Skip to main content
Top

2015 | Book

Shareholder Empowerment

A New Era in Corporate Governance

Editors: Maria Goranova, Lori Verstegen Ryan

Publisher: Palgrave Macmillan US

insite
SEARCH

About this book

In this volume, leading management experts offer critical insights into the promises and illusions of shareholder empowerment, the discrepancies between theory and practice, and the challenges posed by variations in global corporate governance regimes.

Table of Contents

Frontmatter

Shareholder Empowerment: An Introduction

Chapter 1. Shareholder Empowerment: An Introduction
Abstract
Recent trends in shareholder empowerment have spurred a heated debate about whether empowered shareholders will ultimately cure corporate ills or adversely affect corporate fortunes. Publicly traded corporations are uniquely positioned to facilitate financial risk bearing, due to their dispersed ownership and liquidity and shareholders’ ability to diversify their financial risk (Easterbrook & Fischel, 1985). They have not only served as “the main engine of economic progress” in the twentieth century (Jensen, 1989: 61), but have also driven social progress by facilitating professionalism, upward mobility, and meritocracy, as well as by providing job stability, and retirement and health care benefits (Davis, 2011, 2013; Demsetz, 1983). The United States “owed everything to the corporation,” writes Beatty (2001), tracing the very development of democracy in the United States to the morphing of early settler companies into a commonwealth. Yet views on corporations have polarized from “the basis of the prosperity of the West and the best hope for the future of the rest of the world” (Micklethwait & Wooldridge, 2003) to the critical query, “are corporations evil?” (Litowitz, 2003).
Maria Goranova, Lori Verstegen Ryan

Shareholder Empowerment: Promises and Illusions

Frontmatter
Chapter 2. Combining Financial and Psychological Insights for a New Typology of Ownership
Abstract
Since the work of Berle and Means (1932), organizational scholars have recognized that the interests of “owners” of a firm may differ from those of management. Agency theory research has a long tradition of focusing on these potentially different interests (e.g., Eisenhardt, 1989; Fama & Jensen, 1983; Jensen & Meckling, 1976). Scholars also recognize that “owners” can be a diverse mix of different types of investors and have provided typologies of these different “types” (e.g., Brickley, Lease, & Smith, 1988; Bushee, 1998; Connelly, Hoskisson, Tihanyi, & Certo, 2010; David, O’Brien, Yoshikawa, & Delios, 2010). However, most of these typologies still remain mired in agency theory assumptions of economic rationality and purely financial motivation.
Katarina Sikavica, Amy J. Hillman
Chapter 3. Is Shareholder Empowerment a “Good Thing”?
Abstract
From an agency theory perspective (Fama, 1980; Fama & Jensen, 1983; see Lan & Heracleous, 2010, for a recent review), shareholder empowerment can be seen as a means of enhancing the balance of power between owners and managers, controlling managerial power, reducing the effects of information asymmetries, and keeping agency costs in check (Bebchuk, 2005). Critics of this view argue that changing regulatory arrangements (including shareholders’ voting rights and decision influence) would have unanticipated negative effects. Concerns include the introduction of inefficiencies in corporate governance and uncertainty as to how shareholders would be held accountable for their decision influence (Bainbridge, 2006; Bratton & Wachter, 2009; Sharfman, 2012). The equivocal outcomes of shareholder activism on both firm performance and shareholder returns (Goranova & Ryan, 2014) make an evaluation of the desirability of shareholder empowerment even more complex.
Kevin Morrell, Loizos Heracleous
Chapter 4. Shareholder Democracy as a Misbegotten Metaphor
Abstract
