Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 1-2/2018

06-02-2018

Supermajority rule, the law of 1/n, and government spending: a synthesis

Author: Paul Pecorino

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 1-2/2018

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

I develop models in which a minimum winning coalition decides on the level of government spending, where the Coase theorem holds amongst members of the winning coalition. An increase in the supermajority requirement has potentially conflicting effects on spending. A higher requirement increases the tax price internalized by the minimum winning coalition, but also increases the number of districts included in this coalition. I develop separate models in which the spending in question consists of (i) a nonexcludable good, (ii) a distributive consumption good, (iii) infrastructure spending and (iv) a transfer payment. A supermajority rule has no effect on spending for nonexcludable goods and ambiguous effects on spending for distributive projects and infrastructure spending. An increased supermajority requirement does unambiguously reduce transfer spending. I also relate the supermajority rule to the law of 1/n. If the Coase Theorem holds and a minimum winning coalition forms, an increase in the number of districts n has precisely the same effect on overall expenditure as a decrease in the supermajority requirement. Thus, the ambiguous spending effects stemming from supermajority rule carry over into this version of the law of 1/n.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
Supermajority requirements can reduce spending in other ways by, for example, raising transaction costs and thereby reducing the chances that any agreement on new spending projects can be reached. While such a mechanism is potentially important, it lies beyond the scope of this paper. See Buchanan and Tullock (1962, pp. 85–116).
 
2
In some cases, non-excludability may arise from constitutional considerations requiring equal treatment of citizens. Note that throughout the analysis in this paper, districts are homogenous. If districts are heterogeneous, then a tuition subsidy might provide partially nonexcludable benefits if some districts send more students to college than others.
 
3
Lee (2016b) uses a similar model to motivate his empirical study of the interaction between a supermajority rule and a bicameral legislature.
 
4
Lee (2016a) considers a standard form of the law of 1/n in which the Coase theorem does not hold among members of the winning coalition. He then analyzes the interaction between the law of 1/n and supermajority rule. My point is that when the Coase theorem holds within the winning coalition, the law and 1/n and supermajority rule are equivalent, such that an increase in the number of districts is the same as a reduction in the supermajority requirement.
 
5
The results presented herein bear some relationship to the literature on enfranchisement. See, among others, Aumann et al. (1987) and Conley and Temimi (2001). Some resemblance also exists to the analysis in McGuire and Olson (1996).
 
6
Existing theoretical and empirical work analyzes how supermajority rule affects taxation. Knight (2000) finds that supermajority rules lead to lower taxes. Heckelman and Dougherty (2010) find that supermajority rules reduce the prevalence of taxes levied on narrow bases, which tend to be redistributive, but have no effect on more broad-based taxes. The result, presented in the current paper, that redistribution unambiguously declines with the supermajority requirement appears to be consistent with that empirical finding. Gradstein (1999) develops an intertemporal model in which a supermajority rule may be a mechanism credibly to commit to a low future tax rate.
 
7
Replacing n β in (1) with a more general functional form will have no effect on the results.
 
8
As noted previously, the result from this section is similar to the result derived in Lee et al. (2014), who do not derive their result from a utility function. Rather, the authors appeal to a reduced-form demand equation.
 
9
Infrastructure also is analyzed in McGuire and Olson (1996) in the context of their analysis of democracy and autocracy. A single “district” is assumed in their model, but what varies is the stake the ruling coalition has in aggregate output. By contrast, here infrastructure spending is directed to the district level, where it determines district level output.
 
10
Every single term in (13) is multiplied by n, so that term drops out of the expression.
 
11
This is the same expression as derived by Mueller (2003, p. 408) in a model of dictatorship with a single “district”. Also see Brennan and Buchanan (1980).
 
12
Deriving the expression in (15) requires a substitution from (14).
 
13
Equation (14) implies that (1  t) and F(gz) move in opposite directions. Thus, it seems unlikely that a sufficiently large increase in their product could offset the direct effect of an increase in z on the right-hand side of (15). Nevertheless, I am unable to verify that that intuition always holds in a comparative static exercise.
 
14
The theory of the law of 1/n has been amended in the subsequent literature. See, among others, Baron (1991), Chen and Malhotra (2007) and Primo and Snyder (2008). Chen and Malhotra amend the basic theory to take into account the fact that most legislatures are bicameral. The resulting empirical literature is quite large. See, among others, Bradbury and Crain (2001), Gilligan and Matsusaka (2001), Pettersson-Lidbom (2012), Crowley (2015) and Hankins (2015). While the empirical findings on the law of 1/n have been quite mixed, recent work has found either insignificant results (Bel et al. 2017) or a negative relationship between legislature size and spending (Höhmann 2017).
 
15
If it is believed that universalism prevails in spending decisions, supermajority rules are irrelevant. If universalism prevails, but the Coase theorem holds within the (universal) winning coalition, changing the number of districts will have no effect on spending.
 
