Skip to main content
Top

2020 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

5. Taking Stock: Monetary and Banking Policy in the Second Reign

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The chapter analyzes the main contours of monetary and banking policy over the whole 1850–89 period. It starts by discussing the limits to the most widely used monetary data for the period, provided by Peláez and Suzigan’s 1976 book. Specie and liabilities (deposits and vales) of the non-corporate banking system are shown to have constituted, in certain periods, a significant part of the money supply in nineteenth-century Brazil. Private banks (casas bancárias) operated, largely, unsupervised by the government, unlike joint-stock banks. Most contemporaries deemed notes issued by the latter, together with Treasury paper, as the main determinants of the rate of exchange. Part of the reason why the Brazilian government tended to restrict the operation of banks of issue was the concern that an excessive amount of notes in circulation would cause the milréis to depreciate. The political economy of the exchange rate—with imperial finances benefiting from a stable and appreciated milréis—in conjunction with the preeminence of orthodox views on monetary doctrine, partly explain the obstinacy with which the Brazilian government had pursued money policies in the period.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
Friedman and Schwartz (1963).
 
2
Notable examples are Cavalcanti (1890, 1893), Wileman (1896), Calógeras (1910), Ortigão (1914), Neuhaus (1975) and, more recently, Franco (2017).
 
3
Peláez and Suzigan (1976).
 
4
This appears to have been the case in 1853, when the money supply (M1), measured by the sum of notes held by the public and demand deposits, was in the order of 47,000 contos and ‘close to 30,000 contos in specie was to be found in the Brazilian market’ (Calógeras 1910, p. 110). The second half of the 1850s witnessed the largest amount of specie struck by the Brazilian mint, with 21,000 contos in gold coins and 5800 contos in silver coins put into circulation between 1854 and 1859. This comprised approximately 30% of the average outstanding circulation of notes (issued by both the Treasury and private banks) at the time, and an equal share of the average money supply as measured by notes held by the public and demand deposits. Total coinage of gold pieces in the Brazilian mint between 1850 and 1888 amounted to 45.7 thousand contos, while another 20.9 thousand contos in silver coins were put into circulation in the same period. Copper and silver coins, used as small change and issued from 1868 and 1872 onward, respectively, totaled 7.6 thousand contos. Figures in Cavalcanti (1893, vol. 2, p. 327). Unfortunately, an annual series for the stock of specie in circulation (as opposed to specie coined at the mint) is not available. Throughout the period under study here, specie was often driven out of circulation, being either exported or hoarded. This precludes any attempt to arrive at a more precise estimate of the monetary base that would result from adding figures for specie in circulation (including British sovereigns and other foreign coins, which were legal tender) to the published series for notes issued by the government and issuing banks. For a discussion, Abreu and Lago (2001, pp. 363–71).
 
5
In connection to this, Schulz mentions yet another possible correction to the Peláez and Suzigan estimates of the money supply, but relating to the final year of the Empire (1889). According to the author, the exchange-rate parity then achieved provided for the entry in circulation of the equivalent of £ 9 million in specie, or one-third of the money supply at the time. He goes on to cite page 336 in Cavalvanti (1890) as his source, although the latter does not provide this figure but, solely, estimates of gold coins minted in Brazil in different points in time—not specie in circulation. Schulz (2013, p. 164). Still, fragmentary evidence suggests that there was, indeed, an increase in the volume of metal coins in circulation (and, therefore, of the money supply) in Brazil in 1888 and 1889. Over these two years, there was a net inflow of £ 2.9 million in silver and gold coins from Britain, part of which was minted into Brazilian currency and put into circulation. The Brazilian mint produced just over 4.5 thousand contos in silver coins in 1888 and 1889, valued at £ 487,000. There are no detailed data on gold coins minted in Brazil in those two years, although Cavalcanti (1893, vol. 2, p. 315) provides a figure for 1.9 thousand contos (equivalent to £ 205,600) in gold pieces coined in 1888–9. Data on specie imported from Britain in Lago (1982). Coins minted in Brazil in Amato et al. (2008).
 
6
The Brazilian population roughly doubled between 1850 and 1889, from an estimated 7.3 million to 14.3 million according to the 1890 census. Brasil, IBGE (1990, pp. 33–4).
 
7
For the 1870–1913 period, Catão (1992b) provides a carefully constructed wholesale price index.
 
8
As discussed in the text, this is, admittedly, a restrictive definition of the monetary base, as it leaves out metallic currency in circulation and vales (promissory notes) issued by a number of agents at the time, including private banks, companies and, even, individuals.
 
9
At its peak, in December 1861, notes issued by the banks created by government decree in 1857–8 reached 13.5 thousand contos, or 16.5% of total notes in circulation. Thereafter—and because of their incapacity to comply with the rules set out by the 1860 Law of Impediments—, their combined issues declined significantly and would constitute but a marginal share of total notes in circulation (see Table A1 in the Appendix).
 
10
Chapters 2, 3 and 4 present this history in detail.
 
11
This includes the issue of 40.6 thousand contos in 1866, as its main objective was the acquisition of the Bank of Brazil’s metallic reserves in order to help finance expenditures linked to the war against Paraguay.
 
12
For details, see Chap. 4 in this book and Summerhill (2015, ch. 4).
 
13
Figures on funded domestic debt outstanding in Levy (1995). Data originally published in milréis and converted to pounds sterling at the average monthly rate of exchange at each point in time over the whole series.
 
