 38, 33–53.CrossRef Carter, D. A., Simkins, B. J., & Simpson, W. G. (2003). Corporate governance, board diversity, and firm value. The Financial Review, 38, 33–53.CrossRef
go back to reference Collins, R. (1998). The sociology of philosophies: A global theory of intellectual change. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. Collins, R. (1998). The sociology of philosophies: A global theory of intellectual change. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
go back to reference Corrado, C., Hulten, C., & Sichel, D. (2005). Measuring capital and technology: An expanded framework. In C. Corrado, et al. (Eds.), Measuring capital in the new economy, National Bureau of Economic Research Studies in Income and Wealth (Vol. 65, pp. 11–45). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRef Corrado, C., Hulten, C., & Sichel, D. (2005). Measuring capital and technology: An expanded framework. In C. Corrado, et al. (Eds.), Measuring capital in the new economy, National Bureau of Economic Research Studies in Income and Wealth (Vol. 65, pp. 11–45). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRef
go back to reference De Soto, H. (1989). The other path: The invisible revolution in the Third Worlds. New York: Harper and Row Publishers. De Soto, H. (1989). The other path: The invisible revolution in the Third Worlds. New York: Harper and Row Publishers.
go back to reference Dela Rama, M. (2012). Corporate governance and corruption: Ethical dilemmas of Asian business groups. Journal of Business Ethics, 109, 501–519.CrossRef Dela Rama, M. (2012). Corporate governance and corruption: Ethical dilemmas of Asian business groups. Journal of Business Ethics, 109, 501–519.CrossRef
go back to reference Desai, R. M., & Olofsgård, A. (2011). The costs of political influence: Firm-level evidence from developing countries. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 6(2), 137–178.CrossRef Desai, R. M., & Olofsgård, A. (2011). The costs of political influence: Firm-level evidence from developing countries. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 6(2), 137–178.CrossRef
go back to reference Domadenik, P., Prašnikar, J., & Svejnar, J. (2008). Restructuring of firms in transition: Ownership, institutions and openness to trade. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(4), 725–746.CrossRef Domadenik, P., Prašnikar, J., & Svejnar, J. (2008). Restructuring of firms in transition: Ownership, institutions and openness to trade. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(4), 725–746.CrossRef
go back to reference Dombrovsky, V. (2008). Do Political Connections Matter? Firm-level Evidence from Latvia. SSE-Riga/BICEPS Working Paper. Dombrovsky, V. (2008). Do Political Connections Matter? Firm-level Evidence from Latvia. SSE-Riga/BICEPS Working Paper.
go back to reference European Commission. (2014). Macroeconomic Imbalances, Slovenia 2014. Occasional Papers 187. Brussels: European Commission, Directorate-General of Economic and Financial Affairs European Commission. (2014). Macroeconomic Imbalances, Slovenia 2014. Occasional Papers 187. Brussels: European Commission, Directorate-General of Economic and Financial Affairs
go back to reference Faccio, M. (2006). Politically connected firms. American Economic Review, 96, 369–386.CrossRef Faccio, M. (2006). Politically connected firms. American Economic Review, 96, 369–386.CrossRef
go back to reference Fazzari, S., Hubbard, G., & Peterson, B. (1996). Investment and finance reconsidered (pp. 141–195). Washington, DC: Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. Fazzari, S., Hubbard, G., & Peterson, B. (1996). Investment and finance reconsidered (pp. 141–195). Washington, DC: Brookings Papers on Economic Activity.
go back to reference Filippini, M., Hrovatin, N., & Zorić, J. (2014). Efficiency and regulation of the Slovenian electricity distribution companies. Energy Policy, 32(3), 335–344.CrossRef Filippini, M., Hrovatin, N., & Zorić, J. (2014). Efficiency and regulation of the Slovenian electricity distribution companies. Energy Policy, 32(3), 335–344.CrossRef
go back to reference Fisman, R. (2001). Estimating the value of political connections. American Economic Review, 4, 1095–1102.CrossRef Fisman, R. (2001). Estimating the value of political connections. American Economic Review, 4, 1095–1102.CrossRef
go back to reference Fox, J. T., & Smeets, V. (2011). Does Input Quality Drive Measured Differences in Firm Productivity? NBER Working Paper No. 16853. Fox, J. T., & Smeets, V. (2011). Does Input Quality Drive Measured Differences in Firm Productivity? NBER Working Paper No. 16853.
