Skip to main content
Top

2021 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

6. The Constitutional Court of Colombia Versus Central Bank Autonomy

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This chapter deals with the interventions of the Constitutional Court of Colombia in decisions of the Colombian central bank during the 1990s. Constitutional judges, in their eagerness to harmonize every action of the state organs with the social rule of law, have interfered with the Bank of the Republic’s autonomy, operations and legal objectives, causing uncertainty about the independence and role of the institution. By intervening with the operations of the central bank, the Court has produced contradictory judgments. On the one hand, the Court has ratified the autonomy of the central bank by putting clear limits to legislative and executive intervention—which are more commonly considered a threat to central bank independence. On the other hand, the Court has modified the objective of the central bank, limiting its autonomy to achieve goals in line with the social rule of law.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
Carbonari and Vargas (2009), pp. 231–234.
 
2
Const. Colombia Art. 371. Before the constitutional reform of 1991, monetary policy was conducted by a monetary council created in 1963. This council was mostly made up by government members. Inflation was high (20%) but stable. The key for the stability were several economic restrictions, such as capital controls. These arrangements were incompatible with economic liberalization. See Alesina et al. (2005), pp. 347–348.
 
3
The Colombian Constitution states that preserving the purchasing power of the currency is a duty of the Colombian state. The Bank of the Republic is the state’s “intermediary” in the performance of this function. See Const. Colombia Art. 373.
 
4
The original Spanish version of the Constitution of Colombia says that “Colombia es un estado social de derecho.” Some translate this to English in what I would consider being inaccurate: “Colombia is a social state under the rule of law.” The right translation would be: Colombia is a state based on a social rule of law. See: Const. Colombia Art. 1.
 
5
According to Const. Colombia Art. 49, [p]ublic health and environmental protection are public services for which the State is responsible […].
 
6
Const. Colombia Art. 48.
 
7
Const. Colombia Art. 51: “All Colombian citizens are entitled to live in dignity. The State shall determine the conditions necessary to give effect to this right and shall promote plans for public housing, appropriate systems of long-term financing, and community plans for the execution of these housing programs.”
 
8
The Const. Colombia Art. 2 says that “essential goals of the State are to serve the community, promote the general prosperity, and guarantee the effectiveness of the principles, rights, and duties stipulated by the Constitution […]”. The authorities of the Republic are there to protect the life, honor, property, beliefs and other rights and freedoms, and to ensure the compliance of the state and particulars with social obligations.
According to the Colombian Constitution of 1886, the Supreme Court of Colombia oversaw the constitutionality of laws passed by Congress. However, it was necessary that the executive branch previously challenged the law for not being in agreement with the constitution. See Constitution of Colombia of 1886 Art. 151 (4) [Constitución de Colombia de 1886, Diario Oficial No. 6758 y 6759, August 7, 1886]: “Make the final decision on the constitutionality of legislative acts that have been challenged by the government as unconstitutional [Own Translation].
 
9
Celmira Waldo de Valoyes v. Caja Nacaional de Previsión Social-Seccional Chocó, CCC, Sentencia SU-111, 6 March 1997.
 
10
Kugler and Rosenthal (2005), p. 76.
 
11
López Daza (2011), pp. 176–177.
 
12
Constitutional judgments about economic issues are not a novelty. They have taken place in the United States, for instance, where the Supreme Court nullified labor laws that tried to establish guarantees to workers, arguing the violation of freedom of contract. It has also occurred in Spain where the court has declared laws about social security unconstitutional for conflicting with the Spanish Constitution. See Uprimny (2006), pp. 41–44.
The difficulty of adjudicating the constitutionality of economic aspects was recently evidenced in Europe as consequence of the decision of the German Federal Court about the Outright Monetary Transactions Program (OMT) which implied that the central bank could purchase bonds issued by member states in the secondary market. The Court of Justice of the European Union decided that this central bank measure was in line with the EU Treaties. On the other hand, the German Federal Court decided that the OMT might violate the law of the EU. For more detail, see Peter Gauwelier and Others v Deutscher Bundestag. BVerfG, C-62/14. This particular case raised the issue about whether the courts of justice should limit their basis for a decision to the rationality of the measure of the central bank or fully review monetary policy. One of the arguments in favor of a full judicial review of monetary policy can be found in the idea that full judicial review is a requirement to balance central bank autonomy with democracy. The argument against it points to the constitution rank of the ECB (via the Maastricht Treaty) which limits the scope of judicial review to the word of the legal rule that grants the bank independence. A technical argument against it is that judges are not qualified to disentangle complicated economic aspects. The court’s lack of knowledge can be evident, and the court’s credibility can suffer when an expert in monetary policy matters challenges the court’s decision. For more detail on this topic, see Goldmann (2014), pp. 265–274.
 
