Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 3-4/2014

01-09-2014

Reciprocity and resistance to comprehensive reform

Authors: Urs Fischbacher, Simeon Schudy

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 3-4/2014

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Comprehensive reforms often fail, despite being beneficial to society. Politicians may block comprehensive reforms in an attempt to form vote trading coalitions in which they benefit from a piecemeal reform at the expense of others. Because formal commitment devices for vote trading are frequently missing, trust and reciprocity among legislators can play an important role for vote trading. We investigate in a laboratory experiment whether legislators will impede comprehensive reforms in an attempt to form vote trading coalitions even if formal commitment devices for vote trading after reform failure are missing. We find that open ballots allow for vote trading without commitment, based on trust and reciprocity. In turn, legislators frequently reject efficient comprehensive reforms in such institutions.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
For a comprehensive survey on resistance to reform see also Heinemann (2004).
 
2
McKelvey and Ordershook also ran treatments in which any majority of participants could agree on passing or failing bills by signing an agreement card (with unrestricted discussion beforehand). In these treatments they mainly observe fair outcomes in three-player games and support for the competitive solution in five-player games.
 
3
We do so in order to abstract from additional reasons affecting coalition formation such as overrepresentation of own preference intensities (see, e.g., Myerson and Satterthwaite 1983; Casella 2005; Jackson and Sonnenschein 2007; Engelmann and Grimm 2012).
 
4
A copy of translated instructions can be found in the working paper version of this article at http://​www.​twi-kreuzlingen.​ch/​uploads/​tx_​cal/​media/​TWI-RPS-051-Fischbacher-Schudy-2010-05.​pdf.
 
5
For a risk-neutral subject, the probability of reward p r is sufficiently high if p r >1/3 because voting for another’s bill costs two points whereas reward yields six additional points.
 
6
The proof of this proposition can be found in Appendix A.
 
7
Proof of Proposition 2 can be found in Appendix B. Note also that due to the random matching procedure, there is no incentive for individual reputation building across periods, which might induce any additional motives for supporting monetarily unfavorable reforms.
 
8
The number of observations in Table 3 is calculated as follows: In OpenBallotCR reform failure occurred in 158 out of 252 cases. In SecretBallotCR reform failure occurred in 97 out of 204 cases. Thus in total there exist 255 situations in the CR treatments in which two subjects can cast a vote for an unfavorable bill which yields (2×255)=510 observations. For the NoCR treatments the number of observations can be easily derived from the number of subjects (51+54=105). Two-thirds of 105 subjects make a decision in 12 periods which yields a total of 540 observations. Note further that we cluster on the matching groups in order to control for players’ experience.
 
9
In order not to crowd the table unnecessarily we do not here include the regressions results for the third bill.
 
10
This share has to be considered as a lower bound for efficiency concerns, because not accepting subsequent bills after one’s own bill failed can be caused by negative reciprocity too.
 
11
To control for possible end-game effects, we also ran the regressions in Table 5 including a last period dummy. For both, reward and trust, the last period dummy is negative, but statistically insignificant. The coefficient of transparency is robust. For reward, the time trend variable is still negative but statistically insignificant. The coefficient of the interaction term (Period-1) × Comprehensive Reform Treatment is robust.
 
12
The latter difference is not statistically significant (Probit with robust standard errors, p-val.>0.10).
 
13
The latter difference is statistically significant (Probit with robust standard. errors, p-val.<0.10).
 
14
We cannot infer whether the latter increase is due to positive signaling or because members preferring the third bill expect the second bill to be passed anyway and therefore have nothing to lose by voting for the second bill.
 
15
Probit regressions with robust standard errors, p-values<0.06.
 
16
To control for possible end-game effects, we also ran the regressions in Table 9 including a last period dummy. For reward (Open and Secret Ballot) and trust (Secret Ballot), the regression results are robust and the last period dummy is statistically insignificant. For trust in Open Ballot, the last period dummy is negative and statistically significant at the ten percent level.
 
