Skip to main content
Top
Published in: International Tax and Public Finance 2/2021

07-01-2021

Structural fund, endogenous move and commitment

Authors: Carsten Eckel, Yutao Han, Kate Hynes, Jin Zhang

Published in: International Tax and Public Finance | Issue 2/2021

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In this paper, we extend the study on combined tax and infrastructure competition by endogenizing the timing of decisions made by asymmetric countries. We consider how a structural fund affects the endogenous move decision and show that the poor country prefers to be a follower only when the production function is sufficiently concave. We also analyse the effect of the structural fund on total welfare and design a commitment game to ensure that the socially optimal outcome is achieved.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
In the present paper, we refer to hard and soft infrastructure. Hard infrastructure refers to physical facilities such as transportation and communications networks or electrical power facilities. Soft infrastructure refers to basic institutions that are essential to the functioning of a community, such as health, education, financial and legal systems.
 
2
The ESIF consists of five main funds working together to support economic development across all the EU countries. These five funds are the European Regional Development Fund, the Cohesion Fund, the European Agricultural Fund for Rural Development, the European Social Fund and the European Maritime and Fisheries Fund.
 
3
During the period 2014–2020, the Cohesion Fund has assigned EUR 63.4 billion to activities under the trans-European networks (TENs) which includes infrastructure projects under the Connecting Europe Facility. Also encompassed within the Cohesion Fund are investments towards benefiting the environment such as promoting climate change, energy efficiency, the use of renewable energy and strengthening public transport. According to the data from European Commission, Poland, Romania and Czech Republic are the first three countries who receive the most amount of the Cohesion Fund. See https://​ec.​europa.​eu/​regional_​policy/​en/​funding/​cohesion-fund/​ (downloaded July 2, 2020).
 
6
Kempf and Rota-Graziosi (2010) find that leadership by the small region is the risk dominant outcome using the pre-play stage as in Hamilton and Slutsky (1990). However, Hindriks and Nishimura (2015) show that leadership by the large region becomes the risk dominant equilibrium and can even become Pareto superior simply by reversing the form of asymmetry in Kempf and Rota-Graziosi (2010). Ogawa (2013) analyses the role of capital ownership in leadership in tax competition.
 
7
See Altshuler and Goodspeed (2015) for empirical evidence. Wang (1999) asserts that “it is natural and conceivable that, in a real-world situation of tax-setting, the large region moves first” (p. 974). Baldwin and Krugman (2004) also make the same assumption of the large (core) region’s leadership to show that equilibrium tax rates remain higher in the core region than in the small (periphery). The argument there is that the intuitive leadership by the large region is based on its ability to exploit market power. The large region has greater market power that permits itself to benefit from higher tax rates.
 
8
Other examples of studies that have used a linear quadratic production function include Bucovetsky (1991, 2009), Peralta and Ypersele (2006) and Itaya et al. (2008).
 
9
If \(k_{1}=k_{2}=k\), \(g_{1}=g_{2}=g\) and \(S=0\) we have \(F_{2}-F_{1}= \varepsilon k\) and \(\partial F_{2}/\partial k_{2}-\partial F_{1}/\partial k_{1}=\varepsilon\).
 
10
One interesting implication of this result is that there exists a conflict of interest between the two countries if \(\delta <1\). This opens up the possibility of a conditional transfer where the rich country is trying to induce a certain behaviour by the poor country through the structural fund. This is an interesting possibility but lies outside the scope of this study where we assume that the structural fund is exogenously given.
 