13
Cerra Nolasco (2001), p. 171.
 
14
Uprimny (2006), pp. 40–41.
 
15
Ibid., p. 39.
 
16
Ibid., p. 40.
 
17
Alejandro Baquero Nariño and other v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-955, 26 July 2000, quote in Spanish: “La sentencia anuncia con claridad que ha nacido en el panorama de los órganos reguladores del Estado, uno superior a todos, dotado de poderes de intervención, cuyas resoluciones incluso no experimentan las limitaciones que se pueden hacer valer ante las autoridades competentes.” Regarding the opinion of Justices Cifuentes and Naranjo, the CCC manifested that those opinions are against the rule of law, antidemocratic and disrespectful of the CCC. Their opinion threatens the building of institutions of the country according to a majority of CCC justices.
 
18
Cerra Nolasco (2001), p. 167.
 
19
Robertson (2010), p. 5.
 
20
Martinez Caballero (2000), p. 11.
 
21
Mavčič (2001), p. 11.
 
22
Robertson (2010), pp. 12–13.
 
23
Mavčič (2001), p. 11.
 
24
Catrile and Pita (2011), p. 123.
 
25
Rivero Ortega (2013), p. 55.
 
26
Mavčič (2001), p. 11.
 
27
Cerra Nolasco (2001), p. 169.
 
28
Robertson (2010), p. 10.
 
29
In this sense, the activist justices attempt to clarify legal texts or create new legal norms by complementing the constitutional text with judicial opinions.
 
30
Kmiec (2004), pp. 1463–1476.
 
31
Kugler and Rosenthal (2005), p. 90.
 
32
See my explanation in the chapter on legal certainty about limits that judges should have when deciding about the actions of public policy to not usurp the functions of technical agencies.
 
33
Peters (2016), pp. 23–26.
 
34
Roosevelt (2008), p. 12.
 
35
Ibid., pp. 18–21.
 
36
Ibid., p. 169.
 
37
Roosevelt (2008), p. 12.
 
38
Escobar Martinez (2006), pp. 94–96.
 
39
Bonilla (2013), pp. 26–27.
 
40
Robertson (2010), pp. 84–85.
 
41
In common law systems, the law-making role of the courts diminishes the degree of judicial independence. The court requires a joint process of decision making, coordination and increased ways of communication. When they declare a law unconstitutional, a debate between judges and the members of the parliament responsible to fill the spaces left by the declaration of unconstitutionality is often necessary. See Dickson (2007), p. 11.
 
42
Dickson (2007), pp. 12–13.
 
43
Ruggiero (2012), pp. 27–28.
 
44
Ibid., pp. 33–34.
 
45
Ibid., pp. 20–21.
 
46
In his study, Vanberg explains that constitutional review is a game of imperfect information in which it is not possible for the Congress to know how the court is going to review legislation. At the same time, the court cannot know whether or not the Congress is going to comply with the judicial decision. The court could either be friendly with the legislators or declare the law constitutional. The court could also be hostile and nullify laws enacted by the Congress. The court could also be sure of public support and, not only declare the law unconstitutional, but also be ready to engage in an institutional conflict with the legislative branch if the Congress does not comply. On the other hand, the court cannot know if the Congress is going to comply and whether it will face electoral accountability in case of noncompliance. For electoral accountability, the functioning of the legislative branch must be transparent, and the citizens must follow up its performance. When the constitutional court enjoys public support and the performance of the Congress is transparent, the danger of electoral punishment is high, and the Congress has incentives to comply with the court’s decisions. When the court is not well-known, and the transparency of the legislative branch is not high enough, the Congress has little incentives to comply with the constitutional decision. See Vanberg (2001), p. 346 for a detailed explanation of the game.
 
47
Olano Garcia (2004), pp. 576–577.
 
48
Betlem (2002), pp. 397–398.
 
49
For more on how the Colombian administrative court has been modulating judicial decisions, see Escobar Martinez (2006), pp. 91–93.
 
50
Escobar Martinez (2006), p. 107; see also Olano Garcia (2004), p. 577.
 
51
Ruggiero (2012), pp. 16–17.
 
52
Eskridge (1991), p. 343.
 
53
Martinez Caballero (2000), p. 10; see also Bonilla (2013), p. 26.
 
54
According to Const. Colombia Art. 167, in the case in which [a] bill has been opposed as unconstitutional. In such an event, should the Houses insist, the bill shall be sent to the Constitutional Court so that the latter, within the six (6) following days, may decide about its constitutionality. The decision of the Court obliges the President to approve the statute. If the Court declares the bill unconstitutional, it shall be filed away.”
 