17
We thank an anonymous referee for pointing this out.
 
18
See, for instance, Geng et al. (2011), who investigate how two different types of electoral campaigns (self-descriptions of personality and promises regarding prospective in-office behavior) affect choices by elected representatives. The authors find supporting evidence for the guilt aversion hypothesis (Charness and Dufwenberg 2006). When elections were promise-based elected candidates transferred more money to recipients than candidates selected by a random draw (although promises did not differ). Also, promises and beliefs on voter expectations were positively correlated but correlations between dictators’ second-order beliefs and their choices were weaker than predicted. Further, results from Weiss and Wolff (2013) cast doubt on the robustness of the finding that a voting mechanism may create or strengthen an entitlement effect in political-power holders.
 
19
See, e.g., Leibbrandt and Sääksvuori (2012).
 
Literature
go back to reference Alesina, A., & Drazen, A. (1991). Why are stabilizations delayed? The American Economic Review, 81, 1170–1188. Alesina, A., & Drazen, A. (1991). Why are stabilizations delayed? The American Economic Review, 81, 1170–1188.
go back to reference Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 122–142. CrossRef Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 122–142. CrossRef
go back to reference Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. The American Economic Review, 90, 166–193. CrossRef Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. The American Economic Review, 90, 166–193. CrossRef
go back to reference Brams, S. J., & Riker, W. H. (1973). The paradox of vote trading. American Political Science Review, 67, 1235–1247. CrossRef Brams, S. J., & Riker, W. H. (1973). The paradox of vote trading. American Political Science Review, 67, 1235–1247. CrossRef
go back to reference Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
go back to reference Cason, T. N., & Mui, V. L. (2003). Testing political economy models of reform in the laboratory. The American Economic Review, 93, 208–212. CrossRef Cason, T. N., & Mui, V. L. (2003). Testing political economy models of reform in the laboratory. The American Economic Review, 93, 208–212. CrossRef
go back to reference Casella, A. (2005). Storable votes. Games and Economic Behavior, 51, 391–419. CrossRef Casella, A. (2005). Storable votes. Games and Economic Behavior, 51, 391–419. CrossRef
go back to reference Charness, G., & Dufwenberg, M. (2006). Promises and partnership. Econometrica, 74, 1579–1601. CrossRef Charness, G., & Dufwenberg, M. (2006). Promises and partnership. Econometrica, 74, 1579–1601. CrossRef
go back to reference Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics, 117, 817–869. Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics, 117, 817–869.
go back to reference Cox, J. C., Friedman, D., & Gjerstad, S. (2007). A tractable model of reciprocity and fairness. Games and Economic Behavior, 59, 17–45. CrossRef Cox, J. C., Friedman, D., & Gjerstad, S. (2007). A tractable model of reciprocity and fairness. Games and Economic Behavior, 59, 17–45. CrossRef
go back to reference Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2009). Homo reciprocans: survey evidence on behavioural outcomes. The Economic Journal, 119, 592–612. CrossRef Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2009). Homo reciprocans: survey evidence on behavioural outcomes. The Economic Journal, 119, 592–612. CrossRef
go back to reference Dufwenberg, M., & Kirchsteiger, G. (2004). A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47, 268–298. CrossRef Dufwenberg, M., & Kirchsteiger, G. (2004). A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47, 268–298. CrossRef
go back to reference Engelmann, D., & Grimm, V. (2012). Mechanisms for efficient voting with private information about preferences. The Economic Journal, 122, 1010–1041. CrossRef Engelmann, D., & Grimm, V. (2012). Mechanisms for efficient voting with private information about preferences. The Economic Journal, 122, 1010–1041. CrossRef
go back to reference Falk, A., & Fischbacher, U. (2006). A theory of reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 54, 293–315. CrossRef Falk, A., & Fischbacher, U. (2006). A theory of reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 54, 293–315. CrossRef
