Skip to main content
Top
Published in: International Tax and Public Finance 6/2022

23-11-2022

The impact of the international tax reforms under Pillar One and Pillar Two on MNE’s investment costs

Authors: Tibor Hanappi, Ana Cinta González Cabral

Published in: International Tax and Public Finance | Issue 6/2022

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Pillar One and Pillar Two would introduce new rules for the taxation of multinational enterprises (MNEs). This paper assesses the impact of these proposals on MNEs’ investment costs. The analytical framework extends the forward-looking effective tax rates (ETR) model of Devereux and Griffith (International Tax and Public Finance 10: 107–126, 2003) to consider the ETRs for an investment performed by an entity belonging to an MNE group accounting for the possibility that MNEs use their organisational structure to shift profits to low tax jurisdictions. The model incorporates a stylised version of the tax provisions proposed under Pillar One and Pillar Two. The results, covering over 70 jurisdictions, account for differences in tax bases and rates, and are empirically calibrated to map the global activities of in-scope MNEs. The global GDP-weighted average change in the EATRs from Pillar One and Pillar Two is estimated to be 0.4 percentage points, representing a small impact compared to the weighted average EATR in the sample (24%) as well as the 6 percentage point reduction observed in the period 1999–2017 across OECD countries. Overall, the analysis suggests that both Pillars would reinforce each other in lifting the floor of the ETR distribution, thus reducing tax rate differentials across jurisdictions.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
The analysis presented in this paper may not represent the latest discussions of the Inclusive Framework on BEPS on the two-pillar solution, but rather focuses on the proposals outlined at the time of publication of the Pillar One and Pillar Two Blueprint reports.
 
2
Extractives and Regulated Financial Services are excluded from the scope of Pillar One. Note also that the reallocation percentage has changed since the Blueprint from 20 to 25% as indicated in the statement.
 
3
The interest in considering both the IIR and UTPR is relevant when considering revenue estimates. Since this paper is focussed on the impact on investment costs, the distribution of revenues through these rules is not a first order consideration. Revenue estimates are available in (OECD, 2020a, 2020b, 2020c, 2020d, 2020e, 2020f, 2020g). Note that as will be discussed in the calibration section, jurisdictions below 15% are assumed to raise their tax rates to the minimum to absorb any revenue loss to Pillar Two. Implicitly, this mimics the effect of the UTPR with the difference being that under the UTPR carved-out profits should not be subject to top-up taxation.
 
4
The profit shifting share, \(\lambda\), is assumed to be the same for both types of profit; however, this assumption could be generalised in future work assigning different profit shifting propensities to routine and residual profit.
 
5
Note that the cost of capital will be affected by Pillar One if the routine return defined by the proposal is sufficiently low that it bites into the gross normal return.
 
6
In the empirical part discussed below, it is assumed that profits can potentially be shifted to any jurisdiction with a statutory rate below the statutory rate in the domestic jurisdiction.
 
7
In general, it would be possible to calibrate the model differently, e.g., reflecting investments in jurisdiction A by MNEs with a UPE in jurisdiction B, depending on the purpose of the analysis.
 
8
The statutory CIT rate for Saudi Arabia is considered to be 20%, which is the statutory CIT rate faced by non-Saudi investors. This corresponds to the rate a 100% foreign-owned company would face in Saudi Arabia. This rate can be higher in certain sectors of activity. While Saudi Arabia levies a zero-rate CIT on the share of profits owned by Saudi investors in sectors other than oil and gas, other tax liabilities arise for domestic investors, i.e., Zakat. Given the focus of the proposals on the taxation of foreign profits and given data limitations, the analysis abstracts from modelling of Zakat liabilities.
 
9
It would be possible to aggregate these assets based on their average weight in jurisdictions’ capital stock. This would be pursued as part of future work. The equal averaging used in this paper ensures alignment with the methodology in Corporate Tax Statistics (OECD, 2020a, 2020b, 2020c, 2020d, 2020e, 2020f, 2020g).
 
10
The economic depreciation rate of tangible assets is a weighted average rate of the economic depreciation of movable and immovable tangible assets using 2018 US capital stocks.
Share of shifted profits.
 
11
It might be the case that profits are shifted to locations with higher statutory tax rates where the effective rate that applies to these profits are lower than that in the parent jurisdiction. This might be the case when preferential tax regimes are in place, e.g. patent boxes. Given that these preferential regimes are not modelled in this framework, profit shifting behaviour is assumed, as in most of the empirical literature, to respond to statutory tax rates.
 
12
Note that the use of the micro-level estimate might be downwards biased due to the lack of universal coverage of profits in low-tax jurisdictions as well as the presence of non-linearities not accounted for in the estimation. The macro-level estimate is biased towards the higher end of the spectrum and might also be an overestimate due to the failure to control for firm-specific characteristics (Clausing 2016, 2018, 2020).
 