14
Average budget deficits between 1880–1 and 1885–6 exceeded 22,000 contos annually. See Table A6 in the Appendix.
 
15
Figures for apólices in circulation refer to March 1866 and March 1889. Levy (1995, pp. 243–9).
 
16
This figure does not include the 1889 conversion loan.
 
17
For Mauá’s views on monetary matters, Fernandes (1974). Given the weight of receipts from coffee in total exports under the Empire (roughly 50%), much attention has been given to studying its influence in determining the exchange rate in the period. In this regard, Furtado’s classic contribution, by pointing out the instability in the international demand for exports from primary-producing countries, highlights the serious consequences that sudden shifts in demand would have on export earnings from the periphery and, hence, the exchange rate of those countries. Furtado (1970, pp. 164 ff.). Furtado actually reinforces an argument made earlier by Wileman, relating oscillations in the value of the milréis and the price of coffee. Wileman (1896). Later, this relationship was challenged by Delfim Netto (1979, p. 26), who concluded that ‘in the long run the exchange rate was relatively little affected by the price cycles (of coffee)’. Since the 1980s, there were renewed attempts to analyze the main determinants of the exchange rate in imperial Brazil. Most of these works sought to test the extent to which the foreign value of the milréis followed changes in coffee prices, monetary policy, capital flows, the terms of trade or a combination of these variables. The results are inconclusive, but most of the contributions tend to indicate that both domestic influences—linked to coffee output, money supply, and wage setting behavior—as well as international ones, via foreign lending and the international demand for Brazil’s exports, had a bearing on the country’s exchange rate. See Cardoso (1981), Franco (1986), Fishlow (1987), and Catão (1992a, chapter VI). On the difficulties in estimating the main determinants of the exchange rate in late nineteenth-century Brazil, Franco (1991, pp. 77–80).
 
18
For a similar discussion in connection with the political economy of the exchange rate during the First Republic (1889–1930), Triner (2000).
 
19
Topik (1994).
 
20
Session of 9 November 1864, in ACE, p. 404.
 
21
Foreign investors’ concerns regarding the exchange rate were thus expressed: ‘(...) if the question be asked what is hum milréis, the integer of the Brazilian currency, no one can give a precise reply. It not only depends, like gold, on its scarcity or abundance in the domestic market, but on the clearness or obscurity of the foreign and domestic political horizons, and on the weather, and on the chance of getting in crops unaffected by blight and the numerous contingencies to which agriculture is exposed. A difficulty in the River Plate, or a succession of short coffee crops, would again reduce the value of the milréis to half or less of its value today. Nothing but the unusual profits which are expected when unusual risks are concerned can tempt an investor to convert hard cash into the paper currency of Brazil’. Parliamentary Papers 1875, LXXV, Report by Consul Lennon-Hunt on the Trade and Commerce of Rio de Janeiro for the Year 1873, p. 309.
 
22
In the case of coffee, Brazilian exports constituted a significant share of the world total and, hence, exercised considerable influence on the world price of the commodity. For a discussion, Abreu and Tamega (2005).
 
23
The above discussion of the political economy of exchange rate and monetary policy is open to a few qualifications. The first point concerns the relative sensitivity of tradable producers to exchange-rate movements, which, in turn, depends on the price elasticity of demand for their products. In the Brazilian case, the coffee sector was characterized by quasi-monopoly power, coupled with a low price elasticity of demand for its product. This feature enabled coffee producers to weather phases of exchange-rate appreciation better than other exporters. Also, foreign investors, when bringing capital to Brazil, would initially benefit from a depreciated milréis. The income stream from those very investments, on the other hand, would be greater in foreign currency terms the more appreciated the rate of exchange. Finally, in a fixed-rate regime such as the gold standard, divisions might arise within a group of exporters if there is mounting pressure for a competitive devaluation of the currency. In this case, the policy decision will involve choosing between those with long-term contracts, that is, whose sale prices in foreign currency might have been set way beforehand—and who will tend to be against the instability that devaluation introduces—and other exporters who would gain immediate competitiveness as a result of a currency devaluation. Frieden (1994, pp. 85–6).
 
24
See, for example, the debates in the 1878 agricultural congress held in Rio, reprinted as Anais do Congresso Agrícola (1988).
 
25
This is what appears to be implied by Levy and Andrade, when they contend that financing of the agricultural sector via factors (comissários) ‘reasserted the dominance of circulation over production, ensuring the control of the latter by mercantile capital’. Levy and Andrade (1993, p. 25).
 
26
Cf. Silva Netto (1865, Introduction).
 
27
Speech given by Minister of Finance Torres Homem in 1859, cited in Andrada (1923, p. 90).
 
28
Sweigart (1987).
 
29
See also Lago (2019) on the difficulty faced by creditors in foreclosing rural property in imperial Brazil.
 
30
This major obstacle in the way of the development of a long-term market for rural loans was clearly diagnosed by a contemporary. See the chapter “Do Crédito Rural e Sistema Hipotecário” (“On Rural Credit and the Mortgage System”), in Franco (1984, pp. 111–7).
 
31
On the falling prices for slaves in Brazil as contemporaries perceived the inevitability of abolition (without compensation), Mello (1978).
 
32
This “liquidity consciousness” was reinforced by the recurrent panics and crises that characterized the nineteenth century. Fears of a potential mismatch between the maturities of bank assets and liabilities has also been identified as a source of the short-termism of which nineteenth-century British banks have often been accused. Collins (1991, pp. 16–7).
 
33
It has been suggested that a further reason for the relatively high cost of credit in nineteenth-century Brazil was its underdeveloped banking system. The latter, in turn, stemmed in part from the strict control exercised by the government, including the Council of State, over the entry of new players in the market. Ultimately, political power concentrated in the hands of the Executive was used to shield from competition incumbent banks (including the Bank of Brazil), whose boards of directors often included national political officeholders. For an elaboration, Summerhill (2015, ch. 7).
 
34
The original argument is from Gerschenkron (1962, pp. 13 ff).
 
35
Session of 5 June, in ASI 1858, Tome II, p. 16.
 
36
Session of 21 May, in ASI 1858, Tome I, pp. 244–5.
 
37
Indeed, this was perfectly understood by some contemporaries. Commenting on the government’s plans to allow the Banco Commercial do Rio de Janeiro and Mauá’s Bank of Brazil to increase their issue of vales, in order to alleviate the monetary pressure felt in 1853, deputy Bandeira de Mello noted that the measure was fruitless: ‘if the bills offered for discount do not have credit, if they are not sufficiently guaranteed, banks will not discount them, for banks cannot compensate for the lack of credit’. Session of 13 June, in ACD 1853, Tome II, p. 181.
 
38
The first Bank of Brazil was created in October 1808 and its operations started one year later. Throughout its twenty-year life, it was beset by demands from the State that, ultimately, led to its closure and a protracted process of liquidation, running from 1829 to 1835. For details, Franco (1984, ch. 1), Vieira (1962), Peláez (1975), and Gambi (2017).
 
39
Articles 9 and 10 of the said decree determined that ‘the establishment of any corporation with the purpose of engaging in banking operations shall only be authorized once a quarter of its shares have been subscribed; however, if this total has not been realized within the time marked by its statutes, it shall be dissolved (…)’.
 