55
General Rulings of the Constitutional Court of Colombia Art. 3 [Reglamento Interno de la Corte Constitucional de Colombia, Acuerdo 01, 1992].
 
56
Const. Colombia Art. 233: “The judges of the Constitutional Court, the Supreme Court of Justice, and of the Council of State shall be elected for a period of eight years.”
 
57
According to Const. Colombia Art. 241 (9), one of the functions the CCC should perform is to “[r]evise, in the form determined by statute, the judicial decisions connected with the protection of constitutional rights.”
 
58
Azcuna (1993), p. 1.
 
59
Const. Colombia Art. 86: “Every individual may claim legal protection before the judge, at any time or place, through a preferential and summary proceeding, for himself/herself or by whoever acts in his/her name, the immediate protection of his/her fundamental constitutional rights when the individual fears the latter may be jeopardized or threatened by the action or omission of any public authority.”
 
60
According to Const. Colombia Art. 241 (1), to safeguard the constitution the Constitutional Court may [d]ecide on the petitions of unconstitutionality brought by citizens against measures amending the Constitution, no matter what their origin, exclusively for errors of procedure in their formation.”
 
61
Const. Colombia Art. 4.
 
62
Const. Colombia Art. 241: “The safeguarding of the integrity and supremacy of the Constitution is entrusted to the Constitutional […].
 
63
Cerra Nolasco (2001), pp. 169–170.
 
64
Executive Decree 2067 of 1991 Art. 49 [Decreto Ejecutivo 2067 de 1991]: “The judgments of the constitutional court cannot be appealed. Constitutional court proceedings may only be nullified before the ruling of the court. Only irregularities involving violation of the due process may be a basis for the court to nullify the process [Own Translation].
 
65
German Arango Rojas v. Corte Constitucional de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia A-195, 20 May 2009. See also Olano Garcia (2004), p. 572.
 
66
Peters (2016), p. 25.
 
67
Cerra Nolasco (2001), pp. 172–173.
 
68
Felipe Ortega Escobar and other v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-027, 27 January 2012.
 
69
Ibid., p. 173.
 
70
Under exceptional conditions, res iudicata applies to a legal rule declared constitutional: (1) The constitutional court has to decide about the constitutionality of a legal rule that is identical to one previously declared constitutional; (2) The facts that motivate a new constitutional lawsuit are identical; (3) There are no important economic, social, cultural, political or even ideological changes that require a modification in the judicial reasoning to adapt it to the new circumstances. See María Camila Silva Mogollón v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-860, 18 October 2006.
 
71
Marcela Barona Montua v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-109, 15 March 1995.
 
72
Pablo Antonio Bustos Sánchez v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-083, 1 March 1995.
 
73
Martinez Caballero (2000), p. 13.
 
74
Marcela Barona Montua v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-109, 15 March 1995.
 
75
Carlos Eduardo Naranjo Florez v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-151, 5 April 1995.
 
76
AA v. Instituto Colombiano de Bienestar Familiar, CCC, Sentencia T-389, 27 May 1999.
 
77
Camilo Velásquez Reyes v. Corte Constitucional de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia A-256, 4 August 2009.
 
78
AA v. Instituto Colombiano de Bienestar Familiar, CCC, Sentencia T-389, 27 May 1999.
 
79
Roosevelt (2008), p. 3.
 
80
Armando José Soto Jiménez v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-1064, 10 October 2001.
 
81
Olano Garcia (2004), pp. 578–579.
 
82
Armando José Soto Jiménez v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-1064, 10 October 2001.
 
83
Martinez Caballero (2000), p. 24; see also Olano Garcia (2004), p. 577.
 
84
Ivan Santiago Martínez Vásquez v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-100, 23 February 2011.
 
85
The conception of the social rule of law is exclusive to the Colombian legal framework. However, the Mexican Constitution of 1917 was the first to coin the term “social function of property” as the cornerstone of the economic system. See Castillo Calle (2013), p. 6.
The Brazilian Constitution of 1946 put “social justice” at the core of economic activity. See Constitution of Brazil of 1946 Art. 145 [Constituição dos Estados Unidos do Brasil, 18 September 1946]: “The economic order must be organized according to the principles of social justice, reconciling freedom of initiative with the valorization of human labor [Own Translation].”
The Chilean Constitution of 1925 did not introduce the socialization of property but guaranteed public economic goods like protecting labor markets and social welfare. See Constitution of Chile of 1925 Art. 10 [Constitución de Chile de 1925, 18 September 1925]: The value of public importance that the constitution protected was the “socialization of property” that allowed the state to intervene in economic issues to achieve a plethora of socially desirable objectives.
 
