Skip to main content
Top

2019 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

2. Ramsey Model

Author : Burkhard Heer

Published in: Public Economics

Publisher: Springer International Publishing

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This chapter presents the Ramsey model. It is the benchmark model for most dynamic macroeconomic models that study growth and business cycle phenomena. We first study the deterministic Ramsey model in which the total factor productivity is certain. We contrast the effects of a once-and-for-all change with those of a temporary change in productivity on investment, output, and labor supply. In addition, we distinguish the effects of this change when it is known in advance or only observed at the beginning of the period, t, when the shock occurs. Finally, we also introduce uncertainty with respect to the technology level and discuss the real business cycle (RBC) model.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
One way to justify this assumption is that a household with a finite lifetime also cares about the utility of its descendants and applies the same discount factor β to their (representative) lifetime utility.
 
2
Take care to distinguish between the discount factor β and the discount rate θ > 0 that is given by
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \frac{1}{1+\theta} = \beta \;\; \Leftrightarrow \;\; \theta=\frac{1}{\beta}-1.\end{aligned} $$
 
3
Why have we added ‘− 1’ in the nominator of the utility function in (2.2) in the case σ≠1? First notice that the additive constant − 1∕(1 − σ) does not change the solution of the utility maximization problem and, therefore, does not affect optimal consumption. Furthermore, we know from calculus that
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \lim_{x\to 0} \left( \frac{a^x-1}{x}\right) =\ln a.\end{aligned} $$
Therefore, \(\ln c\) is just the limit of the function (c 1−σ − 1)∕(1 − σ) for σ → 1.
In order to derive the limit formula above, notice that from the L’Hôspital rule—which states that if the functions f(x) and g(x) in the nominator and denominator have the limit equal to zero, limx f(x) = 0 and limx g(x) = 0, the value of the limit \(\lim _{x\to 0} \left (f(x)/g(x)\right )\), if it exists, is given by \(\lim _{x\to 0} \left (f'(x)/g'(x)\right )\)—implies
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \lim_{x\to 0} \left( \frac{a^x-1}{x}\right) = \lim_{x\to 0} \left( \frac{a^x \ln a}{1}\right) = \ln a.\end{aligned}$$
 
4
Appendix 2.1 derives the IES in a simplified two-period model.
 
5
The elasticity of substitution σ p is defined as follows:
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \sigma_p = \frac{\frac{d\left( \frac{K}{L}\right)}{\frac{K}{L}}}{\frac{d\left( \frac{w}{r}\right)}{\frac{w}{r}}},\end{aligned}$$
where w and r denote the marginal products of labor and capital.
 
6
You are asked to compute the dynamics for the case in which σ p = 3∕4 in Problem 2.1.
 
7
More generally, an Euler equation is the intertemporal first-order condition for a dynamic choice problem and is usually formulated as a difference of differential equation. Equation (2.12) is also referred to as the Keynes-Ramsey rule that describes the growth rate of consumption as a result of intertemporal utility maximization.
 
8
By local stability we mean that if we perturb the initial condition slightly, then the system stays in the neighborhood of that steady state. If we use the term global stability, the system returns to the steady state even if the starting point is not very close to the steady state.
 
9
A recommendable introduction to the methods of calibration is provided by deJong and Dave (2011).
 
10
Mehra and Prescott (1985), Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987), and Prescott (1986) review empirical studies which suggest a range for σ ∈ [1,  2]. Most business cycle studies either use σ = 1.0 or σ = 2.0.
 
11
Of course, we should check whether this number of periods is sufficient to guarantee a smooth approximation of the new steady state. If not, we should increase the number of periods. For example, I first used 40 periods and found the number to be insufficient. Use the computer code and test for different values of the number of periods.
 
12
Appendix 2.2 provides an overview of how this numerical problem can be solved. The MATLAB/Gauss programs Ch2_ramsey1.m/Ch2_ramsey1.g compute the solution presented in Figs. 2.1, 2.2, 2.3, and 2.4 and can be downloaded from my homepage with all the other programs used in this book.
 
13
The argument for this result is straightforward: The central planner could also choose to behave exactly the same in the case of an expected change as in the case of an unexpected change. Since he chooses a different policy, this must be superior, and it yields a higher value of the objective function.
 