40
Speech delivered in the Chamber of Deputies on 20 June 1853, cited in Franco and Pacheco (1979, Vol. II, p. 106).
 
41
Speech delivered in the Chamber of Deputies on 18 June 1853, cited in Franco and Pacheco (1979, Vol. II, pp. 101–2).
 
42
This was the opinion expressed by a Mr. Robert Clinton Wright at the enquiry into the 1857 commercial crisis. See Relatorio da Commissão de Inquerito de 1859 (undated, pp. 111–2).
 
43
Parliamentary Papers 1860, LXV, Report by Mr. Morgan, British Consul in Bahia, on the Trade of that Port for the Year 1858, p. 2.
 
44
In fact, official recognition of the role of deposits as part of the money supply would only come about when the government passed Decree 3339 (10 November 1864), which stipulated that deposits held in the Bank of Brazil in current account would henceforth count as part of its issues. The same rule would apply to three-fourths of total interest-bearing deposits. Cavalcanti (1893, Vol. 2, p. 279). In the United States, the procedure to include bank deposits with note issues when setting specie requirements was pioneered by the 1842 Louisiana banking act. Hammond (1957, p. 695).
 
45
‘In my opinion, receipts (...) issued by the bankers who failed represented an actual issue in disguise, one thousand times more dangerous and damaging to the public than those made by banks; because, although they acted as currency in commercial transactions, they had no limit whatsoever, except the individual credit of those who signed them; it was but an illicit means to circumvent the dispositions of the law of 22 August 1860’. Statement made by Sebastião Ferreira Soares for the inquiry into the 1864 crisis, in Relatorio da Comissão de Inquerito de 1864 (1865, Annex C, Part I, p. 51).
 
46
This point serves to highlight the fact that to focus exclusively on traditional monetary aggregates to establish the degree of liquidity in the economy can be misleading, as argued by Kindleberger (1996, pp. 49–51). For example, Sweigart remarks that in 1865 ‘a Rio merchant had estimated that coffee factors had lent planters as much as 90,000 contos, a sum only slightly less than the total currency held by the public over the entire country. Not all of the planter drafts ended up in banks; drafts accepted by well-known planters and factors circulated as currency throughout the coffee provinces’. Sweigart (1987, p. 135). It is difficult to assess the extent to which planter drafts behaved as money, as well as the amount of outstanding obligations of this nature in other points in time. Still, their sheer volume in 1865 should add a measure of caution to any analysis of monetary trends based exclusively on aggregates such as M1 or M2. Goldsmith (1986) puts the total amount of deposits held at private banks in 1864 at somewhere between 25–50 thousand contos (see Table 5.1). When these other components are added to the estimates of the money supply provided by M1 and M2, it becomes clear that the Brazilian economy was not suffering from a monetary crunch in the early 1860s.
 
47
On the free banking experience of Scotland, White (1984, 1991).
 
48
It has been remarked that at that time ‘only in England and Scotland were joint-stock companies generally subject to unlimited liability. In America, as well as on the Continent, the principle of limited liability became the general rule right from the beginning’. Cf. Smith (1936, p. 37, footnote 2).
 
49
Coleção das Leis do Império do Brasil, Tome 11, Part 1, 1850, p. 107.
 
50
Barman points out that Brazil was not alone at the time in making incorporation depend on official approval, as the same applied to France under its 1807 Commercial Code. See Barman (1981). Free incorporation was not introduced in the North German Confederation and Austria until 1870 and 1899, respectively. Cameron (1972, p. 17).
 
51
In a way, then, joint-stock issuing banks were invested with a double privilege, that of limited liability—which benefited shareholders—and that of issuing notes.
 
52
As seen in Chap. 3, the 1860 Law of Impediments imposed restrictions not only on the operation of joint-stock banks, but on corporations in general. Additionally, it strengthened the provisions of the Commercial Code, by laying down for the first time clear penalties (in the shape of fines) on those responsible for failing to obtain a charter before embarking on commercial ventures (Art. 2, para 1).
 
53
As expected, this provision could cause problems, as in the case of a respectable family from Rio, left stranded in a train station in the outskirts of the city, for want of legal tender currency to pay the fare. As it turned out, all they had in their pockets was a substantial amount of notes issued by the Banco Commercial & Agrícola, which the company refused to accept. This episode was mentioned during debates held in the Chamber of Deputies. See session of 29 May, in ACD 1858, Tome I, p. 149.
 
54
Minister of Finance Ferraz criticized the banks’ issues of notes of small denomination on the grounds that they fell into the hands of the lower classes, who used them in daily transactions. This subjected the paper to wear and tear, when not total loss, something that would ultimately benefit the issuing bank, who would be free from redeeming them. RMF 1859, p. 69.
 
55
This prompted the adoption of Article 4 of Decree 2685 (10 November 1860), which imposed on the Bank of Brazil the requirement to withdraw from circulation notes of smaller denomination, should it fail to resume (gold) convertibility within six months.
 
56
Similar problems arose in the South of the United States, where states struggled to regulate the private issue of so-called shinplasters. Schweikart (1987, p. 115).
 
57
Throughout most of the period under discussion here, import duties were not collected on an ad valorem basis. Instead, they consisted of a fixed amount (a lump sum) charged on “official values” of each merchandise as detailed in the tariff schedule. In the presence of exchange-rate swings, the market value of a given item could differ—at times, markedly—from “official values”, causing importers to face tariff rates that were quite distinct from what they anticipated (and, sometimes, from the government’s original intent). For a discussion, Villela (2005).
 
58
At the time, the degree of protection afforded to import-substituting industries by a depreciated milréis, as well as its influence on the imports of capital goods (and, hence, domestic investment), were not significant issues in the political economy of the exchange rate.
 
59
An oitava corresponded to 1/8 of an ounce, or 3.586 grams.
 
60
This was the third time the legal parity of the milréis was changed. Historically, the par rate of exchange had been 67.5d. The 27d/1$000 rate replaced the previous parity established in 1833 (at 43.5d/1$000) and would thereafter—and well into the republican period—constitute a veritable “Holy Grail”, a mythical rate of exchange that would be doggedly pursued by the government.
 
61
In addition, as shown in Figure 5.5, in the case of the smaller issuing banks, note issues could be partly backed by shares of companies enjoying profit (dividend) guarantees from the government.
 
