Skip to main content
Top
Published in: International Tax and Public Finance 2/2024

Open Access 27-06-2023

Till taxes keep us apart? The impact of the marriage tax on the marriage rate

Author: Nadia Myohl

Published in: International Tax and Public Finance | Issue 2/2024

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Married couples can face a higher or lower tax burden than cohabitating couples with the same income when the former are taxed as one unit. I study the effect of such joint income taxation on the marriage rate in Switzerland, where tax differentials between married and cohabitating couples vary considerably across cantons. For this purpose, I construct a dataset containing sociodemographic and -economic variables on every individual living in Switzerland and use household-level information to identify cohabitating couples. Using a simulated instrumental variable approach, I find a negative impact of joint income taxation on the marriage rate for couples married between 2012 and 2019. The effect is driven by households without children and from the lower end of the income distribution.
Notes

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

1 Introduction

Taxes affect human behavior, such as influencing the timing of capital gains realizations, birth and even death. 1 Similarly, the marriage tax2 can impact a couple’s timing and decision3 to marry, depending on whether it presents in the form of a marriage penalty or subsidy. 4 But why does this matter for the economy at large?
Benefit payouts from social insurance such as survivor’s- or old-age insurance are often tied to the marriage status and have been shown to affect the marriage market (Persson, 2020). A reduced marriage rate may therefore have negative implications in the case of adverse health- or income shocks both for unmarried couples themselves, but also for the economy at large as it implies a potentially higher take-up of other insurances such as social assistance. Moreover, marriage can directly be linked to fertility, with married women displaying a higher fertility rate than their unmarried counterparts (Gutiérrez & Becerra, 2012). Many governments are successfully promoting fertility through maternity leave (Lalive & Zweimüller, 2009; Raute, 2019; Malkova, 2018) and child benefits (Cohen et al., 2013; González, 2013; Milligan, 2005) as low fertility rates, which are not offset by higher immigration, negatively impact the demographic structure and therefore future labor markets and social insurances. These implications of a reduced marriage rate therefore warrant a closer inspection of potential marriage distortions that arise through joint taxation systems.
Joint income taxation is practiced in a range of countries such as France, the USA, Germany, or Switzerland. The latter is a particularly interesting case to study due to its strong federal structure: The majority of income taxes are paid to the cantons and municipalities, which leads to considerable differences across cantons in the tax system in general and the tax burden in particular. The marriage tax can be quite substantial depending on the couple’s income and their place of residence.5 This paper exploits this sub-national variation in the marriage tax in Switzerland to analyze the impact of the marriage tax on the marriage rate. I use individual-level administrative data on the living and income situation of the universe of the Swiss population and identify cohabitating couples using household-level information.
To estimate the causal impact of the marriage tax on the marriage rate, I use simulated instrumental variables, where the actual marriage tax a couple faces is instrumented by the average marriage tax a random sample of couples would face in the same canton. This approach deals with a potential bias arising due to both measurement error and omitted variables. While income should be measured correctly in the administrative dataset, I cannot rule out measurement error in the marriage tax, as it is estimated using income and household characteristics. An omitted variable bias may arise due to time-varying unobserved variables such as education jointly impacting the explanatory and outcome variables, i.e., marriage tax and status, respectively.
Using a subsample of couples who got married between 2012 and 2019, I find that a 1 percentage point (pp) higher marriage tax as a percentage of net joint income decreases the probability that a couple is married by \(13.7\%\). I focus on couples who get married in the observed time period to avoid potential biases due to the inclusion of couples who married well before I observe them, or who will never marry6, so one can also think of this effect as a delay in marriage. Taking into account the sample period as well as the average marriage rate in the subsample, this indicates that a 1pp higher marriage tax delays the marriage of a couple by 13 months. Among all couples, I observe the strongest behavioral impact on couples without children living in the same household and at the lower end of the overall income distribution. These are also the couples who are most likely to experience a marriage subsidy, indicating that loss aversion may play a role. The results are robust to sample variations and alternative sampling of the simulated instrument.