14
Beaudry and Portier (2004, 2006) are two prominent articles in this literature.
 
15
You are asked to compute the Jacobian and its value in Problem 2.2.
 
16
If you take the eigenvalues of the Jacobian provided in (2.17), the eigenvalues are slightly different due to rounding errors. I used the value of the Jacobian with an accuracy of 10−8 to compute the eigenvalues ρ 1 and ρ 2.
 
17
In a two-dimensional difference equation system, the steady state is a saddle if one of the eigenvalues has an absolute value below one and the other above. The steady state is locally saddle-path stable if one of the two variables is predetermined and the other is a jump variable (not predetermined). (In addition, divergent paths must be ruled out by boundary conditions.) To learn more about the stability analysis in systems of difference equations, consult Azariadis (1993).
 
18
We used the condition “c t = c t−1” rather than “c t+1 = c t” so that both functions which are graphed in Fig. 2.5 have the same argument k t (and not k t+1 as in the case “c t+1 = c t”).
 
19
To verify this statement, differentiate c t with respect to k t and solve for \(k_t= \left (\frac {\alpha }{\delta +n}\right )^{1/(1-\alpha )}\). For β < 1, the value of k t is above the steady state \(k= \left ( \frac {\alpha }{(1+n)/\beta -1+\delta }\right )^{1/(1-\alpha )}\).
 
20
One can show that all transition paths that start above S remain above and, similarly, that all paths that start below S remain below it. In addition, paths with the same initial capital stock k 0 but with different consumption values c 0 do not cross.
 
21
To compute the saddle path in Figs. 2.7 and 2.8, I increased the number of transition periods to 100 in the program Ch2_ramsey1.g so that the approximation of the new steady state is smooth.
 
22
A more general treatment is contained in Gandolfo (2009) or Azariadis (1993).
 
23
The closer we are to the steady state, the better the fit of our linear approximation will be.
 
24
In the case of a real matrix \(\tilde T\), the inverse \(\tilde T^{-1}\) of a unitary matrix is just the transpose \(\tilde T'\).
 
25
Standard software, such as MATLAB or Gauss, provides commands to compute the Schur factorization. MATLAB also provides a routine, ordschur(.), that can change the order of the eigenvalues if needed.
 
26
For those readers interested in numerical linear algebra, a Givens rotation is represented by a matrix transformation. In our problem, we search for a matrix
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} G=\left( \begin{array}{cc} d & -e\\ e & d \end{array}\right)\end{aligned}$$
that helps to transform \(\tilde S\) into \(S=G\tilde S\).
 
27
Notice that the coefficient of the first-order difference equation is equal to the stable root of the Jacobian, ρ 1 = 0.9242.
 
28
For a better illustration of the dynamics during the early periods 1–20, I only used 40 periods for the number of transition periods. Although the adjustment is not complete after 40 periods, the approximation is close during periods when the technology shock increases to Z t = 1.1. The MATLAB/Gauss program Ch2_ramsey2.m/Ch2_ramsey2.g computes the solution presented in Fig. 2.9.
 
29
In 2004, Finn E. Kydland and Edward C. Prescott received the Nobel prize for their research on RBCs.
 
30
The second theorem of welfare economics states that any efficient allocation can be sustained by a competitive equilibrium and, thus, constitutes the converse of the first theorem.
 
31
Two basic types of business cycle models are presented by RBC models, in which only real variables enter the model, and New Keynesian models, in which nominal variables enter the model and prices and/or wages are sticky. Both types of business cycle models are described in greater detail in Heer and Maußner (2009), McCandless (2008), and Cooley (1995).
 
32
The notation of rational expectation was originally introduced by Muth (1961).
 
33
Some time series are also available as monthly data, e.g., industrial production and employment. Some other economic variables such as distributional measures of income and consumption concentration in the form of their Gini coefficients, however, are only available on an annual basis, rendering the analysis of the short-term distributional effects of economic policy more difficult.
 
34
In some studies, the technology level follows a unit root process with trend
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \ln Z_t = \ln Z_{t-1} + a +\epsilon_t, \;\;\; \epsilon_t \sim N(0,\sigma^Z),\end{aligned}$$
where a denotes the drift or growth rate of total factor productivity. The modeling of the technology process (and, more generally, time series of macroeconomic variables) is not an innocuous assumption and affects business-cycle results. For example, Cogley and Nasan (1995) demonstrate that if pre-filtered series are first-order integrated, then HP-filtering of the series may result in business cycles that do not exist in the original pre-filtered data.
 