Literature
go back to reference Altshuler, R., & Goodspeed, T. (2015). Follow the leader? Evidence on European and U.S. tax competition. Public Finance Review, 43(4), 485–504.CrossRef Altshuler, R., & Goodspeed, T. (2015). Follow the leader? Evidence on European and U.S. tax competition. Public Finance Review, 43(4), 485–504.CrossRef
go back to reference Amir, R., & Grilo, I. (1999). Stackelberg versus Cournot equilibrium. Games and Economic Behavior, 26, 1–21.CrossRef Amir, R., & Grilo, I. (1999). Stackelberg versus Cournot equilibrium. Games and Economic Behavior, 26, 1–21.CrossRef
go back to reference Arellano, C., Bulir, A., Lane, T., & Lipschitz, L. (2009). The dynamic implications of foreign aid and its variability. Journal of Development Economics, 88(1), 87–102.CrossRef Arellano, C., Bulir, A., Lane, T., & Lipschitz, L. (2009). The dynamic implications of foreign aid and its variability. Journal of Development Economics, 88(1), 87–102.CrossRef
go back to reference Baldwin, R. E., & Krugman, P. (2004). Agglomeration, integration and tax harmonisation. European Economic Review, 48(1), 1–23.CrossRef Baldwin, R. E., & Krugman, P. (2004). Agglomeration, integration and tax harmonisation. European Economic Review, 48(1), 1–23.CrossRef
go back to reference Basile, R., Castellani, D., & Zanfei, A. (2008). Location choices of multinational firms in Europe: The role of EU cohesion policy. Journal of International Economics, 74(2), 328–340.CrossRef Basile, R., Castellani, D., & Zanfei, A. (2008). Location choices of multinational firms in Europe: The role of EU cohesion policy. Journal of International Economics, 74(2), 328–340.CrossRef
go back to reference Bucovetsky, S. (1991). Asymmetric tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 30(2), 167–181.CrossRef Bucovetsky, S. (1991). Asymmetric tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 30(2), 167–181.CrossRef
go back to reference Bucovetsky, S. (2009) An index of capital tax competition. International Tax and Public Finance, 16(6), 727–752.CrossRef Bucovetsky, S. (2009) An index of capital tax competition. International Tax and Public Finance, 16(6), 727–752.CrossRef
go back to reference Burnside, C., & Dollar, D. (2000). Aid, policies, and growth. American Economic Review, 90(4), 847–868.CrossRef Burnside, C., & Dollar, D. (2000). Aid, policies, and growth. American Economic Review, 90(4), 847–868.CrossRef
go back to reference Cai, H., & Treisman, D. (2005). Does competition for capital discipline governments? Decentralization, globalization, and public policy. The American Economic Review, 95(3), 817–830.CrossRef Cai, H., & Treisman, D. (2005). Does competition for capital discipline governments? Decentralization, globalization, and public policy. The American Economic Review, 95(3), 817–830.CrossRef
go back to reference Dalgaard, C. J., Hansen, H., & Tarp, F. (2004). On the empirics of foreign aid and growth. The Economic Journal, 114(496), F191–F216.CrossRef Dalgaard, C. J., Hansen, H., & Tarp, F. (2004). On the empirics of foreign aid and growth. The Economic Journal, 114(496), F191–F216.CrossRef
go back to reference De Mello, L. (2008). The brazilian tax war: The case of value added tax competition among the states. Public Finance Review, 36(2), 169–193.CrossRef De Mello, L. (2008). The brazilian tax war: The case of value added tax competition among the states. Public Finance Review, 36(2), 169–193.CrossRef
go back to reference Dembour, C., & Wauthy, X. (2009). Investment in public infrastructure with spillovers and tax competition between contiguous regions. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 39, 679–687.CrossRef Dembour, C., & Wauthy, X. (2009). Investment in public infrastructure with spillovers and tax competition between contiguous regions. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 39, 679–687.CrossRef
go back to reference Gomes P., & Pouget F. (2008). Corporate tax competition and the decline of public investment. European Central Bank, 2008, Working Paper Series No. 928. Gomes P., & Pouget F. (2008). Corporate tax competition and the decline of public investment. European Central Bank, 2008, Working Paper Series No. 928.
go back to reference Hamilton, J. H., & Slutsky, S. M. (1990). Endogenous timing in duopoly games: Stackelberg or cournot equilibria. Games & Economic Behavior, 2(1), 29–46.CrossRef Hamilton, J. H., & Slutsky, S. M. (1990). Endogenous timing in duopoly games: Stackelberg or cournot equilibria. Games & Economic Behavior, 2(1), 29–46.CrossRef
go back to reference Hauptmeier, S. F., & Mittermaier, J. R. (2012). Fiscal competition over taxes and public inputs. Regional Science & Urban Economics, 42(3), 407–419.CrossRef Hauptmeier, S. F., & Mittermaier, J. R. (2012). Fiscal competition over taxes and public inputs. Regional Science & Urban Economics, 42(3), 407–419.CrossRef
go back to reference Hindriks, J., & Nishimura, Y. (2015). A note on equilibrium leadership in tax competition models. Journal of Public Economics, 121, 66–68.CrossRef Hindriks, J., & Nishimura, Y. (2015). A note on equilibrium leadership in tax competition models. Journal of Public Economics, 121, 66–68.CrossRef
go back to reference Hindriks, J., Peralta, S., & Weber, S. (2008). Competing in taxes and investment under fiscal equalization. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 2392–2402.CrossRef Hindriks, J., Peralta, S., & Weber, S. (2008). Competing in taxes and investment under fiscal equalization. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 2392–2402.CrossRef
go back to reference Hoffmann M., & Rota Graziosi G. (2010). Endogenous timing game with non-monotonic reaction functions. CERDI, Etudes et Documents E, 2010, 17. Hoffmann M., & Rota Graziosi G. (2010). Endogenous timing game with non-monotonic reaction functions. CERDI, Etudes et Documents E, 2010, 17.