62
On the British monetary controversies, Viner (1937) and Glasner (1989, 1992).
 
63
Saes (1986) and Andrade (1987).
 
64
Major politicians identified with the metalistas were Angelo Muniz da Silva Ferraz (President of the Council of Ministers and Minister of Finance from August 1859 to March 1861), Paulino José Soares de Sousa (Visconde de Uruguai) and José Maria da Silva Paranhos (Visconde de Rio Branco). With Souza Franco’s ideas sided Irineu Evangelista de Souza (Mauá), João Lustosa da Cunha Paranaguá and José Antonio Saraiva, to name the most important. Andrada (1923, p. 112).
 
65
The 1856 edition of Gilbart’s 1827 book A Practical Treatise on Banking was translated by L. J. de Oliveira e Castro as Tractado Practico de Bancos (Rio de Janeiro: Garnier, 1859, 3 vols.). I am indebted to Carlos Gabriel Guimarães for drawing my attention to the Brazilian edition of the Gilbart book.
 
66
This similarity was not lost on a contemporary author (and professor at the Recife Law School), who remarked that ‘every one of our Ministers of Finance (…), advocates of monopoly or plurality of banks, from Torres Homem to Souza Franco, all of them are blind admirers of gold’. Cf. Milet (1875, p. 25).
 
67
See, for example, Saes (1986, Part I), and Andrade (1987).
 
68
For a similar contemporary defense of plurality of issue with convertibility of (non-legal tender) banknotes, Hoyer (1880, pp. 38–40).
 
69
Andrade (1987).
 
70
An early example is Normano (1935, p. 190).
 
71
Debate held on 2 June, in ASI 1858, Tome II, p. 14.
 
72
His participation in the efforts to prop up the rate of exchange in the wake of the 1857 crisis bear witness to this. For details, see Chap. 2.
 
73
Still, this did not stop him from operating in Uruguay, where notes issued by the Mauá Bank were redeemable in specie.
 
74
Mauá’s defense of inconvertible banknotes had already been made public much earlier, in his testimony to the enquiry into the 1857 commercial crisis. See Relatorio da Commissão de Inquerito de 1859 (undated, Annex A, p. 96).
 
75
See Banco do Brasil, Parecer Apresentado á Assembléa (1861).
 
76
Ibid., pp. 14–5.
 
77
Ibid., pp. 16–7. As noted by many authors, the gold standard operated differently in the countries at the center and those in the periphery of the world economy, the latter being frequently hit by convertibility crises, devaluations, and internal dislocations. In effect, borrowing countries were not as capable as core ones to control the rate of their capital imports and exports. For the periphery, buoyant economic activity led to merchandise imports picking-up and, eventually, to a trade deficit. In the early stages of the cycle, this trade deficit would be financed by (foreign) capital inflows which, by their inherent volatility, were bound to return to their countries of origin at news of panics and the subsequent increases in Bank (of England) Rate. Given the lagged response of import demand to credit conditions, this capital flight could result in severe reserve losses that, under the gold standard, would bring about an equally strong monetary contraction. Depending on the magnitudes involved, that is, the size of the gold drain relative to the domestic monetary base, the ensuing deflation could be considerable. In short, capital flows tended to be pro-cyclical, that is, they would increase in boom times and as soon as the slump set in (but merchandise imports were still on the rise), they would return to the centers from where they had originated. This would aggravate the natural instability that derived from the periphery’s frequent reliance on the exports of one or two primary products. For an elaboration of this argument, Ford (1962). For a discussion of these issues as applied to early twentieth-century Brazil, Fritsch (1988). Furtado had already made this point in his classic 1959 book, when describing the economy of nineteenth-century Brazil and its incapacity to adapt to the rules of the gold standard in the period. See Furtado (1970, ch. 27).
 
78
Soares’ reference to “exports in excess of imports” (a trade surplus), as he himself elaborates in his book, would refer in modern parlance to the need for a balance of payments surplus if gold and silver coins were to be retained domestically.
 
79
Soares’ Notas Estatísticas was originally published in 1860. Mauá’s and Soares’ advocacy of paper currency, as already noted, was highly atypical in a world convinced of the superiority of the gold standard. In this respect, they were close to the Birmingham economists of the nineteenth century, who backed inconvertible paper money as a means to enhance employment in times of distress in their city. In a debate in the Senate, Jequitinhonha stated that Souza Franco’s opinions in favor of plurality of issue were akin to those of the Birmingham school, ‘whose theories had been proven false’. See ASI 1858, Tome I, p. 244. On the opposition of the Birmingham economists to deflation and the gold standard, Fetter (1965, pp. 177–80).
 
