Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Social Choice and Welfare 3-4/2017

24-10-2016 | Original Paper

The political choice of social long term care transfers when family gives time and money

Authors: Philippe De Donder, Marie-Louise Leroux

Published in: Social Choice and Welfare | Issue 3-4/2017

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We develop a model where families consist of one parent and one child, with children differing in income and all agents having the same probability of becoming dependent when old. Young and old individuals vote over the size of a social long term care transfer (LTC hereafter) program, which children complement with help in time or money to their dependent parent. Dependent parents have an intrinsic preference for help in time by family members. We first show that low (resp., high) income children provide help in time (resp. in money), whose amount is decreasing (resp. increasing) with the child’s income. The middle income class may give no family help at all, and its elderly members would be the main beneficiaries of the introduction of social LTC transfers. We then provide several reasons for the stylized fact that there are little social LTC transfers in most countries. First, social transfers are dominated by help in time by the family when the intrinsic preference of dependent parents for the latter is large enough. Second, when the probability of becoming dependent is lower than one third, the children of autonomous parents are numerous enough to oppose democratically the introduction of social LTC transfers. Third, even when none of the first two conditions is satisfied, the majority voting equilibrium may entail no social transfers, especially if the probability of becoming dependent when old is not far above one third. This equilibrium may be local (meaning that it would be defeated by the introduction of a sufficiently large social program). This local majority equilibrium may be empirically relevant whenever new programs have to be introduced at a low scale before being eventually ramped up.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
OECD (2011, chapter 7) provides a detailed taxonomy of public LTC systems within the OECD. For broader surveys on long term care, see Brown and Finkelstein (2011) and Cremer et al. (2009).
 
2
It is also associated with the desire of most people to remain in their own homes for as long as possible. Recent polling by the Canadian Life and Health Insurance Association, reported in Frank (2012) found that 77 percent of Canadians would prefer to stay in their homes as they age. See also Torjman (2013).
 
3
The same assumption is made by Nuscheler and Roeder (2013), which we cover in Sect. 1.1. Costa Font et al. (2014) contrast ex ante financing of LTC (such as insurance) with ex post financing (such as transfers, as in our model). They find that most OECD countries’ LTC spending is financed by close to a fifty-fifty mix of ex-ante and ex-post funding sources or that the spending relies heavily on ex-post funding sources. They also obtain that OECD countries view the two forms of funding as substitutes rather than complements.
 
4
Sloan et al. (1997) find little empirical support for the hypothesis that care giving by children is motivated by the prospect of receiving bequests from their parents. Kopczuk and Lupton (2007) also find no empirical evidence of strategic bequests.
 
5
We are interested in how much (more) young agents help their parent in case of dependency, so that any help to a non-dependent parent can be subsumed in the existing model. Note that we also assume away (so-called descending) altruism from parents to children to focus on help by children to parents. In the appendix, we show that introducing descending altruism would not change children preferences toward the tax rate, while parents (both autonomous and dependent) would prefer a lower value of the tax rate. Introducing descending altruism would then bias our results toward even less public LTC transfers.
 
6
Pestieau and Sato (2006, 2008) make the same assumption, although it remains implicit in their setting. This assumption requires that we assume away saving, strategic interactions between parents and children (such as exchanges of help for bequests) and that the size of the public LTC program is chosen at each period. See footnote 4 for the lack of strategic motivations for family help, and footnote 14 for a defence of the last assumption above.
 
7
Finkelstein et al. (2013) show that the marginal utility from consumption varies with health status.
 
8
We leave for future research the case where old agents differ in income, and where children and parental income within a family are correlated.
 
9
We can either assume that \(v(d,e)<0\) or subtract a constant term large enough in the definition of \(U_{Y}^{D}\) to make sure that \( U_{Y}^{N}>U_{Y}^{D}\). Note that this does not affect our analysis, since children do not choose to make their parent dependent or not.
 