16
Of course, the supermajority requirement can take on any value of z = 0.5 to z = 1.0, but under simple majority rule only specific values of z can be realized. Thus, three districts represent the equivalent of z = 0.67 and five districts are equivalent to z = 0.60, but z cannot take on values either above 0.67 or between 0.60 and 0.67 under simple majority rule.
 
17
Thus, we can think of the theory here as the law of 0.5(1 + 1/n).
 
18
This is discussed by Primo and Snyder (2008, pp. 479–480). Unlike the current paper, Primo and Snyder assume universalism. They show circumstances under which total spending can fall in the number of districts in a model with congestion and cost sharing.
 
19
When the legislative body is large we may have a violation of individual rationality if spending requests reflect a tax price of 1/n. Assume that taxes are lump sum and that district level benefits are given by the power function B(g= Ag α , where A > 0 and 0 < α < 1. Further suppose that spending requests reflect a tax price of 1/n and that universalism prevails. It is easy to show that all legislators are made worse off by voting in favor of a spending bill when the size of the legislature n > 1. If we impose individual rationality on legislators, the law of 1/n will be inoperative unless α is tiny or n is very small. This result suggests that the law of 1/n is possibly relevant only for legislative bodies the size of city councils. However, with a legislature that small, the Coase theorem should hold, rendering the traditional law of 1/n inoperative.
 
20
In personal communication, Höhmann has indicated that the results in Höhmann (2017), reporting a negative relationship between legislative size and spending, are not statistically different when at-large and district-based city councils are considered separately.
 
21
Higher transaction costs might be thought to reduce spending by making any deal less likely. However, transaction costs could raise spending if they make it more difficult to pin legislators to their reservation prices as the winning coalition is built. That could happen if informational asymmetries regarding legislator preferences are worse in a larger legislative body. Absent a formal model, however, it is difficult to know if such a mechanism increasing expenditures could indeed be operative.
 
22
Political parties are not present in my analysis, but are of obvious potential importance. In particular, a political imperative likely exists for including all members of the party in the winning coalition. Thus, in terms of the spending effects identified in this paper, a de facto supermajority rule may be in effect even if such a rule does not exist de jure. For example, if the majority party holds 55% of the seats in the legislative body, the winning coalition likely includes all of the members, implying that the coalition represents 55% of the districts and pays a tax price of $0.55 on the dollar. Thus, the predicted outcomes would be equivalent to those observed when z = 0.55.
 
23
Clearly 0.5 drops from (A.3), but I have kept it there to make the make the linkage with a supermajority rule of z = 0.5(1 + 1/n) clearer.
 