86
Const. Colombia. Art. 40: “Any citizen has the right to participate in the establishment, exercise, and control of political power. To make this decree effective the citizen may: […] (6.) Undertake public measures in defense of the Constitution and the law.”
 
87
López Daza (2011), pp. 170–175.
 
88
Andrés de Zubiría Samper v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-776, 9 September 2003.
 
89
Andrés de Zubiría Samper v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-776, 9 September 2003.
 
90
Palombella (2016), p. 8.
 
91
Ribeiro (2003), p. 42.
 
92
Armando José Soto Jiménez v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-1064, 10 October 2001.
 
93
Carbonari and Vargas (2009), pp. 234–236.
 
94
Ibid., p. 236.
 
95
Law of Education Art. 4 [Ley de Educación, Colombia Diario Oficial, 8 February 1994]: “The state, society and family must ensure quality of education and promote access to public education, and it is the responsibility of the Nation to ensure its coverage [Own Translation].”
 
96
Note that also the Law of Integral Social Security System Art. 1 [Ley de Seguridad Social Integral, Colombia Diario Oficial 41.148, 23 December 1993] states the following: “The system of integral social security has the objective of guaranteeing the people and communities rights to be able to have a life quality that is in agreement with human dignity through the protection of the contingencies that affect them [Own Translation].”
 
97
José Alirio Montoya Restrepo and others v. Caja Nacional de Previsión, CCC, Sentencia T-068, 5 March 1998.
 
98
Andrés de Zubiría Samper v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-776, 9 September 2003.
 
99
Armando José Soto Jiménez v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-1064, 10 October 2001.
 
100
José Alirio Montoya Restrepo and others v. Caja Nacional de Previsión, CCC, Sentencia T-068, 5 March 1998.
 
101
Marcela Barona Montua v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-109, 15 March 1995.
 
102
Rodriguez Garavito and Rodríguez Franco (2015), pp. 6–7.
 
103
Celmira Waldo de Valoyes v. Caja Nacional de Previsión Social-Seccional Chocó, CCC, Sentencia SU-111, 6 March 1997.
 
104
Emperatriz Castillo Burbano v. Gobierno de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-747, 6 October 1999.
 
105
René Vargas Pérez v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-481, 7 July 1999.
 
106
Jaime Rafael Pedraza Vanegas v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-050, 10 February 1994.
 
107
René Vargas Pérez v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-481, 7 July 1999.
 
108
Alejandro Baquero Nariño and other v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-955, 26 July 2000.
 
109
Andrés Quintero Rubiano v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-208, 1 March 2000.
 
110
Providing housing to the most vulnerable people is one of the main interests of the economic development plan. See Departamento Nacional de Planificación, Bases del Plan Nacional de Desarrollo, p. 28, 49.
 
111
René Vargas Pérez v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-481, 7 July 1999.
 
112
Juan Carlos Ramírez Gómez v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-191, 8 May 1996.
 
113
Fique Pinto (2008), p. 76.
 
114
Executive Decree 677 of 1972 Art. 1 [Decreto Ejecutivo 677 de 1972, Diario Oficial No. 33.594, 18 May 1972] [hereinafter Colombia, Executive Decree of 18 May 1972]: “The government, through its acting agencies, will encourage savings with the purpose of channeling part of them to construction [Own Translation]. Another strategy was to provide direct housing subsidies to the poorest people in order to allow them to afford housing. See Fique Pinto (2008), p. 77.
 
115
Forero (2004), p. 36; see also Bank of the Republic (2000).
 
116
Held (2000), p. 40.
 
117
Forero (2004), p. 36.
 
118
Urrutia and Namen (2012), p. 296.
 
119
Executive Decree 1229 of 1972 Art. 3 [Decreto Ejecutivo 1229 de 1972, Diario Oficial No. 33.663, 16 August 1972]: “The Board of Savings and Housing will calculate the value of the UPAC monthly […] based on the changes in the consumer price index for employees and workers as prepared by the National Administrative Department of Statistics (DANE) for the previous quarter and inform the CAVs [Own Translation].
 