13
As is the case for other profit measures discussed in this note, routine profit can be interpreted equivalently as a profit measure or as a return on investment, given that the analysis considers a capital investment of one unit.
 
14
To see this, consider the case where the firm-specific profitability ratio, \({\varphi }_{i}\), equals 12.5% and the profitability threshold is defined as \(\overline{\varphi }=10\mathrm{\%}\). In this case, the share of routine returns in total profit is equal to 80% and the share of non-routine profits in total profits is equal to 20%.
 
15
Table 2.3 in (OECD, 2020a, 2020b, 2020c, 2020d, 2020e, 2020f, 2020g) includes summary statistics of global residual profit estimated for in scope MNEs in the ADS and CFB sectors for different profitability thresholds. The ratios discussed here are based in the same data.
 
16
The calibration of \(\widehat{r}\) matches jurisdiction level averages based on firm level data; although it captures variation in profitability across jurisdictions, a firm level calibration could be developed using more comprehensive microdata.
 
17
Extrapolations are used wherever the data on activities of domestic MNEs is not available (OECD, 2020a, 2020b, 2020c, 2020d, 2020e, 2020f, 2020g).
 
18
Note that the effect of nexus elements of the Pillar One proposal are not accounted for in this paper.
 
19
All in all, the share of residual profits varies across jurisdictions depending on the average share of residual to total profits of firms’ in scope. Once the share of residual profit is determined it is reallocated to market jurisdictions to be ultimately taxed at a weighted rate of 26%.
 
20
The agreed rate for the GloBE rules are 15% with jurisdictional blending.
 
21
Note that the effect of this assumption on the results is modest. Low-taxed profits not taxed under an IIR would nonetheless be subject to top-up tax under the UTPR. The difference between the country raising its tax rate or it being subject to top-up tax is the increase in investment costs coming from the increased taxation of carved-out profits. Given that carved-out profits are found to be modest, the increase in investment costs coming from this assumption is not significant. See Chapter 3 in OECD (2020a, 2020b, 2020c, 2020d, 2020e, 2020f, 2020g).
 
22
While other variables such as investment may be desirable, the only variables available to us were based on tangible assets failing to account for importance of intangible assets in the asset mix. Profits were also another variable considered but the presence of losses can potentially bias the weights. Furthermore, EATRs are calculated for a firm in profit and loss-making provisions are not accounted for. Considering positive profits could also be an option but would fail to consider that Pillar One does not affect firms in a loss-making position.
 
23
Among firms in-scope, the existence of an SBIE would mean that only a share of the profits for these firms would be subject to Pillar Two. This is accounted for in the ETR estimation.
 
24
The same data limitations outlined for Pillar One in footnote 31 apply also for Pillar Two.
 
25
To illustrate the limited impact of the design scope of Pillar One being modelled, the turnover of firms in-scope of Pillar One as defined above only account for 10% of the turnover of all MNEs in the analysis.
 
26
Note that the positive effect of the reform on ETRs on investments by in-scope firms in low and middle income jurisdictions turns negative when considering the global average; this effect is driven by the jurisdiction-specific weighting of in and out of scope firms, which occurs before GDP-weighting across jurisdictions.
 
27
To account for the assumption that Pillar Two only applies to MNEs with revenues above EUR 750 million, the impact of Pillar Two is weighted by the share of turnover from MNEs above the EUR 750 million threshold. While this subset of MNEs still includes over 90% of the turnover of all firms in the economy, only those with low-taxed profits will be affected by Pillar Two.
 
28
Pillar One (Amount A only) considers a 10% profitability threshold on Profit/Turnover, 20% reallocation percentage to market and a scope that is restricted to ADS and CFB activities. Pillar Two considers a 12.5% rate with jurisdiction blending and a 10% carve-out on depreciation expenses (approximated using the value of tangible assets), see Sect. 1.4 for additional modelling assumptions. The combined effect expressed here does not account for the interaction between the two pillars. However, this effect is deemed to be very small, given the modest impact of Pillar One. This is supported by findings from the revenue estimate that arrive at similar conclusions (see Chapter 2 in OECD (2020a, 2020b, 2020c, 2020d, 2020e, 2020f, 2020g)).
 