There is extensive literature on the behavioral effects of taxes for non-financial outcomes. Dickert-Conlin and Chandra (1999) show that child tax benefits that depend on the birthyear can cause parents to prepone births from early January to late December. Additionally, Kopczuk and Slemrod (2003) find that the other end of the lifecycle can also be affected by taxes: Changes in estate tax law influence the timing of death, though they cannot rule out that times of death are manipulated through decisions to end life support or by reporting altered times of death.
Other major life decisions such as marriage are also affected by taxes. Previous literature has shown that an increase in the income marriage tax decreases the marriage rate in the USA both on an individual (Fisher, 2013; Alm & Whittington, 1999) and aggregate level (Alm & Whittington, 1995). Alm et al. (1999) find that the marriage penalty is higher for couples with equal within-household income distribution, while marriage is advantageous for those with dissimilar earnings. In addition, Baker et al. (2004) show the positive impact of the removal of a marriage tax in the Canadian survivor’s pension system on the re-marriage rate of widows. Friedberg & Isaac (2022) use a sudden change in the tax treatment of same-sex couples in the USA to demonstrate that an increase in the marriage subsidy increases the marriage rate. Similarly to birth and death timing, individuals also respond to taxes when it comes to marriage timing. Fink (2020) finds that couples with very unequal within-household income distributions prepone their marriage to an earlier year in Germany, as they can take advantage of a marriage subsidy. Frazier and McKeehan (2018) and Alm and Whittington (1997) show the opposite for the USA, where couples are more likely to delay their marriage to the first quarter of a new year when the marriage tax increases, as it tends to present as a marriage penalty.
I contribute to this literature by exploiting Swiss administrative data that include detailed demographic and income variables. This allows me to study the full universe of the population of a country with substantial sub-national variation in the tax code. The panel nature of the dataset also allows me to follow the same couples over time. All the above-mentioned papers, on the other hand, rely on cross-sectional survey data, therefore only focusing on a subsample and relying on datasets that may be prone to errors due to biased reporting. As a further drawback, all but Fisher (2013) and Friedberg & Isaac (2022) include any unmarried individual in their analysis, whereas I only include cohabitating couples, thus reducing a potential downward bias due to the inclusion of individuals who may never marry. I additionally provide a roadmap for other researchers for identifying unmarried couples in administrative datasets when households can be observed, but the relationship between members is unknown.
This paper is most closely related to Fisher (2013) and Friedberg & Isaac (2022) both in method and research question. While their results show similar signs as mine, there are some differences worth mentioning. I estimate an impact of the marriage tax on the marriage rate, which is around 10 times larger than the ones found in Fisher (2013) and Friedberg & Isaac (2022). This may be surprising at first but can be explained by cultural differences in the value of cohabitation and marriage in the USA and Switzerland: While in the USA cohabitation is considered to be an alternative to being single, it is more likely to be an alternative or prelude to marriage in Northern and Western Europe (Rindfuss & VandenHeuvel, 1990; Heuveline & Timberlake, 2004).7
Finally, I identify specific mechanisms that drive the responses to a higher marriage tax in Switzerland. In line with Fisher (2013) and Friedberg & Isaac (2022), I find that childless couples and those from the lowest income quintile react stronger to a higher marriage tax. My findings on the effects by marriage penalty and subsidy, however, are in contrast to Fisher (2013), who does not find any differential effects regarding the type of marriage tax.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: I describe the Swiss tax system in Section 2 and present the data and sample selection as well as descriptive evidence in Section 3. Section 4 discusses the empirical strategy and results. Section 5 concludes.