go back to reference Gill, I., & Kharas, H. (2007). An East Asian renaissance: Ideas for economic growth. Washington, DC: World Bank Group.CrossRef Gill, I., & Kharas, H. (2007). An East Asian renaissance: Ideas for economic growth. Washington, DC: World Bank Group.CrossRef
go back to reference Griliches, Z., & Mairesse, J. (1998). Production functions: The search for identification. In S. Strom (Ed.), Essays in Honour of Ragnar Frisch. Econometric Society Monograph Series. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Griliches, Z., & Mairesse, J. (1998). Production functions: The search for identification. In S. Strom (Ed.), Essays in Honour of Ragnar Frisch. Econometric Society Monograph Series. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Gupta, S., Davoodi, H. R., & Alonso-Terme, R. M. (2002). Does corruption affect income inequality and poverty? Economics and Governance, 3, 23–45.CrossRef Gupta, S., Davoodi, H. R., & Alonso-Terme, R. M. (2002). Does corruption affect income inequality and poverty? Economics and Governance, 3, 23–45.CrossRef
go back to reference Gupta, N., Ham, J. C., & Svejnar, J. (2008). Priorities and sequencing in privatization: Evidence from Czech firm panel data. European Economic Review, 52(2), 183–208.CrossRef Gupta, N., Ham, J. C., & Svejnar, J. (2008). Priorities and sequencing in privatization: Evidence from Czech firm panel data. European Economic Review, 52(2), 183–208.CrossRef
go back to reference Hausman, J. (1978). Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica, 46, 1251–1271.CrossRef Hausman, J. (1978). Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica, 46, 1251–1271.CrossRef
go back to reference Hermalin, B. E., & Weisbach, M. S. (2003). Boards of directors and endogenously determined institution: A survey of the economic literature. Economic Policy Review, 9(1), 7–26. Hermalin, B. E., & Weisbach, M. S. (2003). Boards of directors and endogenously determined institution: A survey of the economic literature. Economic Policy Review, 9(1), 7–26.
go back to reference Joecks, J., Pull, K., & Vetter, K. (2013). Gender diversity in the boardroom and firm performance: What exactly constitutes a “critical mass”? Journal of Business Ethics, 118(1), 61–72.CrossRef Joecks, J., Pull, K., & Vetter, K. (2013). Gender diversity in the boardroom and firm performance: What exactly constitutes a “critical mass”? Journal of Business Ethics, 118(1), 61–72.CrossRef
go back to reference Johnson, S., & Mitton, T. (2003). Cronyism and capital controls: Evidence from Malaysia. Journal of Financial Economics, 67, 351–382.CrossRef Johnson, S., & Mitton, T. (2003). Cronyism and capital controls: Evidence from Malaysia. Journal of Financial Economics, 67, 351–382.CrossRef
go back to reference Jones, C. I. (1998). Introduction to economic growth. New York: W.W. Norton & Co. Inc. Jones, C. I. (1998). Introduction to economic growth. New York: W.W. Norton & Co. Inc.