The rise in corporate scandals and the dawning of the great recession motivated frustrated shareholders to seek greater power in order to influence the actions of the firms in which they own equity. Shareholder democracy has become the umbrella term for these shareholder empowerment efforts.1 Shareholder democracy is a worldwide movement (Fairfax, 2008a) that, having achieved a foothold in the United States, is gaining ground in Canada (Veall, 2012) and Europe (Rose, 2012). Although recently reinvigorated, this shareholder democracy movement is not new. The concept dates back to shortly after World War II, when Lewis Gilbert popularized the concept in the United States. Emerson and Latcham (1954: 152) later argued that “vigorous shareholder participation” was in keeping with democratic values. Mintzberg (1983) contributed a similar argument, contending that a country can only consider itself to be free if its major institutions subscribe to democratic principles. Arguments in favor of shareholder democracy have ranged from protecting society from corporate power to protecting shareholders from managerial abuse to protecting the rights of shareholders to shape their own destinies (Tsuk Mitchell, 2006). These arguments have taken hold as the shareholder democracy movement has pushed successfully for shareholder empowerment at annual meetings, SEC policy changes, and legislative developments that all have led to greater direct shareholder influence over corporate practices (Cohen & Schleyer, 2012).2
Ann K. Buchholtz, Jill A. Brown
Chapter 5. “Agents without Principals” Revisited: Theorizing the Effects of Increased Shareholder Participation in Corporate Governance
Abstract
The subject of corporate governance—defined by Ryan, Buchholtz, and Kolb as “the roles, responsibilities, and balance of power among executives, directors, and shareholders” (2010: 673)—presents management scholars with a number of vexing problems. These problems have included such issues as executive compensation, the adoption of poison pills, the payment of greenmail, the establishment of golden parachutes, and resistance to many shareholder proposals on annual proxy ballots. While many of these issues are of concern mainly to scholars and shareholder activists, executive compensation, because of the ever-increasing multiple of executive pay to average worker pay (Economic Policy Institute, 2013), also resonates with many members of the general public.
Thomas M. Jones, Adrian A. C. Keevil
Chapter 6. Boards and Shareholders: Bridging the Divide
Abstract
Today’s corporate environment, and the interactions among its participants, are increasingly complex and dynamic. The market has responded with expansive regulations, listing rules, and bylaws aimed at empowering shareholders. With this empowerment, shareholders can now voice their discontent and demand necessary corrections. Notably, corporate constituents have not only more information, but also more ways to access it (e.g., formal reporting, public filings, Twitter, blogs, e-mails, listservs, etc.), creating both greater transparency and greater scrutiny of organizational behaviors.
Jenna Burke, Cynthia Clark
Chapter 7. The Twilight of the Berle and Means Corporation
Abstract
During the five decades after Berle and Means published The Modern Corporation and Private Property in 1932, their analysis became the dominant understanding of the American corporation. Social scientists, policymakers, and the broader interested public knew about the separation of ownership and control, the potentially fraught relations between shareholders and managers, and the image of the corporation as a social institution. Berle and Means’s view of an economy dominated by a handful of ever-larger corporations run by an unaccountable managerial class inspired scholarship from sociologists (who were convinced they were right) to financial economists (who wanted to prove them wrong) to lawyers (who contemplated the rights and obligations implied by this system).
Gerald Davis