2 The Swiss tax system

Switzerland raises direct taxes on income and wealth of both individuals and companies, as well as indirect taxes on consumer goods such as value added, petroleum and tobacco. This paper focuses on the income tax paid by individuals, which is described in more detail in the following sections.

2.1 Taxation of natural persons

Individuals pay both income and wealth taxes in Switzerland. Since wealth is per default considered to be the property of both spouses for married couples and couples in a registered partnership8, it is taxed jointly. Individuals pay income tax on their income from employment, wealth (movable and non-movable) and replacement income (pensions, unemployment insurance, etc.) (ESTV, 2018). In what follows, I will focus on the income tax from employment only, as wealth data are not easily available and the wealth tax burden is relatively small (Brülhart et al., 2022).9
Any individual living and working in Switzerland needs to pay taxes on their income. Income taxes are levied on three levels: the federal, cantonal and municipal level.10 The tax is paid in the canton and municipality of main residence, i.e., a person living in the city of Zurich and working in Basel would pay income tax to the federal government, the canton of Zurich and the city of Zurich, even though the place of employment is Basel. Income that is generated through usage of property or businesses, however, is taxed in the municipality and canton where the property or business is located (so-called limited taxation). The revenue from individual income taxation is the biggest source of tax revenue across all levels of government (2015: \(38.8\%\)), of which around 20% go to the federal government, 47% to the cantons and 33% to the municipalities (ESTV, 2018). Tax schedules differ across cantons, while within cantons tax rates also differ across municipalities. Cantons present a tax schedule each year from which a simple income tax is calculated depending on an individual’s taxable income. The final tax owed to the canton and municipality is then determined by applying the current cantonal and municipal tax rates, which are usually quoted in percentage or a multiple of the simple income tax. The federal direct income tax is determined in a similar fashion and the same across all cantons.
Swiss nationals and individuals with a long-term residence permit (C-permit) pay taxes by submitting a tax declaration in the calendar year after the respective tax year. They submit information on their income and wealth in the concerned year, but also have the option of making deductions for expenditures. The most common deductions are for work-related expenditures, commuting (by train or by car), children, donations and insurance payments. Most deductions are either fixed or capped. The tax office then issues a tax bill based on the tax declaration. Foreign residents with residence permits other than a C-permit are taxed at the source. Their tax contributions are directly deducted from their monthly paycheck and transferred to the resident canton. The size of the tax depends on their income level, marital status, age and municipality of residence. It is calculated using assumptions about the wealth of these residents, based on similar individuals who submit a tax declaration (ESTV, 2019). While the fashion of tax collection is differently for these residents, the size of their tax burden is still the same as for those who submit a tax declaration.

2.2 Joint income taxation of married couples

Switzerland follows the concept of joint (family) taxation. Married couples are taxed jointly for both their income and their wealth. In addition, any non-employment income generated by children under the age of 18 is also included in the joint taxation.11
The federal government and the cantons aim to take the marriage tax into account by either applying different tax rates for married couples or splitting the income (ESTV, 2019).
Table 1
Overview joint taxation
Canton
Type
Divisor
Canton
Type
Divisor
Zurich
Double
Schaffhausen
Splitting
1.9
Bern
Double
Appenzell Ausserrhoden
Double
Lucerne
Double
Appenzell Innerrhoden
Splitting
2
Uri
Deduction
St. Gallen
Splitting
2
Schwyz
Splitting
1.9
Graubünden
Splitting
1.9
Obwalden
Deduction
Aargau
Splitting
2
Nidwalden
Splitting
1.85
Thurgau
Splitting
2
Glarus
Splitting
1.6
Ticino
Double
Zug
Double
Vaud
Splitting
Varies
Fribourg
Splitting
2
Valais
Tax rebate
Solothurn
Splitting
1.9
Neuchatel
Splitting
1.81
Basel-Stadt
Double
Geneva
Splitting
2
Basel-Land
Splitting
2
Jura
Double
NOTE: Splitting is based on the following concept: The joint income of married couples is divided by the divisor; the resulting income level is then used to obtain the tax rate which is applied to the joint income. Vaud uses a variable divisor which depends on the size of the family (so-called consumption units): The divisor is 1 for singles, 1.8 for married couples, 1.3 for singles with underaged children plus 0.5 per underaged child. The cantons of Uri, Obwalden and Valais aim to take into account the marriage tax through deductions from the income or the final tax. Source: ESTV (2019)
Table 1 gives an overview of the procedure in each canton, where “Double” stands for separate tax rates for married couples, and “Splitting” stands for a splitting of the overall income, where the divisor represents the amount by which the overall income is divided to determine the relevant tax rate. Three cantons (Uri, Obwalden and Valais) apply the single tariff to the joint income of married couples, but allow for large deductions or a tax rebate on the final tax bill. For the income tax owed to the federal government, there are different tariffs for singles, married couples and families (in the form of an additional deduction from the tax). All cantons except for Vaud allow for child deductions. Depending on the canton, these deductions can be progressive in the number of children or not. Most cantons and the federal government have introduced an indexation of the tax tariffs, rebates and/or deductions based on the development of the inflation during the respective tax period (ESTV, 2018).
Table 2
Marriage tax for hypothetical couples
 