120
Executive Decree 269 of 1974 Art. 1 [Decreto Ejecutivo 269 de 1974, Diario Oficial No. 3.072, 21 February 1974]: “The Board of Savings and Housing will calculate the value of the UPAC monthly […] based on the changes in the consumer price index for employees and workers as prepared by the National Administrative Department of Statistics (DANE) for the previous 24 months and inform the CAVs [Own Translation].”
 
121
Executive Decree 58 of 1976 Art. 1 [Decreto Ejecutivo 58 de 1976, Diario Oficial No. 34.489, 1 February 1976] [hereinafter Colombia, Executive Decree of 1 February 1976]: “The Board of Savings and Housing will calculate the value of the UPAC monthly […] based on the changes in the consumer price index for employees and workers as prepared by the National Administrative Department of Statistics (DANE) for the previous 12 months [Own Translation].” Furthermore, Art. 2 of this decree states that “without prejudice to the provisions of the preceding article, the increase of the unit of constant purchasing power (UPAC) should be have an upper-limit of 18% annually [Own Translation].”
 
122
Held (2000), p. 40.
 
123
Forero (2004), pp. 32–33.
 
124
Urrutia and Namen (2012), p. 296.
 
125
Executive Decree 1685 of 1975 Art. 1 [Decreto 1685 de 1975, Diario Oficial No. 34.402, 18 September 1975]: “Regarding the system for calculating the UPAC, the increase of its value has to be limited to a maximum of 19% annually [Own Translation].”
 
126
Colombia, Executive Decree of 1 February 1976 Art. 1: […] the increase of the unit of constant purchasing power (UPAC) should be maximal 18% annually [Own Translation].”
 
127
Executive Decree 2475 of 1980 Art. 1 [Decreto Ejecutivo 2475 de 1980, Diario Oficial No. 35.610, 29 September 1980].
 
128
Executive Decree 2929 of 1982 Art. 1 [Decreto Ejecutivo 1919 de 1982, Diario Oficial No. 36.115, 22 October 1982].
 
129
Mora (2010), p. 18.
 
130
In 1976, this state organism was eliminated, and all its functions passed to the Monetary Council, according to the Art. 5 of the Decree 1110 of 1976.
 
131
AA v. Instituto Colombiano de Bienestar Familiar, CCC, Sentencia T-389, 27 May 1999.
 
132
See website of the Banco de la Republica: http://​www.​banrep.​gov.​co/​es/​reformas.
 
133
Forero (2004), p. 34.
 
134
Colombia, Executive Decree of 18 May 1972 Art. 6: “For the purposes specified in this decree, there will be a Fund of Savings and Housing in the Bank of the Republic [Own Translation].”
 
135
Ibid., Art. 8: “The Monetary Council will authorize the Bank of the Republic to issue and allocate bonds up to an amount of 60,000,000 of pesos, in three portions of 20,000,000 pesos for the initial allocation of resources for the FAVI [Own Translation].”
 
136
Colombia, Executive Decree of 18 May 1972, Art. 7: “The resources of the Fund of Savings and Housing will come: c) from the reimbursements, interests and fees of the credit operations the [the bank] executes [Own Translation].”
 
137
Ibid., Art. 13: “The Bank of the Republic’s Fund of Savings and Housing, after getting the authorization of the Board for Savings and Housing, will be able to: a) Get internal and external loans […] [Own Translation].
 
138
Ibid., Art. 7: “The resources of the Fund of Savings and Housing will come from: d) part of the budget that is assigned to the Bank of the Republic and that the Bank decides to grant it in the fund [Own Translation].”
 
139
Executive Decree 1131 of 1984 Art. 1 [Decreto Ejecutivo 1131 de 1984, Diario Oficial No. 36.115, 5 June 1984]: “The Bank of the Republic will calculate monthly and report with identical frequency the value in legal tender of the UPAC to the CAVs, for each day of the following month […] calculated based on the changes in the consumer price index as is relevant for employees and workers, prepared by the National Statistics Department (DANE) for the period of the twelve (12) previous months. To that it will add 1.5% of the squared difference between the average variation in the mentioned price index and the effective weighted average of the deposit certificates up to ninety (90) days issued by commercial banks and financial corporations, calculated by the Bank of the Republic for the next month [Own Translation].”
 
140
Executive Decree 1319 of 1989 Art. 1 [Decreto Ejecutivo 1319 de 1989, Diario Oficial No. 38.869, 22 June 1989]: […] calculated like this: forty percent (40%) of the resulting variation in the national index of consumer prices (total weighted) prepared by the National Administrative Department of Statistics for the period of the next twelve (12) months. To that thirty-five (35%) of the average of the variable rate of DFT calculated by the Bank of the Republic for the next month are to be added [Own Translation].”
 