10
Assuming away labor income tax distortions biases the model in favor of the introduction of social LTC transfers (since distortions would decrease the most-preferred value of \(\tau \) of agents).
 
11
Alternatively, we could have assumed that the benefit b decreases linearly with the child’s income w. This would have generated the same kind of redistributive effects.
 
12
This formulation is made not only for analytical convenience, but also because it is more consistent with the empirical results than the alternative formulation where net income is \((1-\tau )w(1-e)\). The latter formulation means that the marginal cost of e decreases with \(\tau \), while the marginal cost of \(\tau \) decreases with e, so that e and \(\tau \) could be complements rather than substitutes in our approach. Sloan et al. (2002), Houtven and Norton (2004) and Charles and Sevak (2005) find that informal care is a substitute for home health care, nursing home care, hospital care and physician visits.
 
13
Karagyozova and Siegelman (2012) review the empirical literature on relative risk aversion. They report several studies which find a coefficient of relative risk aversion lower than one. Hansen and Singleton (1983) evaluate it to be between [0.35, 1]; Holt and Laury (2002) elicit the distribution of coefficients of relative risk aversion and find that \(64\,\%\) of respondents had a coefficient comprised between 0.15 and 0.97. Chetty (2006) finds that “using 33 sets of estimates of wage and income elasticities, the mean implied value of (the coefficient of relative risk aversion) is 0.71, with a range of 0.15 to 1.78 in the additive utility case.” Assumption 2 is then reasonable.
 
14
The alternative assumption that the result of a vote would hold for decades does not seem reasonable to us. The literature on the political economy of pensions often assumes that voting takes place once and for all (see for instance, Casamatta et al. (2000) and Cremer et al. (2007)), but this assumption is a pis-aller to explain the emergence of pay-as-you-go social transfer schemes in the absence of altruism. The presence of altruism in our model makes the unpalatable assumption of voting once and for all not necessary.
 
15
The boundaries of this “middle class” are obtained analytically by (i) setting \(V_{Ye}=0\) for \(f=e=0\) and solving for \( w<\beta \) (to obtain its lowerbound), and (ii) by setting \(V_{Yf}=0\) for \( f=e=0\) and solving for \(w>\beta \) (to obtain its upperbound). All figures are based on the following assumptions: \(u(x)=2\sqrt{x},\) \(v(d,e)=ln[d+\beta e]\), \(\pi =0.5\), \({\bar{w}}=5\), \(T=2\), \({\bar{p}}=4\), \(\beta =5\). In Fig. 1, we assume moreover that \(\tau =0\) and \(\alpha =1\).
 
16
Proceeding simultaneously proves much easier to obtain the individually optimal amounts of \(\tau \), e and f than proceeding sequentially and using the envelope theorem, because of the frequent corner solutions for the variables.
 
17
In order to focus on empirically relevant situations and not to multiply cases, we assume from now on that no young agent with a dependent parent most prefers \(\tau _{Y}^{*}\ge 1\), which could in theory occur in our setting with untaxed labor income \(w(T-1)\). This condition is satisfied if
$$\begin{aligned} wu^{\prime }\left( w\left( T-1\right) \right) >\alpha \frac{{\bar{w}}}{\pi }\phi ^{\prime }\left( {\bar{p}}+ \frac{{\bar{w}}}{\pi }\right) . \end{aligned}$$
 
18
Figs. 2 and 3 differ only in the value of \(\alpha \). In both figures, all agents prefer either \(\tau ^{*}>0\) or \(f^{*}>0\). The curve \(\beta e^{*}(0,w)\) (as in Fig. 1) is only depicted here to allow the comparison with \(\tau ^{*}{\bar{w}}/\pi \) when \(\tau ^{*}\) is set at its most-preferred level for individual w.
 
19
The case where \(\beta >{\bar{w}}/\pi \) is available upon request but not reported here since the majority chosen value of \(\tau \) is zero in that case.
 