80
These events are examined in detail in Chaps. 2 and 3.
 
Literature
go back to reference Abreu, Marcelo de P., and Luiz A.C. do Lago. 2001. Property Rights and the Fiscal and Financial Systems in Brazil: Colonial Heritage and Imperial Period. In Transferring Wealth and Power from the Old to the New World: Monetary and Fiscal Institutions in the 17th Through the 19th Centuries, ed. Michael D. Bordo and Roberto Cortés-Conde, 327–377. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Abreu, Marcelo de P., and Luiz A.C. do Lago. 2001. Property Rights and the Fiscal and Financial Systems in Brazil: Colonial Heritage and Imperial Period. In Transferring Wealth and Power from the Old to the New World: Monetary and Fiscal Institutions in the 17th Through the 19th Centuries, ed. Michael D. Bordo and Roberto Cortés-Conde, 327–377. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Abreu, Marcelo de P. and Felipe Tamega (2005). Market Power and Commodity Prices: Brazil, Chile and the United States, 1820s–1930. Texto para Discussão, Departamento de Economia PUC-Rio, No. 511. Abreu, Marcelo de P. and Felipe Tamega (2005). Market Power and Commodity Prices: Brazil, Chile and the United States, 1820s–1930. Texto para Discussão, Departamento de Economia PUC-Rio, No. 511.
go back to reference Amato, Claudio P., Irlei S. das Neves, and Arnaldo Russo. 2008. Livro de Moedas do Brasil. São Paulo: Artgraph. Amato, Claudio P., Irlei S. das Neves, and Arnaldo Russo. 2008. Livro de Moedas do Brasil. São Paulo: Artgraph.
go back to reference Anais do Congresso Agrícola do Rio de Janeiro 1878 (1988). Rio de Janeiro, Fundação Casa de Rui Barbosa. Anais do Congresso Agrícola do Rio de Janeiro 1878 (1988). Rio de Janeiro, Fundação Casa de Rui Barbosa.
go back to reference Banco do Brasil. 1861. Parecer Apresentado á Assembléa Geral dos Accionistas do Banco do Brasil pela Commissão Especial Eleita em 2 de Maio de 1861. Rio de Janeiro: Villeneuve. Banco do Brasil. 1861. Parecer Apresentado á Assembléa Geral dos Accionistas do Banco do Brasil pela Commissão Especial Eleita em 2 de Maio de 1861. Rio de Janeiro: Villeneuve.
go back to reference Barman, Roderick J. 1981. Business and Government in Imperial Brazil: the experience of Viscount Mauá. Journal of Latin American Studies 13 (2): 239–264.CrossRef Barman, Roderick J. 1981. Business and Government in Imperial Brazil: the experience of Viscount Mauá. Journal of Latin American Studies 13 (2): 239–264.CrossRef
go back to reference Brasil, Câmara dos Deputados, Annaes da Camara dos Deputados, 1850–89. Brasil, Câmara dos Deputados, Annaes da Camara dos Deputados, 1850–89.
go back to reference Brasil, Leis e Decretos, Coleção de Leis e Decretos, various volumes. Brasil, Leis e Decretos, Coleção de Leis e Decretos, various volumes.
go back to reference Brasil, IBGE. (1990). Estatísticas Históricas do Brasil. Vol. 3, 2nd ed. (séries econômicas, demográficas e sociais, 1550–1985). Rio de Janeiro: IBGE. Brasil, IBGE. (1990). Estatísticas Históricas do Brasil. Vol. 3, 2nd ed. (séries econômicas, demográficas e sociais, 1550–1985). Rio de Janeiro: IBGE.
go back to reference Brasil, Ministério da Fazenda, Balanços da Receita e Despeza do Imperio, various years. Brasil, Ministério da Fazenda, Balanços da Receita e Despeza do Imperio, various years.
go back to reference ———. Proposta e Relatorio Apresentados á Assembléa-Geral Legislativa Pelo Ministro e Secretario d’Estado dos Negócios da Fazenda, various years. ———. Proposta e Relatorio Apresentados á Assembléa-Geral Legislativa Pelo Ministro e Secretario d’Estado dos Negócios da Fazenda, various years.
go back to reference Brasil, Senado, Annaes do Senado do Império do Brasil, varios years. Brasil, Senado, Annaes do Senado do Império do Brasil, varios years.
go back to reference Calógeras, João P. 1910. La Politique Monetaire du Brésil. Rio de Janeiro: Imprensa Nacional. Calógeras, João P. 1910. La Politique Monetaire du Brésil. Rio de Janeiro: Imprensa Nacional.
go back to reference Cameron, Rondo, ed. 1972. Banking and Economic Development: Some Lessons of History. New York: Oxford University Press. Cameron, Rondo, ed. 1972. Banking and Economic Development: Some Lessons of History. New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Cameron, Rondo, et al., eds. 1967. Banking in the Early Stages of Industrialization. New York: Oxford University Press. Cameron, Rondo, et al., eds. 1967. Banking in the Early Stages of Industrialization. New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Cardoso, Eliane A. 1981. Desvalorizações Cambiais, Indústria e Café: Brasil, 1862–1906. Revista Brasileira de Economia 35 (2): 85–106. Cardoso, Eliane A. 1981. Desvalorizações Cambiais, Indústria e Café: Brasil, 1862–1906. Revista Brasileira de Economia 35 (2): 85–106.
go back to reference Catão, Luis A. V. 1992a. The Failure of Export-Led Growth in Brazil and Mexico, c. 1870–1930. Research Papers, No. 31, Institute of Latin American Studies, University of London. Catão, Luis A. V. 1992a. The Failure of Export-Led Growth in Brazil and Mexico, c. 1870–1930. Research Papers, No. 31, Institute of Latin American Studies, University of London.
go back to reference ———. 1992b. A New Wholesale Price Index for Brazil During the Period 1870–1913. Revista Brasileira de Economia 46 (4): 519–533. ———. 1992b. A New Wholesale Price Index for Brazil During the Period 1870–1913. Revista Brasileira de Economia 46 (4): 519–533.
go back to reference Cavalcanti, Amaro. 1890. Resenha Financeira do Ex-Império do Brasil em 1889. Rio de Janeiro: Imprensa Nacional. Cavalcanti, Amaro. 1890. Resenha Financeira do Ex-Império do Brasil em 1889. Rio de Janeiro: Imprensa Nacional.
go back to reference ———. 1893. O Meio Circulante Nacional. Rio de Janeiro: Imprensa Nacional. ———. 1893. O Meio Circulante Nacional. Rio de Janeiro: Imprensa Nacional.
go back to reference Collins, Michael. 1991. Banks and Industrial Finance in Britain, 1800–1939. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Collins, Michael. 1991. Banks and Industrial Finance in Britain, 1800–1939. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference da Silva Netto, A. 1865. Formula Mais Effectiva para a Solução dos Nossos Bancos de Emissão. Rio de Janeiro: Typographia Perseverança. da Silva Netto, A. 1865. Formula Mais Effectiva para a Solução dos Nossos Bancos de Emissão. Rio de Janeiro: Typographia Perseverança.