35
Basu, Fernald, and Kimball (2006) construct a measure of technology change in the presence of variable capacity utilization and imperfect competition.
 
36
The calibration of RBC models with respect to the characteristics of other industrialized countries employs similar values, e.g., Heer and Maußner (2009) estimate ρ Z = 0.90 and σ Z = 0.0072 for the German economy.
 
37
Notice that we interchanged the derivative and the expectational operator to derive the first-order conditions using:
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \frac{d}{dx} \mathbb{E} f(x,Z) = \mathbb{E}\frac{d}{dx} f(x,Z).\end{aligned}$$
This condition holds if f(x, Z) is integrable for all x and f is differentiable with respect to x. Furthermore, the expected value of Z is finite, \(\mathbb {E}(Z)<\infty \). The above equation is a special application of the Leibniz integral rule according to which
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \frac{d}{dx} \left( \int_{a(x)}^{b(x)} f(x,Z)\; dZ \right)= f(x,b(x))\cdot \frac{d}{dx} b(x)-f(x,a(x))\cdot \frac{d}{dx} a(x)+ \int_{a(x)}^{b(x)} \frac{\partial }{\partial x} f(x,Z) \;dZ. \end{aligned}$$
 
38
Therefore, our approximation is fairly close to the steady state but becomes increasingly inaccurate with increasing distance from the steady state. Linear approximation is a useful technique for the behavior of economies during tranquil times. During periods of severe crisis such as the Great Recession of 2007–2008, one should instead apply global approximation methods, as described in Chapters 5 and 6 in Heer and Maußner (2009).
 
39
The computation of the policy functions is described in greater detail in Appendix 2.3.
 
40
The MATLAB and Gauss programs, Ch2_rbc.m and Ch2_rbc.g, compute the policy functions, the impulse responses, and the time series statistics.
 
41
Empirical studies such as Galí (1999) and Basu, Fernald, and Kimball (2006) find that a positive technology shock led to a contraction of labor inputs. The standard RBC model is inconsistent with this observation. In Sect. 4.​5.​2, we present a New Keynesian model with sticky prices and adjustment costs of capital that is able to account for this fact.
 
42
Sometimes, the researcher also cuts the first 50 periods or similarly from the simulation so that the initialization of the state variables in the first period with their steady state values does not have any effect on the results.
 
43
The paper had already circulated as a discussion paper two decades earlier and was then introduced as a working paper by Hodrick and Prescott in 1980 that was published in 1997.
 
44
For a more detailed description of this filter and its computation, see for example, Chapter 12.4 in Heer and Maußner (2009).
 
45
Ravn and Uhlig (2001) and Baxter and King (1999) propose values of λ equal to 6.5 and 10 for annual data, respectively.
 
46
The data are described in more detail in Appendix 2.4.
 
47
The statistics are computed with the help of the MATLAB or Gauss programs Ch2_data.m and Ch2_data.g.
 
48
For the risk-free rate and the real equity return rate, we restrict our attention to the period 1959:Q2–2015:Q2. To construct the inflation rate for the computation of the real return, we use the price index for Private Consumption Expenditures (Excluding Food and Energy), which is only available during the period 1959:Q1–2015:Q2.
 
49
The parameter β = 0.99 in the RBC model is often calibrated to imply an annual real interest rate of 4%, which is a midpoint between the real returns of T-Bills and US equity.
 
50
In the case of the interest rate or equity return, which are already measured in percentage points, we do not take the log but rather apply the HP filter to the original series.
 
51
This approximation follows from a first-order Taylor series expansion
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} f(x) \approx f'(x_0) (x-x_0) \end{aligned}$$
with \(f(x)=\ln (1+x)\) and x 0 = 0 implying:
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \ln (1+x) \approx \frac{1}{1+x_0} (x-x_0)= x.\end{aligned}$$
 
52
In Problem 2.6, you are asked to analytically demonstrate this result.
 
53
The toolbox is available as the Gauss source file toolbox.src from my homepage.
 
54
This appendix is intended to offer a short introduction to the ideas of solution methods using a simple example. A much more detailed technical description with a generalization to multi-dimensional problems is provided in Chapter 2.4 of Heer and Maußner (2009) or in Chapter 6.8 of McCandless (2008).
 
55
In (2.77), we report the result from the computation with the program Ch2_rbc.g, where we used an accuracy of eight digits. If you compute the result by hand using the numerical values from Eqs. (2.75) and (2.76), the result might diverge by an order of 10−3 due to rounding errors.
 