20
Assuming that they throw a dice to determine which value of \(\tau \) to vote for would not affect our results. Alternatively, we could assume that autonomous parents vote in favor of the best alternative for their child, that is for \(\tau ^{*}=0\). In that case, no group forms a majority by itself with \(0<\pi <1\), and the necessary condition for \(\tau ^{*}>0\) becomes \(\pi >1/2\), a more stringent condition than the one we obtain after Lemma 1.
 
21
We assume throughout the paper that dependency does not prevent old agents from voting (because of cognitive issues, for instance). If all dependent agents were prevented from voting, the Condorcet winning value of the tax rate would be zero if \(F({\bar{w}}/\pi )<1/2\pi \) (which always holds if \(\pi <1/2\)), thanks to an alliance of young agents with autonomous parents, and of young agents with dependent parents and \(w\ge {\bar{w}}/\pi \). If \(F(\bar{w }/\pi )>1/2\pi \), then the Condorcet winning value of \(\tau \) is positive, and the decisive voter is a young agent with a dependent parent and a productivity \(w<{\bar{w}}/\pi \) such that \(F^{-1}(w)=1/2\pi \).
 
22
It is easy to show, using the implicit function theorem on (1), that \(\breve{w}\) decreases with \(\pi \).
 
23
The assumption mentioned in footnote 17 implies that this threshold is lower than 1.
 
24
The assumption mentioned in footnote 17 implies that \(f^{*}(\tau ,w)=0\) for \(\tau >{\tilde{\tau }}\) with \({\tilde{\tau }}<1\).
 