141
Const. Colombia Art. 371: “The Bank of the Republic shall exercise the functions of a central bank. It shall be organized as a legal public entity with administrative, patrimonial, and technical autonomy, subject to its own legal regime.”
 
142
Const. Colombia Art. 373: “The State, through the intermediary of the Bank of the Republic, shall oversee the maintenance of the purchasing power of the currency.”
 
143
Executive Decree 1730 of 1991 Art. 2.1.2.3.7 [Decreto Ejecutivo 1730 de 1991, Diario Oficial No. 39.889, 4 July 1991] […] calculated as follows: forty-five percent (45%) of the resulting variation of the national consumer price index (weighted total) prepared by the National Department of Statistics DANE for the period of twelve 12 months. To this 35% of the average rate of the fixed term deposits calculated by the Bank of the Republic for the precious month will be added [Own Translation].”
 
144
BRC Act Art. 16: “The Banco de la Republica will study and adopt monetary, credit and exchange measures aimed at regulating the circulation of money, The Banco de la República will study and adopt the monetary, credit, and and, in general, the liquidity of the financial market and the normal operation of the internal and external payments of the national economy, taking care of the stability of the value of the currency. To such effect, the Board of Directors will: […] f) Set forth the methodology for determining the value of the Constant Purchasing Power Unit (UPAC) in local currency, intending that it also reflects the movements of the interest rate in the economy.”
 
145
Decision No. 26 of 1994 of the Bank of the Republic [Resolución Externa No. 26 de 1994]: “The Bank of the Republic will calculate monthly for every day of the following month and inform with the same frequency the Savings and Housing Corporations (CAVs), of the value in terms of legal tender of the UPAC, which is equivalent to seventy-four percent (74%) of the moving average of fixed term deposits rates […][Own Translation]”.
 
146
Forero (2004), p. 36.
 
147
Hofstetter et al. (2011), p. 6.
 
148
Forero (2004), p. 36.
 
149
Hofstetter et al. (2011), p. 7.
 
150
Mora (2010), p. 19.
 
151
Const. Colombia Art. 51: “All Colombian citizens are entitled to live in dignity. The State shall determine the conditions necessary to give effect to this right and shall promote plans for public housing, appropriate systems of long-term financing, and community plans for the execution of these housing programs.”
 
152
Fique Pinto (2008), p. 73.
 
153
AA v. Instituto Colombiano de Bienestar Familiar, CCC, Sentencia T-389, 27 May 1999.
 
154
Andrés Quintero Rubiano v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-208, 1 March 2000.
 
155
AA v. Instituto Colombiano de Bienestar Familiar, CCC, Sentencia T-389, 27 May 1999.
 
156
Decision No. 10 of 1999 of the Bank of the Republic Art. 1 [Resolución Externa No. 10 de 1999]: “The Bank of the Republic will calculate monthly for every day of the following month and will inform the Savings and Housing Corporations (CAVs) at the same frequency on the value the Unit of Constant Purchasing Power UPAC in terms of legal tender. For this purpose, the monetary correction will be equivalent to the arithmetic average of the annual inflation rate based on the consumer price index of the twelve (12) previous months [Own Translation].
 
157
Executive Decree 1730 of 1991 Art. 2.1.2.3.7 [Decreto Ejecutivo 1730 de 1991, Diario Oficial No. 39.889, 4 July 1991].
 
158
Humberto de Jesús Longas Londono v. Gobierno de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-700, 16 September 1999.
 
159
See also, the Const. Colombia Art. 189 (25) which states that the President of the Republic must [o]rganize the public credit […]”.
 
160
According to Const. Colombia Art. 150 (19 d), Congress must “regulate activities concerning finance […]”.
 
161
Humberto de Jesús Longas Londono v. Gobierno de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-700, 16 September 1999.
 
162
Humberto de Jesús Longas Londono v. Gobierno de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-700, 16 September 1999; see also Uprimny (2006), p. 46.
 
163
Executive Decree 663 of 1993 [Decreto Ejecutivo 663 de 1993, Diario Oficial No. 40.820, 5 April 1993].
 
164
Emperatriz Castillo Burbano v. Gobierno de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-747, 6 October 1999.
 
165
Sixto Acuna Acevedo and others v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-1140, 30 August 2000.
 
166
Law 546 of 1999 of Colombia Art. 3 [Ley 546 de 1999, Diario Oficial 43.827, 23 December 1999] [hereinafter Law 546]: “The unit of real value UVR is a unit of account that reflects the purchasing power of the currency, based solely on the variation of the consumer price index: 1. Protect the patrimony of families represented in housing. 3. Protect the users of housing loans. [Own Translation].
 