Literature
go back to reference Attanasio, O., & Low, H. (2004). Estimating Euler equations. Review of Economic Dynamics, 7, 406–435.CrossRef Attanasio, O., & Low, H. (2004). Estimating Euler equations. Review of Economic Dynamics, 7, 406–435.CrossRef
go back to reference Auerbach, A. J., & Kotlikoff, L. (1987). Dynamic fiscal policy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Auerbach, A. J., & Kotlikoff, L. (1987). Dynamic fiscal policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Azariadis, C. (1993). Intertemporal macroeconomics. Oxford: Blackwell. Azariadis, C. (1993). Intertemporal macroeconomics. Oxford: Blackwell.
go back to reference Basu, S., Fernald, J. G., & Kimball, M. S. (2006). Are technology improvements contractionary?. American Economic Review, 96, 1418–1448.CrossRef Basu, S., Fernald, J. G., & Kimball, M. S. (2006). Are technology improvements contractionary?. American Economic Review, 96, 1418–1448.CrossRef
go back to reference Baxter, M., & King, R. G. (1999). Measuring business cycles: Approximate band-pass filters for economic time series. Review of Economics and Statistics, 81(4), 575–593.CrossRef Baxter, M., & King, R. G. (1999). Measuring business cycles: Approximate band-pass filters for economic time series. Review of Economics and Statistics, 81(4), 575–593.CrossRef
go back to reference Beaudry, P., & Portier, F. (2004). An exploration into Pigou’s theory of cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(6), 1183–1216.CrossRef Beaudry, P., & Portier, F. (2004). An exploration into Pigou’s theory of cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(6), 1183–1216.CrossRef
go back to reference Beaudry, P., & Portier, F. (2006). Stock prices, news, and economic fluctuations. American Economic Review, 596(4), 1293–1307.CrossRef Beaudry, P., & Portier, F. (2006). Stock prices, news, and economic fluctuations. American Economic Review, 596(4), 1293–1307.CrossRef
go back to reference Blanchard, O. J., & Kahn, C. M. (1980). The solution of linear difference models under rational expectations. Econometrica, 48, 1305–1311.CrossRef Blanchard, O. J., & Kahn, C. M. (1980). The solution of linear difference models under rational expectations. Econometrica, 48, 1305–1311.CrossRef
go back to reference Cass, D. (1965). Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation. Review of Economic Studies, 32, 233–240.CrossRef Cass, D. (1965). Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation. Review of Economic Studies, 32, 233–240.CrossRef
go back to reference Cogley, T., & Nasan, J. M. (1995). Output dynamics in real-business-cycle models. American Economic Review, 85, 492–511. Cogley, T., & Nasan, J. M. (1995). Output dynamics in real-business-cycle models. American Economic Review, 85, 492–511.
go back to reference Cooley, T. F. (1995). Frontiers of business cycle research. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Cooley, T. F. (1995). Frontiers of business cycle research. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Cooley, T. F., & Prescott, E. C. (1995). Economic growth and business cycles. In T. F. Cooley (Ed.), Frontiers of business cycle research (pp. 1–64). Princeton: Princeton University Press. Cooley, T. F., & Prescott, E. C. (1995). Economic growth and business cycles. In T. F. Cooley (Ed.), Frontiers of business cycle research (pp. 1–64). Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference deJong, D. N., & Dave, C. (2011). Structual macroeconometrics (2nd ed.). Princeton: Princeton University Press. deJong, D. N., & Dave, C. (2011). Structual macroeconometrics (2nd ed.). Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Galí, J. (1999). Technology, employment, and the business cycle: Do technology shocks explain aggregate fluctuations?. American Economic Review, 89, 249–271.CrossRef Galí, J. (1999). Technology, employment, and the business cycle: Do technology shocks explain aggregate fluctuations?. American Economic Review, 89, 249–271.CrossRef
go back to reference Heer, B., & Maußner, A. (2009). Dynamic general equilibrium modeling: Computational methods and applications (2nd ed.). Heidelberg: Springer.CrossRef Heer, B., & Maußner, A. (2009). Dynamic general equilibrium modeling: Computational methods and applications (2nd ed.). Heidelberg: Springer.CrossRef
go back to reference Heer, B., Maußner, A., & Süssmuth, B. (2018). Cyclical asset returns in the consumption and investment goods sector. Review of Economic Dynamics, 28, 51–70.CrossRef Heer, B., Maußner, A., & Süssmuth, B. (2018). Cyclical asset returns in the consumption and investment goods sector. Review of Economic Dynamics, 28, 51–70.CrossRef