25
It is immediate that \(f^{*}(0,{\bar{w}}/\pi )<{\bar{w}}/\pi .\)
 
Literature
go back to reference Bonsang E (2007) How do middle-aged children allocate time and money transfers to their older parents in Europe? Empirica 34:171–188CrossRef Bonsang E (2007) How do middle-aged children allocate time and money transfers to their older parents in Europe? Empirica 34:171–188CrossRef
go back to reference Bonsang E (2009) Does informal care from children to their elderly parents substitute for formal care in Europe? J Health Econ 28:143–154CrossRef Bonsang E (2009) Does informal care from children to their elderly parents substitute for formal care in Europe? J Health Econ 28:143–154CrossRef
go back to reference Brown JR, Finkelstein A (2009) The private market for long-term care insurance in the United States: a review of the evidence. J Risk Insur 76:5–29CrossRef Brown JR, Finkelstein A (2009) The private market for long-term care insurance in the United States: a review of the evidence. J Risk Insur 76:5–29CrossRef
go back to reference Brown JR, Finkelstein A (2011) Insuring long-term care in the United States. J Econ Perspect 25(4):119–142CrossRef Brown JR, Finkelstein A (2011) Insuring long-term care in the United States. J Econ Perspect 25(4):119–142CrossRef
go back to reference Casamatta G, Cremer H, Pestieau P (2000) The political economy of social security. Scand J Econ 102(3):503–522CrossRef Casamatta G, Cremer H, Pestieau P (2000) The political economy of social security. Scand J Econ 102(3):503–522CrossRef
go back to reference Charles K, Sevak P (2005) Can family caregiving substitute for nursing home care? J Health Econ 24:1174–1190CrossRef Charles K, Sevak P (2005) Can family caregiving substitute for nursing home care? J Health Econ 24:1174–1190CrossRef
go back to reference Chetty R (2006) A new method of estimating risk aversion. Am Econ Rev 96(5):1821–1836CrossRef Chetty R (2006) A new method of estimating risk aversion. Am Econ Rev 96(5):1821–1836CrossRef
go back to reference Costa Font J, Courbage C, Swartz K (2014) Financing long-term care: ex-ante, ex-post or both? CESifo Working Paper 5104 Costa Font J, Courbage C, Swartz K (2014) Financing long-term care: ex-ante, ex-post or both? CESifo Working Paper 5104
go back to reference Couch K, Daly M, Wolf D (1999) Time? Money? Both? The allocation of resources to older parents. Demography 36:219–232CrossRef Couch K, Daly M, Wolf D (1999) Time? Money? Both? The allocation of resources to older parents. Demography 36:219–232CrossRef
go back to reference Cremer H, De Donder P, Maldonado D, Pestieau P (2007) Voting over the size and type of social security when some individuals are myopic. J public Econ 91(10):2041–2061CrossRef Cremer H, De Donder P, Maldonado D, Pestieau P (2007) Voting over the size and type of social security when some individuals are myopic. J public Econ 91(10):2041–2061CrossRef
go back to reference Cremer H, Roeder K (2013) Long-term care and lazy rotten kids, CESifo Working Paper 4372 Cremer H, Roeder K (2013) Long-term care and lazy rotten kids, CESifo Working Paper 4372
go back to reference De Donder Ph (2013) Majority voting and the single crossing property when voters belong to separate groups. Econ Lett 118(3):523–525CrossRef De Donder Ph (2013) Majority voting and the single crossing property when voters belong to separate groups. Econ Lett 118(3):523–525CrossRef
go back to reference De Donder Ph., Leroux M-L (2013) Behavioral biases and long term care annuities: a political economy approach. The B.E. J Econ Anal Policy (Adv) 14(2):551–575 De Donder Ph., Leroux M-L (2013) Behavioral biases and long term care annuities: a political economy approach. The B.E. J Econ Anal Policy (Adv) 14(2):551–575
go back to reference De Donder Ph., Pestieau P (2015) Private, social and self insurance for long-term care in the presence of family help: a political economy analysis. J Public Econ Theory (forthcoming) De Donder Ph., Pestieau P (2015) Private, social and self insurance for long-term care in the presence of family help: a political economy analysis. J Public Econ Theory (forthcoming)
go back to reference Epple D, Romano R (1996) Public provision of private goods. J Political Econ 104(1):57–84CrossRef Epple D, Romano R (1996) Public provision of private goods. J Political Econ 104(1):57–84CrossRef
go back to reference Finkelstein A, Luttmer E, Notowidigdo M (2013) What good is wealth without health? The effect of health on the marginal utility of consumption. J Eur Econ Assoc 11:221–258CrossRef Finkelstein A, Luttmer E, Notowidigdo M (2013) What good is wealth without health? The effect of health on the marginal utility of consumption. J Eur Econ Assoc 11:221–258CrossRef
go back to reference Frank S (2012) Boomers will have to pay for much of their own long-term care. The Ottawa Citizen, 2 Sept Frank S (2012) Boomers will have to pay for much of their own long-term care. The Ottawa Citizen, 2 Sept
go back to reference Gans J, Smart M (1996) Majority voting with single-crossing preferences. J Public Econ 59:219–237CrossRef Gans J, Smart M (1996) Majority voting with single-crossing preferences. J Public Econ 59:219–237CrossRef