Literature
go back to reference Barrios, S. et al. (2012), International taxation and multinational firm location decisions. Barrios, S. et al. (2012), International taxation and multinational firm location decisions.
go back to reference Cadestin, C., et al. (2018). Multinational enterprises and global value chains: The OECD analytical AMNE database. OECD Publishing, Paris. Cadestin, C., et al. (2018). Multinational enterprises and global value chains: The OECD analytical AMNE database. OECD Publishing, Paris.
go back to reference Davies, R., Siedschlag I. and Studnicka Z. (2021), The impact of taxes on the extensive and intensive margins of FDI. Davies, R., Siedschlag I. and Studnicka Z. (2021), The impact of taxes on the extensive and intensive margins of FDI.
go back to reference Egger, P. et al. (2009b), Firm-specific forward-looking effective tax rates. Egger, P. et al. (2009b), Firm-specific forward-looking effective tax rates.
go back to reference Egger, P. et al. (2009a), Bilateral effective tax rates and foreign direct investment. Egger, P. et al. (2009a), Bilateral effective tax rates and foreign direct investment.
go back to reference Feld, L. and Heckemeyer J. (2011), Fdi and taxation: A meta-study. Feld, L. and Heckemeyer J. (2011), Fdi and taxation: A meta-study.
go back to reference Grubert, H. and Altshuler R. (2013b), fixing the system: An analysis of alternative proposals for the reform of international tax. Grubert, H. and Altshuler R. (2013b), fixing the system: An analysis of alternative proposals for the reform of international tax.
go back to reference Grubert, H., & Altshuler, R. (2013a). Fixing the system: An analysis of alternative proposals for the reform of international tax. National Tax Journal, 66(3), 671–712.CrossRef Grubert, H., & Altshuler, R. (2013a). Fixing the system: An analysis of alternative proposals for the reform of international tax. National Tax Journal, 66(3), 671–712.CrossRef
go back to reference Jorgenson, D. and Hall R. (1967), “Tax policy and investment behavior”, American Economic Review, Vol. 57/3. Jorgenson, D. and Hall R. (1967), “Tax policy and investment behavior”, American Economic Review, Vol. 57/3.
go back to reference Maffini, G., Xing J. and Devereux M. (2019), The impact of investment incentives: Evidence from UK Corporation Tax Returns. Maffini, G., Xing J. and Devereux M. (2019), The impact of investment incentives: Evidence from UK Corporation Tax Returns.
go back to reference de Mooij, R. and Ederveen S. (2006), What a difference does it make? Understanding the empirical literature on taxation and international capital flows. de Mooij, R. and Ederveen S. (2006), What a difference does it make? Understanding the empirical literature on taxation and international capital flows.
go back to reference De Mooij, R. and Liu L. (2018), At a cost: The real effects of transfer pricing regulations. De Mooij, R. and Liu L. (2018), At a cost: The real effects of transfer pricing regulations.
go back to reference OECD (2020g), “Technical note on the methodology to assess the tax revenue effects of Pillar Two” No. CTPA/CFA/WP2/NOE2(2020g)1. OECD (2020g), “Technical note on the methodology to assess the tax revenue effects of Pillar Two” No. CTPA/CFA/WP2/NOE2(2020g)1.
go back to reference OECD. (2021b). Tax challenges arising from the digitalisation of the economy–global anti-base erosion model rules (Pillar Two): Inclusive framework on BEPS. OECD. OECD. (2021b). Tax challenges arising from the digitalisation of the economy–global anti-base erosion model rules (Pillar Two): Inclusive framework on BEPS. OECD.
go back to reference Petkova, K., Stasio A. and Zagler M. (2020), On the relevance of double tax treaties. Petkova, K., Stasio A. and Zagler M. (2020), On the relevance of double tax treaties.
go back to reference Steinmüller, E., Thunecke G. and Wamser G. (2019), Corporate income taxes around the world: a survey on forward-looking tax measures and two applications. Steinmüller, E., Thunecke G. and Wamser G. (2019), Corporate income taxes around the world: a survey on forward-looking tax measures and two applications.
go back to reference Turban, S., Sorbe, S., Millot, V., & Johansson, Å. (2020). A set of matrices to map the location of profit and economic activity of multinational enterprises. OECD Taxation Working Papers 52, OECD Publishing. Turban, S., Sorbe, S., Millot, V., & Johansson, Å. (2020). A set of matrices to map the location of profit and economic activity of multinational enterprises. OECD Taxation Working Papers 52, OECD Publishing.
go back to reference van ‘t Riet, M. and Lejour, A. (2018), Optimal tax routing: Network analysis of FDI diversion. van ‘t Riet, M. and Lejour, A. (2018), Optimal tax routing: Network analysis of FDI diversion.
go back to reference Zwick, E. and J. Mahon (2017), Tax Policy and Heterogeneous Investment Behavior. Zwick, E. and J. Mahon (2017), Tax Policy and Heterogeneous Investment Behavior.
Metadata
Title
The impact of the international tax reforms under Pillar One and Pillar Two on MNE’s investment costs
Authors
Tibor Hanappi
Ana Cinta González Cabral
Publication date
23-11-2022
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
International Tax and Public Finance / Issue 6/2022
Print ISSN: 0927-5940
Electronic ISSN: 1573-6970
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-022-09750-0

Other articles of this Issue 6/2022

International Tax and Public Finance 6/2022 Go to the issue