go back to reference Falk, A., Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2008). Testing theories of fairness-intentions matter. Games and Economic Behavior, 62, 287–303. CrossRef Falk, A., Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2008). Testing theories of fairness-intentions matter. Games and Economic Behavior, 62, 287–303. CrossRef
go back to reference Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (1998). Reciprocity and economics: the economic implications of homo reciprocans. European Economic Review, 42, 845–859. CrossRef Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (1998). Reciprocity and economics: the economic implications of homo reciprocans. European Economic Review, 42, 845–859. CrossRef
go back to reference Fehr, E., Kirchsteiger, G., & Riedl, A. (1998). Gift exchange and reciprocity in competitive experimental markets. European Economic Review, 42, 1–34. CrossRef Fehr, E., Kirchsteiger, G., & Riedl, A. (1998). Gift exchange and reciprocity in competitive experimental markets. European Economic Review, 42, 1–34. CrossRef
go back to reference Fernandez, R., & Rodrik, D. (1991). Resistance to reform: status quo bias in the presence of individual-specific uncertainty. The American Economic Review, 81, 1146–1155. Fernandez, R., & Rodrik, D. (1991). Resistance to reform: status quo bias in the presence of individual-specific uncertainty. The American Economic Review, 81, 1146–1155.
go back to reference Fischbacher, U. (2007). Z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171–178. CrossRef Fischbacher, U. (2007). Z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171–178. CrossRef
go back to reference Fischbacher, U., & Schudy, S. (2013). Agenda setting and reciprocal vote trading. TWI research paper series, vol. 60. Fischbacher, U., & Schudy, S. (2013). Agenda setting and reciprocal vote trading. TWI research paper series, vol. 60.
go back to reference Geng, H., Weiss, A. R., & Wolff, I. (2011). The limited power of voting to limit power. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 13, 695–719. CrossRef Geng, H., Weiss, A. R., & Wolff, I. (2011). The limited power of voting to limit power. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 13, 695–719. CrossRef
go back to reference Greiner, B. (2004). An online recruitment system for economic experiments. In K. Kremer & V. Macho (Eds.), Forschung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen. GWDG Bericht 63 (pp. 79–93). Göttingen: Gesellschaft für wissenschaftliche Datenverarbeitung. Greiner, B. (2004). An online recruitment system for economic experiments. In K. Kremer & V. Macho (Eds.), Forschung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen. GWDG Bericht 63 (pp. 79–93). Göttingen: Gesellschaft für wissenschaftliche Datenverarbeitung.
go back to reference Heinemann, F. (2004). Explaining blockades to beneficial policy reforms—an empirical investigation. Applied Economics Quarterly, 55, 9–26. Heinemann, F. (2004). Explaining blockades to beneficial policy reforms—an empirical investigation. Applied Economics Quarterly, 55, 9–26.
go back to reference Jackson, M. O., & Sonnenschein, H. F. (2007). Overcoming incentive constraints by linking decisions. Econometrica, 75, 241–257. CrossRef Jackson, M. O., & Sonnenschein, H. F. (2007). Overcoming incentive constraints by linking decisions. Econometrica, 75, 241–257. CrossRef
go back to reference Kagel, J., Sung, H., & Winter, E. (2010). Veto power in committees: an experimental study. Experimental Economics, 13, 1–22. CrossRef Kagel, J., Sung, H., & Winter, E. (2010). Veto power in committees: an experimental study. Experimental Economics, 13, 1–22. CrossRef
go back to reference Leibbrandt, A., & Sääksvuori, L. (2012). Communication in intergroup conflicts. European Economic Review, 56, 1136–1147. CrossRef Leibbrandt, A., & Sääksvuori, L. (2012). Communication in intergroup conflicts. European Economic Review, 56, 1136–1147. CrossRef
go back to reference Levine, D. K. (1998). Modeling altruism and spitefulness in experiments. Review of Economic Dynamics, 1, 593–622. CrossRef Levine, D. K. (1998). Modeling altruism and spitefulness in experiments. Review of Economic Dynamics, 1, 593–622. CrossRef