go back to reference Hansen LP, Singleton KJ (1983) Stochastic consumption, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of asset returns. J Political Econ 91(2):249–265CrossRef Hansen LP, Singleton KJ (1983) Stochastic consumption, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of asset returns. J Political Econ 91(2):249–265CrossRef
go back to reference Holt CA, Laury SK (2002) Risk aversion and incentive effects. Am Econ Rev 92(5):1644–1655CrossRef Holt CA, Laury SK (2002) Risk aversion and incentive effects. Am Econ Rev 92(5):1644–1655CrossRef
go back to reference Jousten A, Lipszyc B, Marchand M, Pestieau P (2005) Long-term care insurance and optimal taxation for altruistic children. FinanzArchiv 61:1–18CrossRef Jousten A, Lipszyc B, Marchand M, Pestieau P (2005) Long-term care insurance and optimal taxation for altruistic children. FinanzArchiv 61:1–18CrossRef
go back to reference Karagyozova T, Siegelman P (2012) Can propitious selection stabilize insurance markets? J Insur issues 35(2):121–158 Karagyozova T, Siegelman P (2012) Can propitious selection stabilize insurance markets? J Insur issues 35(2):121–158
go back to reference Kopczuk W, Lupton J (2007) To leave or not to leave: the distribution of bequests motives. Rev Econ Stud 74:207–235CrossRef Kopczuk W, Lupton J (2007) To leave or not to leave: the distribution of bequests motives. Rev Econ Stud 74:207–235CrossRef
go back to reference Nuscheler R, Roeder K (2013) The political economy of long-term care. Eur Econ Rev 62:154–173CrossRef Nuscheler R, Roeder K (2013) The political economy of long-term care. Eur Econ Rev 62:154–173CrossRef
go back to reference OECD (2011) Help wanted? Providing and paying for long-term care. OECD Publishing, Paris OECD (2011) Help wanted? Providing and paying for long-term care. OECD Publishing, Paris
go back to reference Pestieau P, Sato M (2006) Long-term care: the state and the family. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique 83(84):151–166CrossRef Pestieau P, Sato M (2006) Long-term care: the state and the family. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique 83(84):151–166CrossRef
go back to reference Pestieau P, Sato M (2008) Long-term care: the state, the market and the family. Economica 299:435–454CrossRef Pestieau P, Sato M (2008) Long-term care: the state, the market and the family. Economica 299:435–454CrossRef
go back to reference Pestieau P, Sato M (2009) Social and private long term care insurance with variable altruism (unpublished mimeo) Pestieau P, Sato M (2009) Social and private long term care insurance with variable altruism (unpublished mimeo)
go back to reference Pinquart M, Soerensen S (2002) Older adults’ preferences for informal, formal, and mixed support for future care needs: a comparison of Germany and the United States. Int J aging Hum Dev 54(4):291–314CrossRef Pinquart M, Soerensen S (2002) Older adults’ preferences for informal, formal, and mixed support for future care needs: a comparison of Germany and the United States. Int J aging Hum Dev 54(4):291–314CrossRef
go back to reference Sloan F, Picone G, Hoerger T (1997) The supply of children ’s time to disabled elderly parents. Econ Inq 35:295–308CrossRef Sloan F, Picone G, Hoerger T (1997) The supply of children ’s time to disabled elderly parents. Econ Inq 35:295–308CrossRef
go back to reference Sloan F, Zhang H, Wang J (2002) Upstream intergenerational transfers. South Econ J 69:363–380CrossRef Sloan F, Zhang H, Wang J (2002) Upstream intergenerational transfers. South Econ J 69:363–380CrossRef
go back to reference Stigler G (1970) Director’s law of public income redistribution. J Law Econ 13(1):1–10CrossRef Stigler G (1970) Director’s law of public income redistribution. J Law Econ 13(1):1–10CrossRef
go back to reference Torjman S (2013) Financing long-term care: more money in the mix. Caledon Institute of Social Policy, Ottawa Torjman S (2013) Financing long-term care: more money in the mix. Caledon Institute of Social Policy, Ottawa
go back to reference Van Houtven C, Norton E (2004) Informal care and health care use of older adults. J Health Econ 23:1159–1180CrossRef Van Houtven C, Norton E (2004) Informal care and health care use of older adults. J Health Econ 23:1159–1180CrossRef
go back to reference Zissimopoulos (2001) Resource transfers to the elderly: do adult children substitute financial transfers for time transfers? RAND Working Paper 01–05 Zissimopoulos (2001) Resource transfers to the elderly: do adult children substitute financial transfers for time transfers? RAND Working Paper 01–05
Metadata
Title
The political choice of social long term care transfers when family gives time and money
Authors
Philippe De Donder
Marie-Louise Leroux
Publication date
24-10-2016
Publisher
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Published in
Social Choice and Welfare / Issue 3-4/2017
Print ISSN: 0176-1714
Electronic ISSN: 1432-217X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-016-0999-3

Other articles of this Issue 3-4/2017

Social Choice and Welfare 3-4/2017 Go to the issue