167
Law 546 Art. 2: “Objectives and criteria of this law: the National government will regulate the long-term specialized housing finance system to set the necessary conditions to implement the constitutional right for decent housing in accordance with the following objectives and criteria […] [Own Translation]”.
 
168
Bank of the Republic (2000).
 
169
The UVR replaced the UPAC, which was declared unconstitutional in the constitutional decision. See Humberto de Jesús Longas Londono v. Gobierno de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-700, 16 September 1999.
 
170
Alejandro Baquero Nariño and other v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-955, 26 July 2000.
 
171
Alejandro Baquero Nariño and other v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-955, 26 July 2000.
 
172
Ibid.
 
173
Decision No. 14 of 2000 of the Bank of the Republic Art. 1 [Resolución Externa No. 14 de 2000].
 
174
For instance, Gunar Raul Ramírez and others v. Bank of the Republic of Colombia and other, Consejo de Estado de Colombia, File N: 76001-23-31-000-2001-02078-01(26174), 2 February 2004; Myriam Valencia de Zafra v. Bank of the Republic and other, Consejo de Estado de Colombia, File N: 76001-23-31-000-2001-00804-01(28298), 13 April 2006; Hugo Yesid Suarez Sierra v. Bank of the Republic and other, Consejo de Estado de Colombia, File N: 25000-23-26-000-2001-01147-01(25614), 10 June 2004; among others.
 
175
For instance, the CCC in a writ of protection of the constitutional rights of the debtors revoked the foreclosure declaration made in favor of the Savings and Housing Corporation “Colmena”. See Jorge Enrique Pineda Rodríguez v. Juzgado Sexto Civil del Circuito de Bucaramanga and other, CCC, Sentencia T-597, 27 July 2006.
 
176
For instance, Granahorrar Banco Comercial S.A., and others v. Tribunal Administrativo de Cundinamarca, Consejo de Estado de Colombia, File N: 25000-23-25-000-2001-9014-01(AG-035), 20 June 2002.
 
177
Bank of the Republic v. Seguros Generales Suramericana S.A. and other, File N: 11001-03-26-000-2014-00195-00(52969), 8 July 2015.
 
178
Decision No. 13 of 2000 of the Bank of the Republic [Resolución Externa No. 13 de 2000].
 
179
Alejandro Baquero Nariño and other v. Congreso de la República de Colombia, CCC, Sentencia C-955, 26 July 2000.
 
180
Ninfa Inés Andrade Navarrete and other v Bank of the Republic, Consejo de Estado de Colombia, File N: 11001-03-27-000-2004-00074-00(14824), 23 August 2012.
 
181
Decision No. 3 of 2005 of the Bank of the Republic [Resolución Externa No. 3 de 2005].
 
182
Ninfa Inés Andrade Navarrete v. Bank of the Republic, Consejo de Estado de Colombia, File N: 11001-03-27-000-2006-00009-00(15971), 1 January 2008.
 
183
AA v. Instituto Colombiano de Bienestar Familiar, CCC, Sentencia T-389, 27 May 1999.
 
184
He refers to “choque de trenes institucionales” López Daza (2011), p. 177.
 
185
CRBP Law Art. 24: “The attributions and duties of the board are: g): Set the interest rates and the debt readjustment index set forth in the civil code for operations carried out by operators, excluding financial entities.”
 
186
Civ. Code Peru Art. 1243: “The conventional maximum loan interest rate is set by the Bank of Reserve of Peru. [Own Translation]”.
 
187
Circular letter 021-2007 of the CRBP [Circular No. 021-2007-BCRP].
 
188
Law 29,947 of Peru [Ley 29.947, Diario Oficial No. 479.481, 28 November 2012].
 
189
Colegio de Abogados de Lima Norte v. Congreso de la República del Perú, TC Peru, Sentencia Exp. No. 011-2013, 27 August 2014.
 