go back to reference Kang, D. C. (2003). Transaction costs and crony capitalism in East Asia. Comparative Politics, 35, 439–458.CrossRef Kang, D. C. (2003). Transaction costs and crony capitalism in East Asia. Comparative Politics, 35, 439–458.CrossRef
go back to reference Kaufmann, D., & Vincente, P. C. (2011). Legal corruption. Economics and Politics, 23(2), 195–219.CrossRef Kaufmann, D., & Vincente, P. C. (2011). Legal corruption. Economics and Politics, 23(2), 195–219.CrossRef
go back to reference Khwaja, A. I., & Mian, A. (2005). Do lenders prefer politically connected firms? Rent seeking in an emerging financial market. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 1371–1411.CrossRef Khwaja, A. I., & Mian, A. (2005). Do lenders prefer politically connected firms? Rent seeking in an emerging financial market. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 1371–1411.CrossRef
go back to reference Knyazeva, A., Knyazeva, D., & Stiglitz, J. E. (2013). Ownership change, institutional development and performance. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(7), 2605–2627.CrossRef Knyazeva, A., Knyazeva, D., & Stiglitz, J. E. (2013). Ownership change, institutional development and performance. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(7), 2605–2627.CrossRef
go back to reference Kochan, T., Bezrukova, K., Ely, R., Jackson, S., Joshi, A., Jehn, K., et al. (2003). The effects of diversity on business performance: report of the diversity network. Human Resource Management, 42(1), 3–21.CrossRef Kochan, T., Bezrukova, K., Ely, R., Jackson, S., Joshi, A., Jehn, K., et al. (2003). The effects of diversity on business performance: report of the diversity network. Human Resource Management, 42(1), 3–21.CrossRef
go back to reference Kroszner, R. S., & Stratmann, T. (1998). Interest-group competition and the organization of congress: Theory and evidence from financial services’ political action committees. American Economic Review, 88(5), 1163–1187. Kroszner, R. S., & Stratmann, T. (1998). Interest-group competition and the organization of congress: Theory and evidence from financial services’ political action committees. American Economic Review, 88(5), 1163–1187.
go back to reference Krueger, A. O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review, 64(3), 291–304. Krueger, A. O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review, 64(3), 291–304.
go back to reference Lee, S. H., & Oh, K. K. (2007). Corruption in Asia: Pervasiveness and arbitrariness. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 24, 97–114.CrossRef Lee, S. H., & Oh, K. K. (2007). Corruption in Asia: Pervasiveness and arbitrariness. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 24, 97–114.CrossRef
go back to reference Levinsohn, J., & Petrin, A. (2003). Estimating production function using inputs to control for unobservables. Review of Economic Studies, 70, 317–341.CrossRef Levinsohn, J., & Petrin, A. (2003). Estimating production function using inputs to control for unobservables. Review of Economic Studies, 70, 317–341.CrossRef
go back to reference Nielsen, R. P. (2003). Corruption networks and implications for ethical corruption reform. Journal of Business Ethics, 42, 125–149.CrossRef Nielsen, R. P. (2003). Corruption networks and implications for ethical corruption reform. Journal of Business Ethics, 42, 125–149.CrossRef
go back to reference Nwabuzor, A. (2005). Corruption and development: New initiatives in economic openness and strengthened rule of law. Journal of Business Ethics, 59(1–2), 121–138.CrossRef Nwabuzor, A. (2005). Corruption and development: New initiatives in economic openness and strengthened rule of law. Journal of Business Ethics, 59(1–2), 121–138.CrossRef
go back to reference Olley, S., & Pakes, A. (1996). The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunications equipment industry. Econometrica, 64, 1263–1298.CrossRef Olley, S., & Pakes, A. (1996). The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunications equipment industry. Econometrica, 64, 1263–1298.CrossRef
go back to reference Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. New Haven: Yale University Press. Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.
go back to reference Prašnikar, J., & Gregorič, A. (2002). The influence of workers’ participation on the power of management in transitional countries. The case of Slovenia. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 73(2), 269–297.CrossRef Prašnikar, J., & Gregorič, A. (2002). The influence of workers’ participation on the power of management in transitional countries. The case of Slovenia. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 73(2), 269–297.CrossRef
go back to reference Prašnikar, J., & Svejnar, J. (1993). Workers participation in management vs. social ownership and government policies: Yugoslav lessons for transforming socialist economies. In A. Atkinson (Ed.), Alternatives to Capitalism (pp. 106–126). New York: St. Martin’s Press. Prašnikar, J., & Svejnar, J. (1993). Workers participation in management vs. social ownership and government policies: Yugoslav lessons for transforming socialist economies. In A. Atkinson (Ed.), Alternatives to Capitalism (pp. 106–126). New York: St. Martin’s Press.