go back to reference de Andrada, Antonio Carlos R. 1923. Bancos de Emissão no Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: Edições Leite Ribeiro. de Andrada, Antonio Carlos R. 1923. Bancos de Emissão no Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: Edições Leite Ribeiro.
go back to reference de Andrade, Ana Maria R. 1987. 1864: conflito entre metalistas e pluralistas. Unpublished MSc. dissertation, Universidade Federal do Rio de Janeiro. de Andrade, Ana Maria R. 1987. 1864: conflito entre metalistas e pluralistas. Unpublished MSc. dissertation, Universidade Federal do Rio de Janeiro.
go back to reference de Mauá, Barão. 1942. O Meio Circulante no Brasil. In Visconde de Mauá, Autobiografia (Exposição aos Credores e ao Público) seguida de O Meio Circulante no Brasil, ed. C. Ganns, 2nd ed., 93–309. Rio de Janeiro: Zélio Valverde. (originally published in 1878). de Mauá, Barão. 1942. O Meio Circulante no Brasil. In Visconde de Mauá, Autobiografia (Exposição aos Credores e ao Público) seguida de O Meio Circulante no Brasil, ed. C. Ganns, 2nd ed., 93–309. Rio de Janeiro: Zélio Valverde. (originally published in 1878).
go back to reference de Mello, Pedro C. 1978. Aspectos Econômicos da Organização do Trabalho da Economia Cafeeira do Rio de Janeiro, 1850–1888. Revista Brasileira de Economia 32 (1): 19–67. de Mello, Pedro C. 1978. Aspectos Econômicos da Organização do Trabalho da Economia Cafeeira do Rio de Janeiro, 1850–1888. Revista Brasileira de Economia 32 (1): 19–67.
go back to reference de Saes, Flavio M. 1986. Crédito e Bancos no Desenvolvimento da Economia Paulista, 1850–1930. São Paulo: IPE/USP. de Saes, Flavio M. 1986. Crédito e Bancos no Desenvolvimento da Economia Paulista, 1850–1930. São Paulo: IPE/USP.
go back to reference Delfim Netto, Antonio. 1979. O Problema do Café no Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: Editora da FGV. Delfim Netto, Antonio. 1979. O Problema do Café no Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: Editora da FGV.
go back to reference do Lago, Luiz A.C. 1982. Balança Comercial, Balanço de Pagamentos e Meio Circulante no Brasil no Segundo Império: uma nota para uma revisão. Revista Brasileira de Economia 36 (4): 489–508. do Lago, Luiz A.C. 1982. Balança Comercial, Balanço de Pagamentos e Meio Circulante no Brasil no Segundo Império: uma nota para uma revisão. Revista Brasileira de Economia 36 (4): 489–508.
go back to reference ______. 2019. Latifúndio e Pequena Propriedade: Estrutura Fundiária e Economia no Brasil da Colônia ao Império. Texto para Discussão, Departamento de Economia PUC-Rio, No. 667. ______. 2019. Latifúndio e Pequena Propriedade: Estrutura Fundiária e Economia no Brasil da Colônia ao Império. Texto para Discussão, Departamento de Economia PUC-Rio, No. 667.
go back to reference Fernandes, Santiago. 1974. Mauá, o Economista do Império: análise de sua crítica científica ao padrão-ouro. Revista Brasileira de Economia 28 (2): 3–28. Fernandes, Santiago. 1974. Mauá, o Economista do Império: análise de sua crítica científica ao padrão-ouro. Revista Brasileira de Economia 28 (2): 3–28.
go back to reference Fetter, Frank W. 1965. Development of British Monetary Orthodoxy, 1797–1875. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Fetter, Frank W. 1965. Development of British Monetary Orthodoxy, 1797–1875. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
go back to reference Fishlow, Albert 1987. Market Forces or Group Interests: Inconvertible Paper Currency in Pre-1914 Latin America. Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of California at Berkeley, No. 8753, September. Fishlow, Albert 1987. Market Forces or Group Interests: Inconvertible Paper Currency in Pre-1914 Latin America. Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of California at Berkeley, No. 8753, September.
go back to reference Ford, Alec G. 1962. The Gold Standard: 1880–1914, Britain and Argentina. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Ford, Alec G. 1962. The Gold Standard: 1880–1914, Britain and Argentina. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
go back to reference Franco, Bernardo de S. 1984. Os Bancos do Brasil. Brasília: Editora da Universidade de Brasília. (originally published in 1848). Franco, Bernardo de S. 1984. Os Bancos do Brasil. Brasília: Editora da Universidade de Brasília. (originally published in 1848).
go back to reference Franco, Gustavo Henrique B. 1986. Taxa de Câmbio e Oferta de Moeda, 1880–1897: uma análise econométrica. Revista Brasileira de Economia 40 (1): 63–88. Franco, Gustavo Henrique B. 1986. Taxa de Câmbio e Oferta de Moeda, 1880–1897: uma análise econométrica. Revista Brasileira de Economia 40 (1): 63–88.
go back to reference ———. 1991. A Década Republicana: o Brasil e a economia internacional – 1880/1900. Rio de Janeiro: Ipea (Série PNPE, n. 27). ———. 1991. A Década Republicana: o Brasil e a economia internacional – 1880/1900. Rio de Janeiro: Ipea (Série PNPE, n. 27).
go back to reference ———. 2017. A Moeda e a Lei: uma história monetária brasileira, 1933–2013. Rio de Janeiro: Zahar. ———. 2017. A Moeda e a Lei: uma história monetária brasileira, 1933–2013. Rio de Janeiro: Zahar.
go back to reference Franco, Afonso A. de M., and Claudio Pacheco. 1979. História do Banco do Brasil. Brasília: Banco do Brasil. Franco, Afonso A. de M., and Claudio Pacheco. 1979. História do Banco do Brasil. Brasília: Banco do Brasil.
go back to reference Frieden, Jeffrey. 1994. Exchange Rate Politics: Contemporary Lessons from American History. Review of International Political Economy 1 (1): 81–103.CrossRef Frieden, Jeffrey. 1994. Exchange Rate Politics: Contemporary Lessons from American History. Review of International Political Economy 1 (1): 81–103.CrossRef