Literature
go back to reference Aumann, R. J., Kurz, M., & Neyman, A. (1987). Power and public goods. Journal of Economic Theory, 42, 108–127.CrossRef Aumann, R. J., Kurz, M., & Neyman, A. (1987). Power and public goods. Journal of Economic Theory, 42, 108–127.CrossRef
go back to reference Baqir, R. (2002). Districting and government overspending. Journal of Political Economy, 110, 1318–1354.CrossRef Baqir, R. (2002). Districting and government overspending. Journal of Political Economy, 110, 1318–1354.CrossRef
go back to reference Baron, D. P. (1991). Majoritarian incentives, pork barrel programs, and procedural control. American Journal of Political Science, 35, 57–90.CrossRef Baron, D. P. (1991). Majoritarian incentives, pork barrel programs, and procedural control. American Journal of Political Science, 35, 57–90.CrossRef
go back to reference Bel, G., Raudla, R., Rodrigues, M., & Tavares, A. F. (2017). These rules are made for spending: Testing and extending the law of 1/n. Public Choice, forthcoming. Bel, G., Raudla, R., Rodrigues, M., & Tavares, A. F. (2017). These rules are made for spending: Testing and extending the law of 1/n. Public Choice, forthcoming.
go back to reference Bradbury, J. C., & Crain, W. M. (2001). Legislative organization and government spending: Cross-country evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 82, 309–325.CrossRef Bradbury, J. C., & Crain, W. M. (2001). Legislative organization and government spending: Cross-country evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 82, 309–325.CrossRef
go back to reference Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (1980). The power to tax: Analytical foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (1980). The power to tax: Analytical foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Chen, J., & Malhotra, N. (2007). The law of K/N: The effect of chamber size on government spending in bicameral legislatures. American Political Science Review, 101, 657–676.CrossRef Chen, J., & Malhotra, N. (2007). The law of K/N: The effect of chamber size on government spending in bicameral legislatures. American Political Science Review, 101, 657–676.CrossRef
go back to reference Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRef Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRef
go back to reference Conley, J. P., & Temimi, A. (2001). Endogenous enfranchisement when groups’ preferences conflict. Journal of Political Economy, 109, 79–102.CrossRef Conley, J. P., & Temimi, A. (2001). Endogenous enfranchisement when groups’ preferences conflict. Journal of Political Economy, 109, 79–102.CrossRef
go back to reference Crowley, G. R. (2015). Local intergovernmental competition and the law of 1/n. Southern Economic Journal, 81, 742–768.CrossRef Crowley, G. R. (2015). Local intergovernmental competition and the law of 1/n. Southern Economic Journal, 81, 742–768.CrossRef
go back to reference Egger, P., & Koethenbuerger, M. (2010). Government spending and legislative organization: Quasi-experimental evidence from Germany. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2, 200–212. Egger, P., & Koethenbuerger, M. (2010). Government spending and legislative organization: Quasi-experimental evidence from Germany. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2, 200–212.
go back to reference Gilligan, T. W., & Matsusaka, J. G. (2001). Fiscal policy legislature size, and political parties: Evidence from state and local governments in the first half of the 20th century. National Tax Journal, 54, 57–82.CrossRef Gilligan, T. W., & Matsusaka, J. G. (2001). Fiscal policy legislature size, and political parties: Evidence from state and local governments in the first half of the 20th century. National Tax Journal, 54, 57–82.CrossRef
go back to reference Gradstein, M. (1999). Optimal taxation and fiscal constitution. Journal of Public Economics, 72, 471–485.CrossRef Gradstein, M. (1999). Optimal taxation and fiscal constitution. Journal of Public Economics, 72, 471–485.CrossRef
go back to reference Hankins, W. B. (2015). Government spending, shocks, and the role of legislature size: Evidence from the American states. Social Science Quarterly, 96, 1059–1070.CrossRef Hankins, W. B. (2015). Government spending, shocks, and the role of legislature size: Evidence from the American states. Social Science Quarterly, 96, 1059–1070.CrossRef
go back to reference Heckelman, J. C., & Dougherty, K. L. (2010). Majority rule versus supermajority rules: Their effects on narrow and broad taxes. Public Finance Review, 38, 738–761.CrossRef Heckelman, J. C., & Dougherty, K. L. (2010). Majority rule versus supermajority rules: Their effects on narrow and broad taxes. Public Finance Review, 38, 738–761.CrossRef
go back to reference Höhmann, D. (2017). The effect of legislature size on public spending: Evidence from a regression discontinuity design. Public Choice, 173, 345–367.CrossRef Höhmann, D. (2017). The effect of legislature size on public spending: Evidence from a regression discontinuity design. Public Choice, 173, 345–367.CrossRef
go back to reference Knight, B. G. (2000). Supermajority voting requirements for tax increases: Evidence from the states. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 41–67.CrossRef Knight, B. G. (2000). Supermajority voting requirements for tax increases: Evidence from the states. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 41–67.CrossRef
go back to reference Lee, D. (2016a). Supermajority rule and the law of 1/n. Public Choice, 164, 251–274.CrossRef Lee, D. (2016a). Supermajority rule and the law of 1/n. Public Choice, 164, 251–274.CrossRef
go back to reference Lee, D. (2016b). Supermajority rule and bicameral bargaining. Public Choice, 169, 53–75.CrossRef Lee, D. (2016b). Supermajority rule and bicameral bargaining. Public Choice, 169, 53–75.CrossRef
go back to reference Lee, D., Borcherding, T. E., & Kang, Y. (2014). Public spending and the paradox of supermajority rule. Southern Economic Journal, 80, 614–632.CrossRef Lee, D., Borcherding, T. E., & Kang, Y. (2014). Public spending and the paradox of supermajority rule. Southern Economic Journal, 80, 614–632.CrossRef
go back to reference McGuire, M. C., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 72–96. McGuire, M. C., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 72–96.
go back to reference Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Pettersson-Lidbom, P. (2012). Does the size of the legislature affect the size of government? Evidence from two natural experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 96, 269–278.CrossRef Pettersson-Lidbom, P. (2012). Does the size of the legislature affect the size of government? Evidence from two natural experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 96, 269–278.CrossRef
go back to reference Primo, D. M., & Snyder, J. M. (2008). Distributive politics and the law of 1/n. Journal of Politics, 70, 477–486.CrossRef Primo, D. M., & Snyder, J. M. (2008). Distributive politics and the law of 1/n. Journal of Politics, 70, 477–486.CrossRef
go back to reference Riker, W. H. (1962). The theory of political coalitions. New Haven: Yale University Press. Riker, W. H. (1962). The theory of political coalitions. New Haven: Yale University Press.
go back to reference Tullock, G. (1959). Problems of majority voting. Journal of Political Economy, 67, 571–579.CrossRef Tullock, G. (1959). Problems of majority voting. Journal of Political Economy, 67, 571–579.CrossRef
go back to reference Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 642–664.CrossRef Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 642–664.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Supermajority rule, the law of 1/n, and government spending: a synthesis
Author
Paul Pecorino
Publication date
06-02-2018
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 1-2/2018
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0512-x

Other articles of this Issue 1-2/2018

Public Choice 1-2/2018 Go to the issue