Household income 100 000
Household income 250 000
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
Married
Unmarried
Tax
Married
Unmarried
Tax
Panel A: single earner, no children
Zurich
8912
12667
− 3755
48798
58385
− 9587
Lausanne
13865
18400
− 4535
62637
74113
− 11476
Geneva
9697
17882
− 8185
59528
70968
− 11440
Panel B: single earner, two children
Zurich
4763
5269
− 506
41912
43030
− 1118
Lausanne
9138
10599
− 1136
52427
56664
− 4237
Geneva
3673
4770
− 1097
51044
52862
− 1818
Panel C: dual earner, no children
Zurich
7493
6948
545
44437
36998
7439
Lausanne
12978
10814
2164
58804
52114
6690
Geneva
9105
9062
43
56404
51080
5324
Panel D: dual earner, two children
Zurich
3828
3805
23
37552
27964
9588
Lausanne
8887
6061
2826
48772
42491
6281
Geneva
3447
4556
− 1109
47920
36389
11531
NOTE: Example of marriage tax for different gross income levels (i.e., income before social contributions and deductions for taxes) and varying types of couples for selected municipalities. Columns (1) and (4) show the tax burden when evaluated jointly (i.e., as a married couple), columns (2) and (5) when evaluated individually (i.e., as an unmarried couple), and columns (3) and (6) are the difference. A positive value of the marriage tax indicates a marriage penalty and a negative value a marriage subsidy. Panels A and B contain single-earner households with or without children, where one individual earns \(100\%\) of overall household income. Panels C and D contain dual-earner households with or without children, where each individual earns \(50\%\) of overall household income. Calculations for the individual taxations are done assuming that one person claims both children in their tax declaration, with the other person being treated as single without children
Nevertheless, a marriage tax can arise due to different reasons: In case of splitting factors lower than 2, it is evident that the taxable income is higher under joint than individual taxation. Similarly, this is the case for cantons applying a double tariff, where the two tariffs do not co-move. However, even in cases where the splitting factor is equal to two, it is possible that a marriage tax exists due to the nonlinearity of the Swiss tax system, as it is progressive in income. The progressivity of the tax code is the main driver of the marriage tax both in splitting- and double tariff systems. Table 2 presents examples of the marriage tax for different types of couples and income levels12 for the three largest cities: Zurich, Lausanne and Geneva. A dual-earner13 couple with two children and high income in Geneva (Panel D), which employs a splitting factor of 2, pays considerably more when married compared to when unmarried, but the same couple with low income receives a marriage subsidy. This is due to the progressivity of the tax code. Conversely, single-earner couples without children tend to profit financially from marriage from an income tax perspective (Panel A).
Figures 1 and 2 show the variation in the marriage tax across Swiss municipalities for different types of hypothetical couples. The figures therefore are representative of the tax structure of the cantons and give a first impression of which types of couples tend to experience a marriage penalty or subsidy depending on their municipality of residence. In each figure I consider high- and low-income dual- and single-earner households, respectively. Figure 1 shows couples with two children, while Figure 2 assumes that households are childless. Single-earner households tend to experience a marriage subsidy, while dual-earner households are financially penalized by marriage. However, as can be seen in Panel (c) of both Figures 1 and 2, this is not necessarily true in all cantons. Those with a higher income tend to experience a higher marriage penalty than those with low income, especially when children are present and in dual-earner households (Panels (a) and (c) of Figure 1). Single-earner households with children, on the other hand, tend to always experience a small subsidy (Panels (b) and (d)).
Interestingly, the tax system leads to a much lower marriage tax for couples without children (Figure 2). In fact, the couples who enjoy the highest subsidies are childless couples where only one individual works (Panels (b) and (d)). This is likely due to the way single parents are treated in almost all cantons. A single person with a child gets very often treated the same as a married couple, i.e., a splitting factor is applied to their income or the married tariff is applied. Hence, the marriage tax as a percentage of net joint income is naturally smaller for these couples, as the difference between the tax burden when they are married compared to unmarried is smaller. Similarly, for dual-earner couples without children in the same household, the marriage penalty is relatively smaller than for dual-earner couples with children.