go back to reference Itaya, J., Okamura, M. & Yamaguchi, C. (2008). Are regional asymmetries detrimental to tax coordination in a repeated game setting? Journal of Public Economics, 92(12), 2403–2411.CrossRef Itaya, J., Okamura, M. & Yamaguchi, C. (2008). Are regional asymmetries detrimental to tax coordination in a repeated game setting? Journal of Public Economics, 92(12), 2403–2411.CrossRef
go back to reference Janeba, E., & Osterloh, S. (2013). Tax and the city: A theory of local tax competition. Journal of Public Economics, 106(6), 89–100.CrossRef Janeba, E., & Osterloh, S. (2013). Tax and the city: A theory of local tax competition. Journal of Public Economics, 106(6), 89–100.CrossRef
go back to reference Kempf, H., & Rota-Graziosi, G. (2010). Endogenizing leadership in tax competition. Journal of Public Economics, 94(9–10), 768–776.CrossRef Kempf, H., & Rota-Graziosi, G. (2010). Endogenizing leadership in tax competition. Journal of Public Economics, 94(9–10), 768–776.CrossRef
go back to reference Kempf, H., & Graziosi, G. R. (2010). Leadership in public good provision: A timing game perspective. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 12(4), 763–787.CrossRef Kempf, H., & Graziosi, G. R. (2010). Leadership in public good provision: A timing game perspective. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 12(4), 763–787.CrossRef
go back to reference Kumar M. S., & Quinn D. P. (2012). Globalization and corporate taxation. IMF Working Paper WP/12/252. Washington, DC: IMF Fiscal Affairs and Finance Department. Kumar M. S., & Quinn D. P. (2012). Globalization and corporate taxation. IMF Working Paper WP/12/252. Washington, DC: IMF Fiscal Affairs and Finance Department.
go back to reference Normann, H. T. (2002). Endogenous timing with incomplete information and with observable delay. Games and Economic Behavior, 39, 282–291.CrossRef Normann, H. T. (2002). Endogenous timing with incomplete information and with observable delay. Games and Economic Behavior, 39, 282–291.CrossRef
go back to reference Ogawa, H. (2013). Further analysis on leadership in tax competition: The role of capital ownership. International Tax & Public Finance, 20(3), 474–484.CrossRef Ogawa, H. (2013). Further analysis on leadership in tax competition: The role of capital ownership. International Tax & Public Finance, 20(3), 474–484.CrossRef
go back to reference Peralta, S. & van Ypersele, T. (2006). Coordination of capital taxation among asymmetric countries. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 36(6), 708–726.CrossRef Peralta, S. & van Ypersele, T. (2006). Coordination of capital taxation among asymmetric countries. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 36(6), 708–726.CrossRef
go back to reference Pieretti, P., & Zanaj, S. (2011). On tax competition, public goods provision and jurisdictions’ size. Journal of International Economics, 84, 124–130.CrossRef Pieretti, P., & Zanaj, S. (2011). On tax competition, public goods provision and jurisdictions’ size. Journal of International Economics, 84, 124–130.CrossRef
go back to reference Swank, D. (2016). Taxing choices: International competition, domestic institutions and the transformation of corporate tax policy. Journal of European Public Policy, 23(4), 571–603.CrossRef Swank, D. (2016). Taxing choices: International competition, domestic institutions and the transformation of corporate tax policy. Journal of European Public Policy, 23(4), 571–603.CrossRef
go back to reference Wang, Y. Q. (1999). Commodity taxes under fiscal competition: Stackelberg equilibrium and optimality. American Economic Review, 89(4), 974–981.CrossRef Wang, Y. Q. (1999). Commodity taxes under fiscal competition: Stackelberg equilibrium and optimality. American Economic Review, 89(4), 974–981.CrossRef
go back to reference Wildasin, D. E. (1988). Nash equilibrium in models of fiscal competition. Journal of Public Economics, 35, 229–240.CrossRef Wildasin, D. E. (1988). Nash equilibrium in models of fiscal competition. Journal of Public Economics, 35, 229–240.CrossRef
go back to reference Wilson, J. D. (1986). A theory of interregional tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 296–315.CrossRef Wilson, J. D. (1986). A theory of interregional tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 296–315.CrossRef
go back to reference Zissimos, B., & Wooders, M. (2008). Public good differentiation and the intensity of tax competition. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 1105–1121.CrossRef Zissimos, B., & Wooders, M. (2008). Public good differentiation and the intensity of tax competition. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 1105–1121.CrossRef
go back to reference Zodrow, G. R., & Mieszkowski, P. (1986). Pigou, tiebout, property taxation, and the underprovision of local public goods. Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 356–370.CrossRef Zodrow, G. R., & Mieszkowski, P. (1986). Pigou, tiebout, property taxation, and the underprovision of local public goods. Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 356–370.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Structural fund, endogenous move and commitment
Authors
Carsten Eckel
Yutao Han
Kate Hynes
Jin Zhang
Publication date
07-01-2021
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
International Tax and Public Finance / Issue 2/2021
Print ISSN: 0927-5940
Electronic ISSN: 1573-6970
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-020-09641-2

Other articles of this Issue 2/2021

International Tax and Public Finance 2/2021 Go to the issue

OriginalPaper

Targeting FDI