go back to reference Prašnikar, J., Svejnar, J., Mihajlek, D., & Prašnikar, V. (1994). A test of enterprise behaviour under Yugoslav labor management. Review of Economics and Statistics, 4, 728–741.CrossRef Prašnikar, J., Svejnar, J., Mihajlek, D., & Prašnikar, V. (1994). A test of enterprise behaviour under Yugoslav labor management. Review of Economics and Statistics, 4, 728–741.CrossRef
go back to reference Rose-Ackerman, S. (2008). Corruption and government. International Peacekeeping, 5(3), 328–343.CrossRef Rose-Ackerman, S. (2008). Corruption and government. International Peacekeeping, 5(3), 328–343.CrossRef
go back to reference Sabirianova, K., Svejnar, J., & Terrell, K. (2012). Foreign investment, corporate ownership, and development: Are firms in emerging markets catching up to the world standard? Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(4), 981–999.CrossRef Sabirianova, K., Svejnar, J., & Terrell, K. (2012). Foreign investment, corporate ownership, and development: Are firms in emerging markets catching up to the world standard? Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(4), 981–999.CrossRef
go back to reference Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1994). Politicians and firms. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(4), 995–1025.CrossRef Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1994). Politicians and firms. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(4), 995–1025.CrossRef
go back to reference Singh, V., & Vinnicombe, S. (2004). Why so few women directors in top UK boardrooms? Evidence and Theoretical Explanations, Corporate Governance—An International. Review, 12(4), 479–488. Singh, V., & Vinnicombe, S. (2004). Why so few women directors in top UK boardrooms? Evidence and Theoretical Explanations, Corporate GovernanceAn International. Review, 12(4), 479–488.
go back to reference Smith, N., Smith, V., & Verner, M. (2006). Do women in top management affect firm performance? A panel study of 2500 Danish Firms. International Journal of Productivity and Performance Management, 55(7), 569–593.CrossRef Smith, N., Smith, V., & Verner, M. (2006). Do women in top management affect firm performance? A panel study of 2500 Danish Firms. International Journal of Productivity and Performance Management, 55(7), 569–593.CrossRef
go back to reference Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management, 2(1), 3–21.CrossRef Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management, 2(1), 3–21.CrossRef
go back to reference Todaro, M. P., & Smith, S. C. (2014). Economic development (12th ed.). New York, NY: Addison Wesley. Todaro, M. P., & Smith, S. C. (2014). Economic development (12th ed.). New York, NY: Addison Wesley.
go back to reference Transparency International. (1997). The corruption perception index. Berlin: Transparency International. Transparency International. (1997). The corruption perception index. Berlin: Transparency International.
go back to reference Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies and theft. Economic Inquiry, 5(3), 224–232.CrossRef Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies and theft. Economic Inquiry, 5(3), 224–232.CrossRef
go back to reference Vynoslavaska, O., McKinney, J. A., Moore, C. W., & Longenecker, J. G. (2005). Transition ethics: A comparison of Ukrainian and United States business professionals. Journal of Business Ethics, 61(3), 283–299.CrossRef Vynoslavaska, O., McKinney, J. A., Moore, C. W., & Longenecker, J. G. (2005). Transition ethics: A comparison of Ukrainian and United States business professionals. Journal of Business Ethics, 61(3), 283–299.CrossRef
go back to reference Wooldridge, J. M. (2009). On estimating firm-level production functions using proxy variables to control for unobservables. Economics Letters, 104(3), 112–114.CrossRef Wooldridge, J. M. (2009). On estimating firm-level production functions using proxy variables to control for unobservables. Economics Letters, 104(3), 112–114.CrossRef
go back to reference Xin, X., & Rudel, T. K. (2004). The context of political corruption: A cross-national analysis. Social Science Quarterly, 85(2), 294–309.CrossRef Xin, X., & Rudel, T. K. (2004). The context of political corruption: A cross-national analysis. Social Science Quarterly, 85(2), 294–309.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Political Connectedness, Corporate Governance, and Firm Performance
Authors
Polona Domadenik
Janez Prašnikar
Jan Svejnar
Publication date
09-05-2015
Publisher
Springer Netherlands
Published in
Journal of Business Ethics / Issue 2/2016
Print ISSN: 0167-4544
Electronic ISSN: 1573-0697
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-015-2675-4

Other articles of this Issue 2/2016

Journal of Business Ethics 2/2016 Go to the issue