3 Data and descriptive evidence

3.1 Datasets and sources

I obtain four different datasets from three different sources: The Swiss Federal Statistical Office (FSO), the Swiss Federal Tax Administration (ESTV) and the Central Compensations Office (CCO).
Population and Households Statistics (STATPOP). I obtain both the individual-level and household-level datasets from the Population and Households Statistics (STATPOP) of the FSO. Individual-level data are available since 2010 and are a stock dataset, containing demographic variables such as age, gender, marital status, residence status and parents on each individual living in Switzerland.14 It also contains a household identifier (ID), which allows me to obtain further information on who this person lives with by combining it with the household-level dataset (available since 2012). It is therefore possible to locate unmarried couples who are living together, but due to their marital status are not filing taxes jointly. Additionally, the household-level dataset contains information on the household age group and gender composition, as well as the number of children (Bundesamt für Statistik, STATPOP, 2021).
Income. I receive information on the gross income of each employed individual in Switzerland by combining the STATPOP dataset with the individual social security accounts (AHV) from the CCO. It includes the exact income based on which the social security contributions are calculated over the course of a year. Since contributions to the AHV are not topcoded in Switzerland, I can see the actual income and there is no distortion at the top. However, this only includes income through legal earnings from employment, i.e., income from capital is not included (Zentrale Ausgleichsstelle, 2021).
Tax data. Income tax data are on municipal and cantonal level and can be downloaded from the website of the ESTV. This dataset contains the tax schedule for each canton-year pair, as well as within each canton the tax rate of each municipality. It also includes the different tax tariffs depending on the income level, which can vary with marital status in cantons that apply different tax rates (the “Double” cantons in Table 1), as well as deductions which can be made from net joint income. I obtain the same information for the federal income tax (ESTV 2021a).
Municipal data. Municipal data are from the FSO and include both demographic (population density, sex ratio) and socio-economic (social assistance rate) variables on municipal level (FSO , 2021).

3.2 Data handling and sample selection

I merge the STATPOP and income datasets on an individual-year level such that each individual appears only once per year. I then add the remaining two datasets based on the municipal and cantonal identifiers, which are registered in the STATPOP data for each observation.
In order to estimate the impact of joint income taxation on the marriage rate, I need to identify two groups of individuals in the overall dataset: married and unmarried couples. Identification of married couples is simple enough, as the marriage status of each individual as well as the ID of their spouse is registered in the STATPOP dataset. I therefore include anyone in my analysis who is married during the sample period and who is living with their spouse. I identify unmarried couples living together by employing an algorithm which is described in detail in Appendix A.15 To treat both types of couples the same, I drop married couples if their age difference is more than 12 years.16 In addition, I limit my analysis to couples where both are in working age (18–65 for men and 18–64 for women) and drop those where at least one individual is self-employed. This is necessary, as the AHV income data are not reliable when it comes to the self-employed. Finally, I drop couples whose’ gross joint income is zero, as they do not pay any income tax.17 As the entire analysis is done at couple level, I reduce the dataset to one observation per couple-year pair and assign each couple an ID which depends on both individuals’ personal IDs.
Divorced and widowed individuals are not part of the married dataset, but they may show up in the unmarried dataset if they are living together with a new partner.
The income as reported from the CCO is the gross income of individuals, i.e., the income based on which the social security contributions are calculated. For taxes, however, net income is relevant. I therefore deduct from the gross income the social security contributions: old-age insurance, unemployment insurance and accident insurance. Switzerland’s pension system relies on a three-pillar approach such that in addition to the old age insurance, individuals also save through a pension fund. I subtract the mandatory contributions to the pension fund system, which are dependent on age and income level to reach the net income. As mentioned in Section 2.1, it is possible to further deduct certain expenditures from the net income for tax purposes. I apply the most common deductions, which are dependent on work status and/or observable without further knowledge of the couple18 to the net joint income before applying the tax calculator: deductions for children, secondary earner, work-related expenditures, as well as personal deductions based on marital status. The latter two are calculated as a percentage of income with minimum and maximum values in most cantons and on the federal level. As deductions for children above the age of 18 are dependent on the child’s work status (i.e., is she still in school/university or already earning her own income) in most cantons, I limit the child deductions to children below the age of 18 living in the same household. While this might overestimate the taxable income in some cases, this should not influence the results too much as the magnitude of these deductions is limited and generally not very large for adult children.
To analyze the effect of the marriage tax, I calculate for each couple the tax burden under joint taxation and under individual taxation. I do this by applying the tax code and rate of the respective year in the couple’s canton and municipality of residence, as well as the respective tax code and rate of the federal income tax to the taxable income, i.e., net income after deductions for expenditures.19 The couple then faces a marriage tax, \(mtax\), which is the difference between the tax burden under joint and individual taxation as a percentage of net joint income:
$$\begin{aligned} \text {mtax} = \frac{\text {tax}_\text {joint}-\text {tax}_\text {individual}}{{Y}_\text {joint}}*100 \end{aligned}$$
where \({\text {tax}_{\text {individual}}=\text {tax}^{\text {female}} + \text {tax}^{\text {male}}}\) is the sum of the tax burden based on each individual’s separate taxable income.20\({\text {tax}_{\text {joint}}}\) is the tax burden based on the joint taxable income, and \({Y_{\text {joint}}}\) is the couple’s net joint income. A negative value of \({\text {mtax}}\) indicates a marriage subsidy, and a positive value a marriage penalty.