go back to reference ———. 2015. Currency Politics: The Political Economy of Exchange-Rate Policy. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.CrossRef ———. 2015. Currency Politics: The Political Economy of Exchange-Rate Policy. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Friedman, Milton, and Anna Schwartz. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Friedman, Milton, and Anna Schwartz. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Fritsch, Winston. 1988. External Constraints on Economic Policy in Brazil, 1889–1930. London: Macmillan.CrossRef Fritsch, Winston. 1988. External Constraints on Economic Policy in Brazil, 1889–1930. London: Macmillan.CrossRef
go back to reference Furtado, Celso. 1970. Formação Econômica do Brasil. 10th ed. São Paulo: Companhia Editora Nacional. Furtado, Celso. 1970. Formação Econômica do Brasil. 10th ed. São Paulo: Companhia Editora Nacional.
go back to reference Gambi, Thiago F.R. 2017. Bancos Nacionais do Brasil: os casos de 1808 e 1853. In Historia Bancaria y Monetaria de América Latina (siglos XIX y XX): nuevas perspectivas, ed. Carlos Marichal and Thiago Gambi, 63–99. Santander: Editorial de la Universidad de Cantabria. Gambi, Thiago F.R. 2017. Bancos Nacionais do Brasil: os casos de 1808 e 1853. In Historia Bancaria y Monetaria de América Latina (siglos XIX y XX): nuevas perspectivas, ed. Carlos Marichal and Thiago Gambi, 63–99. Santander: Editorial de la Universidad de Cantabria.
go back to reference Gerschenkron, Alexander. 1962. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Gerschenkron, Alexander. 1962. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
go back to reference Gilbart, James W. 1859. Tractado Practico de Bancos. Rio de Janeiro: Garnier. Gilbart, James W. 1859. Tractado Practico de Bancos. Rio de Janeiro: Garnier.
go back to reference Glasner, David. 1989. On Some Classical Monetary Controversies. History of Political Economy 21 (2): 201–229.CrossRef Glasner, David. 1989. On Some Classical Monetary Controversies. History of Political Economy 21 (2): 201–229.CrossRef
go back to reference ———. 1992. The Real Bills Doctrine in the Light of the Law of Reflux. History of Political Economy 24 (4): 867–894.CrossRef ———. 1992. The Real Bills Doctrine in the Light of the Law of Reflux. History of Political Economy 24 (4): 867–894.CrossRef
go back to reference Goldsmith, Raymond W. 1986. Brasil, 1850–1984: desenvolvimento financeiro sob um século de inflação. São Paulo: Harper & Row. Goldsmith, Raymond W. 1986. Brasil, 1850–1984: desenvolvimento financeiro sob um século de inflação. São Paulo: Harper & Row.
go back to reference Great Britain, Foreign Office, Diplomatic and Consular Reports (“Blue Books”), various years. Great Britain, Foreign Office, Diplomatic and Consular Reports (“Blue Books”), various years.
go back to reference Hammond, Bray. 1957. Banks and Politics in America from the Revolution to the Civil War. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Hammond, Bray. 1957. Banks and Politics in America from the Revolution to the Civil War. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Hoyer, Martins. 1880. Estudos Sobre a Reforma do Meio Circulante. Maranhão: Typographia do Payz. Hoyer, Martins. 1880. Estudos Sobre a Reforma do Meio Circulante. Maranhão: Typographia do Payz.
go back to reference Junta dos Corretores de Fundos Públicos da Cidade do Rio de Janeiro. Livro Official de Cotações de Titulos e Valores, various volumes. Junta dos Corretores de Fundos Públicos da Cidade do Rio de Janeiro. Livro Official de Cotações de Titulos e Valores, various volumes.
go back to reference Kindleberger, Charles P. 1996. Manias, Panics and Crashes: a history of financial crises. London: MacMillan, 3rd edn. Kindleberger, Charles P. 1996. Manias, Panics and Crashes: a history of financial crises. London: MacMillan, 3rd edn.
go back to reference Levy, Maria Barbara. 1995. The Brazilian Public Debt – Domestic and Foreign, 1824–1913. In The Public Debt in Latin America in Historical Perspective, ed. Reinhard Liehr, 201–228. Vervuert: Frankfurt am Mein. Levy, Maria Barbara. 1995. The Brazilian Public Debt – Domestic and Foreign, 1824–1913. In The Public Debt in Latin America in Historical Perspective, ed. Reinhard Liehr, 201–228. Vervuert: Frankfurt am Mein.
go back to reference Levy, Maria Barbara, and Ana Maria R. de Andrade. 1993. El Sector Financiero y El Desarollo Bancario en Río de Janeiro (1850–1888). In La Economia Financiera y la Formación de la Banca Central en España y Latinoamerica, ed. C. Marichal and P. Tedde, 209–254. Madrid: Banco de España. Levy, Maria Barbara, and Ana Maria R. de Andrade. 1993. El Sector Financiero y El Desarollo Bancario en Río de Janeiro (1850–1888). In La Economia Financiera y la Formación de la Banca Central en España y Latinoamerica, ed. C. Marichal and P. Tedde, 209–254. Madrid: Banco de España.
go back to reference Milet, Henrique Augusto. 1875. O Meio Circulante e a Questão Bancária. 2nd ed. Recife: Typographia do Jornal do Recife. (originally published in 1860). Milet, Henrique Augusto. 1875. O Meio Circulante e a Questão Bancária. 2nd ed. Recife: Typographia do Jornal do Recife. (originally published in 1860).
go back to reference Neuhaus, Paulo. 1975. História Monetária do Brasil, 1900–45. Rio de Janeiro: IBMEC. Neuhaus, Paulo. 1975. História Monetária do Brasil, 1900–45. Rio de Janeiro: IBMEC.
go back to reference Normano, João Frederico. 1935. Brazil: a study of economic types. Chapel Hill: The University of North Carolina Press. Normano, João Frederico. 1935. Brazil: a study of economic types. Chapel Hill: The University of North Carolina Press.
go back to reference Ortigão, Ramalho. 1914. A Moeda Circulante no Brazil. Rio de Janeiro: Typographia do Jornal do Commercio. Ortigão, Ramalho. 1914. A Moeda Circulante no Brazil. Rio de Janeiro: Typographia do Jornal do Commercio.
go back to reference Peláez, Carlos Manuel. 1975. The Establishment of Banking Institutions in a Backward Economy: Brazil, 1800–1851. Business History Review XLIX (4): 446–472.CrossRef Peláez, Carlos Manuel. 1975. The Establishment of Banking Institutions in a Backward Economy: Brazil, 1800–1851. Business History Review XLIX (4): 446–472.CrossRef
go back to reference Peláez, Carlos Manuel, and Wilson Suzigan. 1976. História Monetária do Brasil. 2nd ed. Brasília: Editora da Universidade de Brasília. Peláez, Carlos Manuel, and Wilson Suzigan. 1976. História Monetária do Brasil. 2nd ed. Brasília: Editora da Universidade de Brasília.