Shareholder Diversity and Global Empowerment

Frontmatter
Chapter 8. Managerialism versus Shareholderism: An Examination of Hedge Fund Activism
Abstract
For investment institutions that fully exploit their private status, hedge funds command a surprisingly large public profile. For example, the media gave significant coverage to SAC, the hedge fund started by Steven A. Cohen, with eight employees convicted of insider trading (Stevenson & Goldstein, 2014). Recent cases of successful hedge fund activism include Daniel Loeb’s Third Point Fund pressuring of auction house Sotheby’s—the oldest company traded on the NYSE—to separate its businesses, engage in stock buybacks, and increase its dividend (Stevenson & de la Merced, 2014). A case of activism that has met with opposition from other investors concerns leveraged-buyout-turned-hedge-fund-activist Carl C. Icahn pressing Apple for a stock buyback (de la Merced, 2014). Another visible case is the battle between William A. Ackman of Pershing Square Capital Management and Herbalife, in which he has “pulled the levers of power” in pressing regulators and politicians against the company (Schmidt, Lipton, & Stevenson, 2014). Rooted in collective memory is Long-Term Capital Management, which in 1998 created turmoil in currency markets, causing 14 central banks to facilitate efforts to avoid global contagion of the downturn (Dungey, Frey, Gonzalez-Hermosillo, & Martin, 2007; Furfine, 2006; Halstead, Hedge, & Klein, 2005) and leading to popular use of the phrases “too big to fail” and “moral hazard.” Yet, despite the publicity surrounding them and despite their global importance, information about hedge funds remains incomplete and insufficient (McCahery & Vermeulen, 2008).
Marguerite Schneider
Chapter 9. Religious Organizations as Shareholders: Salience and Empowerment
Abstract
While a traditional agency approach tends to assume that shareholder interests are aligned, research highlights that shareholders are heterogeneous and divided in their demands (Anabtawi 2007; Barnea & Rubin, 2010; Williams & Ryan, 2007). A complete discussion of shareholder empowerment would therefore not be possible without including the role of responsible investment, a well established investment approach that represents more than $3.7 trillion in the United States, or more than 11 percent of the US’s total assets under management (USSIF, 2012). Religious organizations (ROs) have been credited with being the pioneers of responsible investment (Kreander, McPhail, & Molyneaux, 2004; Sparkes & Cowton, 2004). While neither the largest nor the richest type of shareholder, they are the most active filers of social issue resolutions in the United States (Proffitt & Spicer, 2006), consistently filing around 25 percent of all shareholder proposals (Copland & O’Keefe, 2013). Increasing media awareness of aligning the values and mission of an organization with its investment principles has also raised the profile of nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) and ROs in investment (BBC, 2013; Guardian, 2013; Thomas, 2011).
Jennifer Goodman
Chapter 10. Angel Investors: Early Firm Owners
Abstract
Angel investors are often the first outside investors in a firm (Wetzel, 1983). Given the history of the firm prior to their financing—that is, virtually new and unknown—their decision to provide funding for the entrepreneurial venture poses quite an investment risk (Mason & Harrison, 2002). Ventures perceived to be less risky while still offering an acceptable return on investment are more likely to receive financing (Ganzach, 2000; Lange, Leleux, & Surlemont, 2003; Tyebjee & Bruno, 1984). Certain firm and angel characteristics influence the angel’s perception of the investment and decision to participate (Galbraith, De Noble, & Ehrlich, 2009). Once involved as part-owners, the angels themselves can have a strong influence on the firm and its functioning (Prowse, 1998). Provided that the firm survives and moves more closely to an investor exit (e.g., initial public offering [IPO] or buyout), the angels also play a role with regard to the next-stage owners.
John Berns, Karen Schnatterly
Chapter 11. Privatization and Principal-Principal Conflicts in Transition Economies
Abstract
The corporate governance literature identifies two major governance models. The first is based on equity finance, controlled by capital markets, and mostly seen in common law system countries such as the United Kingdom and the United States. The second is based on debt finance, controlled by financial institutions, and mostly seen in continental European countries (such as Germany) and Japan. Because both equity and debt markets were underdeveloped, transition economies (also some South American and Asian countries) have introduced a third model characterized by concentrated ownership (Estrin, Hanousek, Kočenda, & Svejnar, 2009; Pistor, 2006). Transition economies are formerly socialist countries and are distinguished by a number of institutional and organizational features that introduce peculiar problems and may dictate differences in corporate governance mechanisms. In fact, “no other place in the world offers such ample and creative corporate governance pathologies” (Fox & Heller, 2006: 391). In particular, principal-principal (PP) conflicts, which refer to the potential expropriation of minority shareholders by controlling owners, are among the most well known corporate governance problems in transition economies (Young et al., 2008).
Canan Mutlu, Mike Peng, Marc van Essen
Chapter 12. Institutional Change and Ownership Patterns in Italy
Abstract
Dominant legal (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1997, 1998, 2000) and political (Roe, 2003) views of corporate governance systems suggest that such institutional changes as regulatory reforms and privatization processes can break down the institutions of stable shareholding. So the partial stability of ownership patterns in Italy during the last two decades, despite a large increase in investors’ rights and the privatization of a number of state-owned firms, seems to be an “unambiguous disconfirmation of existing theories” (Culpepper, 2007: 799).
Alessandro Zattoni, Francesca Cuomo
Chapter 13. Local Repairs in Light of Global Ideals: Corporate Governance Reforms and Firm Ownership around the World
Abstract
Agency theory’s principal-agent corporate governance model has taken the fields of financial economics and management studies by storm since it was first introduced by Jensen and Meckling (1976). Its employment by scholars of both denominations has since then largely shaped the language that we employ to describe the modern corporation (Lubatkin, Lane, Collin, & Very, 2005). In fact, the large industrial corporation is primarily discussed, both in the business press and by security analysts, using such financial terms as “debts,” “assets,” and “cash flow” (Fligstein & Freeland, 1995). In turn, managers and owners of firms have largely begun to see their firms in exactly the same way (Useem, 1993). Firms in the United States and the United Kingdom are particularly evaluated according to a financial economics framework, and governed in light of a financially inspired view of the modern corporation (Fama, 1980; Fama & Jensen, 1983; Roe, 1994).
Jordan Otten, Marc van Essen
Backmatter
Metadata
Title
Shareholder Empowerment
Editors
Maria Goranova
Lori Verstegen Ryan
Copyright Year
2015
Publisher
Palgrave Macmillan US
Electronic ISBN
978-1-137-37393-9
Print ISBN
978-1-137-37644-2
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137373939