go back to reference Heer, B., & Schubert, S. F. (2012). Unemployment and debt dynamics in a highly indebted small open economy. Journal of International Money and Finance, 31, 1392–1413.CrossRef Heer, B., & Schubert, S. F. (2012). Unemployment and debt dynamics in a highly indebted small open economy. Journal of International Money and Finance, 31, 1392–1413.CrossRef
go back to reference Hodrick, R. J., & Prescott, E. C. (1997). Postwar US business cycles: An empirical investigation. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 29, 1–16.CrossRef Hodrick, R. J., & Prescott, E. C. (1997). Postwar US business cycles: An empirical investigation. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 29, 1–16.CrossRef
go back to reference Jermann, U. J. (1998). Asset pricing in production economies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 41, 257–275.CrossRef Jermann, U. J. (1998). Asset pricing in production economies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 41, 257–275.CrossRef
go back to reference Judd, K. L. (1998). Numerical methods in economics. Cambridge: MIT Press. Judd, K. L. (1998). Numerical methods in economics. Cambridge: MIT Press.
go back to reference King, R. G., & Watson, M. W. (2002). System reduction and solution algorithms for singular difference systems under rational expectations. Computational Economics, 20, 57–86.CrossRef King, R. G., & Watson, M. W. (2002). System reduction and solution algorithms for singular difference systems under rational expectations. Computational Economics, 20, 57–86.CrossRef
go back to reference Koopmans, T. C. (1965). On the concept of optimal economic growth. In The econometric approach to development planning (pp. 225–287). Amsterdam: North-Holland. Koopmans, T. C. (1965). On the concept of optimal economic growth. In The econometric approach to development planning (pp. 225–287). Amsterdam: North-Holland.
go back to reference Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1982). Time to build and agregate fluctuations. Econometrica, 50, 1345–1370.CrossRef Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1982). Time to build and agregate fluctuations. Econometrica, 50, 1345–1370.CrossRef
go back to reference Long, J. B., & Plosser, C. I. (1983). Real business cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 91, 39–69.CrossRef Long, J. B., & Plosser, C. I. (1983). Real business cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 91, 39–69.CrossRef
go back to reference McCandless, G. (2008). The ABCs of RBCs. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. McCandless, G. (2008). The ABCs of RBCs. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
go back to reference McGrattan, E. R., & Prescott, E. C. (2014). A reassessment of real business cycle theory. American Economic Review, 104, 177–182.CrossRef McGrattan, E. R., & Prescott, E. C. (2014). A reassessment of real business cycle theory. American Economic Review, 104, 177–182.CrossRef
go back to reference Mehra, R., & Prescott, E. C. (1985). The equity premium: a puzzle. Journal of Monetary Economics, 15, 145–161.CrossRef Mehra, R., & Prescott, E. C. (1985). The equity premium: a puzzle. Journal of Monetary Economics, 15, 145–161.CrossRef
go back to reference Miranda, M. J., & Fackler, P. L. (2002). Applied computational economics and finance. Cambridge: MIT Press. Miranda, M. J., & Fackler, P. L. (2002). Applied computational economics and finance. Cambridge: MIT Press.
go back to reference Muth, J. F. (1961). Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica, 29, 315–335.CrossRef Muth, J. F. (1961). Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica, 29, 315–335.CrossRef
go back to reference Prescott, E. C. (1986). Theory ahead of business-cycle measurement. Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy, 24, 11–44.CrossRef Prescott, E. C. (1986). Theory ahead of business-cycle measurement. Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy, 24, 11–44.CrossRef
go back to reference Ramsey, F. (1928). A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal, 38, 543–559.CrossRef Ramsey, F. (1928). A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal, 38, 543–559.CrossRef
go back to reference Ravn, M. O., & Uhlig, H. (2001). On adjusting the HP-filter for the frequency of observations (CEPR Discussion Paper, 2858). Ravn, M. O., & Uhlig, H. (2001). On adjusting the HP-filter for the frequency of observations (CEPR Discussion Paper, 2858).
Metadata
Title
Ramsey Model
Author
Burkhard Heer
Copyright Year
2019
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-00989-2_2