go back to reference McCabe, K. A., Rassenti, S. J., & Smith, V. L. (1998). Reciprocity, trust, and payoff privacy in extensive form bargaining. Games and Economic Behavior, 24, 10–24. CrossRef McCabe, K. A., Rassenti, S. J., & Smith, V. L. (1998). Reciprocity, trust, and payoff privacy in extensive form bargaining. Games and Economic Behavior, 24, 10–24. CrossRef
go back to reference McKelvey, R. D., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1980). Vote trading: an experimental study. Public Choice, 35, 151–184. CrossRef McKelvey, R. D., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1980). Vote trading: an experimental study. Public Choice, 35, 151–184. CrossRef
go back to reference Myerson, R. B., & Satterthwaite, M. A. (1983). Efficient mechanisms for bilateral trading. Journal of Economic Theory, 29, 265–281. CrossRef Myerson, R. B., & Satterthwaite, M. A. (1983). Efficient mechanisms for bilateral trading. Journal of Economic Theory, 29, 265–281. CrossRef
go back to reference Paetzel, F., Sausgruber, R., & Traub, S. (2012). Social preferences and voting on reform-an experimental study. Available at SSRN 2066455. Paetzel, F., Sausgruber, R., & Traub, S. (2012). Social preferences and voting on reform-an experimental study. Available at SSRN 2066455.
go back to reference Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game-theory and economics. The American Economic Review, 83, 1281–1302. Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game-theory and economics. The American Economic Review, 83, 1281–1302.
go back to reference Rabin, M., & Schrag, J. (1999). First impressions matter: a model of confirmatory bias. Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics, 114, 37–82. Rabin, M., & Schrag, J. (1999). First impressions matter: a model of confirmatory bias. Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics, 114, 37–82.
go back to reference Saint-Paul, G. (2002). The political economy of employment protection. Journal of Political Economy, 110, 672–704. CrossRef Saint-Paul, G. (2002). The political economy of employment protection. Journal of Political Economy, 110, 672–704. CrossRef
go back to reference Samuelson, W., & Zeckhauser, R. (1988). Status quo bias in decision making. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1, 7–59. CrossRef Samuelson, W., & Zeckhauser, R. (1988). Status quo bias in decision making. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1, 7–59. CrossRef
go back to reference Strassmair, C. (2009). Can intentions spoil the kindness of a gift? An experimental study. Munich discussion paper. Strassmair, C. (2009). Can intentions spoil the kindness of a gift? An experimental study. Munich discussion paper.
go back to reference Stratmann, T. (1992). The effects of logrolling on congressional voting. The American Economic Review, 82, 1162–1176. Stratmann, T. (1992). The effects of logrolling on congressional voting. The American Economic Review, 82, 1162–1176.
go back to reference Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: how political institutions work. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: how political institutions work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Tullock, G. (1959). Problems of majority voting. Journal of Political Economy, 67, 571–579. CrossRef Tullock, G. (1959). Problems of majority voting. Journal of Political Economy, 67, 571–579. CrossRef
go back to reference Weiss, A. R., & Wolff, I. (2013). Does being elected increase subjective entitlements? Evidence from the laboratory. TWI research paper series, No. 82. Weiss, A. R., & Wolff, I. (2013). Does being elected increase subjective entitlements? Evidence from the laboratory. TWI research paper series, No. 82.
go back to reference Xiao, E., & Houser, D. (2005). Emotion expression in human punishment behavior. In Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, vol. 102, pp. 7398–7401. Xiao, E., & Houser, D. (2005). Emotion expression in human punishment behavior. In Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, vol. 102, pp. 7398–7401.
Metadata
Title
Reciprocity and resistance to comprehensive reform
Authors
Urs Fischbacher
Simeon Schudy
Publication date
01-09-2014
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 3-4/2014
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0097-3

Other articles of this Issue 3-4/2014

Public Choice 3-4/2014 Go to the issue

Premium Partner