Literature
go back to reference Alesina A, Carrasquilla A, Steiner R (2005) Toward a truly independent Central Bank in Colombia. In: Alesina A (ed) Institutional reforms: the case of Colombia. The MIT Press, pp 337–360 Alesina A, Carrasquilla A, Steiner R (2005) Toward a truly independent Central Bank in Colombia. In: Alesina A (ed) Institutional reforms: the case of Colombia. The MIT Press, pp 337–360
go back to reference Bonilla D (2013) Introduction. In: Bonilla D (ed) Constitutionalism of the global south: the activist tribunals of India, South Africa and Colombia. Cambridge University Press Bonilla D (2013) Introduction. In: Bonilla D (ed) Constitutionalism of the global south: the activist tribunals of India, South Africa and Colombia. Cambridge University Press
go back to reference Carbonari F, Vargas J (2009) A bridge to peace through citizenship building: guaranteeing health and education rights in Colombia. In: Gacitúa-Marió E, Georgieva S, Norton A (eds) Building equality and opportunity through social guarantees. The World Bank, pp 231–257 Carbonari F, Vargas J (2009) A bridge to peace through citizenship building: guaranteeing health and education rights in Colombia. In: Gacitúa-Marió E, Georgieva S, Norton A (eds) Building equality and opportunity through social guarantees. The World Bank, pp 231–257
go back to reference Cerra Nolasco E (2001) El Control de Constitucionalidad. Análisis de la Doctrina de la Corte en los 10 Años de Vigencia Constitucionalidad. Revista de Derecho Universidad del Norte 16:162–179 Cerra Nolasco E (2001) El Control de Constitucionalidad. Análisis de la Doctrina de la Corte en los 10 Años de Vigencia Constitucionalidad. Revista de Derecho Universidad del Norte 16:162–179
go back to reference Dickson B (2007) Judicial activism in common law Supreme Courts. Oxford University Press Dickson B (2007) Judicial activism in common law Supreme Courts. Oxford University Press
go back to reference Kugler M, Rosenthal H (2005) Checks and balances: an assessment of the institutional separation of political powers in Colombia. In: Alesina A (ed) Institutional reforms: the case of Colombia. The MIT Press, pp 75–102 Kugler M, Rosenthal H (2005) Checks and balances: an assessment of the institutional separation of political powers in Colombia. In: Alesina A (ed) Institutional reforms: the case of Colombia. The MIT Press, pp 75–102
go back to reference Mavčič A (2001) Constitutional review. Bookworld Publications Mavčič A (2001) Constitutional review. Bookworld Publications
go back to reference Peters C (2016) Legal formalism, procedural principles, and judicial constraint in American adjudication. In: Pineschi L (ed) General principles of law - the role of the judiciary, Ius Gentium: Comparative Perspectives on Law and Justice, vol. 46. Springer, pp 23–44. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-19180-5_2 Peters C (2016) Legal formalism, procedural principles, and judicial constraint in American adjudication. In: Pineschi L (ed) General principles of law - the role of the judiciary, Ius Gentium: Comparative Perspectives on Law and Justice, vol. 46. Springer, pp 23–44. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1007/​978-3-319-19180-5_​2
go back to reference Ribeiro M (2003) Limiting arbitrary power: the vagueness Doctrine in Canadian constitutional law. UBC Press Ribeiro M (2003) Limiting arbitrary power: the vagueness Doctrine in Canadian constitutional law. UBC Press
go back to reference Rivero Ortega R (2013) Derecho Administrativo Económico, Sexta Edición. Marcial Pons Rivero Ortega R (2013) Derecho Administrativo Económico, Sexta Edición. Marcial Pons
go back to reference Robertson D (2010) The judge as political theorist: contemporary constitutional review. Princeton University Press Robertson D (2010) The judge as political theorist: contemporary constitutional review. Princeton University Press
go back to reference Rodriguez Garavito C, Rodríguez Franco D (2015) Radical deprivation on trial. Cambridge University Press Rodriguez Garavito C, Rodríguez Franco D (2015) Radical deprivation on trial. Cambridge University Press
go back to reference Roosevelt K (2008) The myth of judicial activism: making sense of supreme court decisions. Yale University Press Roosevelt K (2008) The myth of judicial activism: making sense of supreme court decisions. Yale University Press
go back to reference Ruggiero C (2012) Judicial power in a federal system: Canada, United States and Germany. LFB Scholarly Publishing LLC Ruggiero C (2012) Judicial power in a federal system: Canada, United States and Germany. LFB Scholarly Publishing LLC
go back to reference Uprimny R (2006) Legitimidad y Conveniencia del Control Constitucional a la Economía. In: Buitrago F (ed) En la Encrucijada: Colombia en el Siglo XXI, Uniandes Journals, pp 38–68 Uprimny R (2006) Legitimidad y Conveniencia del Control Constitucional a la Economía. In: Buitrago F (ed) En la Encrucijada: Colombia en el Siglo XXI, Uniandes Journals, pp 38–68
Metadata
Title
The Constitutional Court of Colombia Versus Central Bank Autonomy
Author
Andrea Lucia Tapia-Hoffmann
Copyright Year
2021
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-70986-0_6