go back to reference Relatorio da Commissão de Inquerito Nomeada por Aviso do Ministério da Fazenda, de 10 de Outubro de 1859 (undated). Relatorio da Commissão de Inquerito Nomeada por Aviso do Ministério da Fazenda, de 10 de Outubro de 1859 (undated).
go back to reference Relatorio da Commissão Encarregada pelo Governo Imperial por Aviso do Primeiro de Outubro e 28 de Dezembro de 1864, de Proceder a um Inquerito Sobre as Causas Principais e Accidentaes da Crise do Mez de Setembro de 1864. 1865. Rio de Janeiro, Typographia Nacional. Relatorio da Commissão Encarregada pelo Governo Imperial por Aviso do Primeiro de Outubro e 28 de Dezembro de 1864, de Proceder a um Inquerito Sobre as Causas Principais e Accidentaes da Crise do Mez de Setembro de 1864. 1865. Rio de Janeiro, Typographia Nacional.
go back to reference Rodrigues, José Honório, ed. 1978. Atas do Conselho de Estado. Brasília: Senado Federal. Rodrigues, José Honório, ed. 1978. Atas do Conselho de Estado. Brasília: Senado Federal.
go back to reference Schulz, John. 2013. A Crise Financeira da Abolição. 2nd ed. São Paulo: Edusp. Schulz, John. 2013. A Crise Financeira da Abolição. 2nd ed. São Paulo: Edusp.
go back to reference Schweikart, Larry. 1987. Banking in the American South from the Age of Jackson to Reconstruction. Baton Rouge and London: Louisiana State University Press. Schweikart, Larry. 1987. Banking in the American South from the Age of Jackson to Reconstruction. Baton Rouge and London: Louisiana State University Press.
go back to reference Smith, Vera. 1936. The Rationale of Central Banking. London: P. S. King & Son. Smith, Vera. 1936. The Rationale of Central Banking. London: P. S. King & Son.
go back to reference Soares, Sebastião F. 1977. Notas Estatísticas Sobre a Produção Agrícola e Carestia dos Gêneros Alimentícios no Império do Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: IPEA/INPES. (originally published in 1860). Soares, Sebastião F. 1977. Notas Estatísticas Sobre a Produção Agrícola e Carestia dos Gêneros Alimentícios no Império do Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: IPEA/INPES. (originally published in 1860).
go back to reference Soares, Luis Carlos. 1984. A Manufatura na Sociedade Escravista: o surto manufatureiro no Rio de Janeiro e nas suas circunvizinhanças (1840–1870). In La Préindustrialization du Brésil: essais sur une économie en transition, ed. F. Mauro. Paris: CNRS. Soares, Luis Carlos. 1984. A Manufatura na Sociedade Escravista: o surto manufatureiro no Rio de Janeiro e nas suas circunvizinhanças (1840–1870). In La Préindustrialization du Brésil: essais sur une économie en transition, ed. F. Mauro. Paris: CNRS.
go back to reference Summerhill, William R. 2015. Inglorious Revolution: Political Institutions, Sovereign Debt, and Financial Underdevelopment in Imperial Brazil. New Haven: Yale University Press.CrossRef Summerhill, William R. 2015. Inglorious Revolution: Political Institutions, Sovereign Debt, and Financial Underdevelopment in Imperial Brazil. New Haven: Yale University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Suzigan, Wilson. 1990. Moeda e Sistema Bancário. In Estatísticas Históricas do Brasil, ed. IBGE, vol. 3, 2nd ed.. (séries econômicas, demográficas e sociais, 1550–1985). Rio de Janeiro: IBGE. Suzigan, Wilson. 1990. Moeda e Sistema Bancário. In Estatísticas Históricas do Brasil, ed. IBGE, vol. 3, 2nd ed.. (séries econômicas, demográficas e sociais, 1550–1985). Rio de Janeiro: IBGE.
go back to reference Sweigart, Joseph E. 1987. Coffee Factorage and the Emergence of a Brazilian Capital Market, 1850–1888. New York: Garland Publishing. Sweigart, Joseph E. 1987. Coffee Factorage and the Emergence of a Brazilian Capital Market, 1850–1888. New York: Garland Publishing.
go back to reference Topik, Steven. 1994. State Autonomy in Economic Policy: Brazil’s Experience, 1822–1930. Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Affairs 26 (4): 449–476.CrossRef Topik, Steven. 1994. State Autonomy in Economic Policy: Brazil’s Experience, 1822–1930. Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Affairs 26 (4): 449–476.CrossRef
go back to reference Triner, Gail. 2000. Banking and Economic Development: Brazil, 1889–1930. New York: Palgrave. Triner, Gail. 2000. Banking and Economic Development: Brazil, 1889–1930. New York: Palgrave.
go back to reference Vieira, Dorival T. 1962. A Evolução do Sistema Monetário Brasileiro. São Paulo: FCEA/USP. Vieira, Dorival T. 1962. A Evolução do Sistema Monetário Brasileiro. São Paulo: FCEA/USP.
go back to reference Villela, André A. 2005. Política Tarifária no II Reinado: evolução e impactos, 1850–1889. Nova Economia 15 (1): 35–68. Villela, André A. 2005. Política Tarifária no II Reinado: evolução e impactos, 1850–1889. Nova Economia 15 (1): 35–68.
go back to reference Viner, Jacob. 1937. Studies in the Theory of International Trade. New York: Harper Bros. Viner, Jacob. 1937. Studies in the Theory of International Trade. New York: Harper Bros.
go back to reference White, Lawrence. 1984. Free Banking in Britain: Theory, Experience and Debate, 1800–45. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. White, Lawrence. 1984. Free Banking in Britain: Theory, Experience and Debate, 1800–45. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference ———. 1991. Banking Without a Central Bank: Scotland Before 1844 as a Free Banking System. In Unregulated Banking: Chaos or order? ed. F. Capie and E. Wood. London: Macmillan. ———. 1991. Banking Without a Central Bank: Scotland Before 1844 as a Free Banking System. In Unregulated Banking: Chaos or order? ed. F. Capie and E. Wood. London: Macmillan.
go back to reference Wileman, Joseph P. 1896. Brazilian Exchange: The Study of an Inconvertible Currency. Buenos Aires: Gali Brothers. Wileman, Joseph P. 1896. Brazilian Exchange: The Study of an Inconvertible Currency. Buenos Aires: Gali Brothers.
Metadata
Title
Taking Stock: Monetary and Banking Policy in the Second Reign
Author
André A. Villela
Copyright Year
2020
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-32774-3_5