3.3 Descriptive evidence

In what follows, I briefly describe the current state of marriage in Switzerland in general and the marriage tax in particular. This analysis is purely descriptive as the results arise both due to the tax system and due to the composition of couples in the sample, as all results are unweighted.
Figure 3 shows that while the marriage rate has decreased by roughly 4.5pp over the analyzed time period (Panel (a)), the average marriage tax has risen up until 2018 (Panel (b)). The drop in the average marriage tax in 2019 is likely due to a simultaneous drop in the share of couples where both individuals work and therefore a reduction in the average net joint income21, which is in line with a relative drop of the average marriage tax for single-earner households in 2019 (Panel (f)). Panel (c) shows that while couples from the first and second income quintile22 mostly experience a marriage subsidy, those from the middle to upper half of the income distribution face a marriage penalty.
Households with children on average face a marriage penalty, while those without children face a marriage subsidy (Panel (e)) and so do single-earner households (Panel (f)). The findings for hypothetical couples in Section 2.2 that single-earner and childless households tend to profit from marriage are therefore confirmed when looking at the data. Finally, the average marriage tax for unmarried and married couples has converged over the analyzed time period, as it has risen more for the married than the unmarried couples (Panel (d)).
Panel (a) in Figure 4 shows that while they develop similarly over time, the average marriage tax is roughly 0.5pp higher in cantons with an income splitting system than those which apply a double tariff. The marriage tax has remained the same in most cantons, with the exception of a large reduction in the canton of Jura (JU) due to a change in the applicable child deductions (Panel (b)).
Panels (c–d) show the average marriage tax and marriage rate by within household income distribution, where households are clustered in five distribution bins23 with the most equal distribution on the right and the most unequal distribution on the left of the graph. While the average marriage tax rises the more equal the within-household income distribution, the marriage rate declines.
As previously mentioned, the Swiss tax system depends heavily on the specific cantonal tax schedules in general, and the applied tax rates in the municipalities, in particular. As a result, there is considerable variation in the marriage tax couples face across municipalities. Figure 5 presents the average marriage tax paid by married couples per municipality in Switzerland in the form of a heatmap. It is evident that there is quite some variation across municipalities in the magnitude and direction of the average marriage tax. While it is small in most municipalities, with the majority of municipalities showing an average marriage tax of \(+/- 0.5\%\), it can be as low as \(-5.78\%\) and as high as \(2.98\%\). Note that this is a purely descriptive result, meaning that the differences may arise due to compositional effects of certain types of couples choosing to move into specific municipalities in addition to the differences in the tax schedules and rates.

4 Marriage rate

Sections 2.2 and 3.3 show substantial variation in the marriage tax across type of couples, age, income levels and within-household income distribution, as well as across cantons and municipalities. In what follows, I analyze whether the marriage tax has behavioral implications for couples by estimating its causal impact on the marriage rate.

4.1 Empirical strategy

Recall from Section 3.2 the definition of the marriage tax:
$$\begin{aligned} \text {mtax} = \frac{\text {tax}_{\text {joint}}-\text {tax}_{\text {individual}}}{Y_{\text {joint}}}*100 \end{aligned}$$
(1)
where a negative value of \(\text {mtax}\) indicates a marriage subsidy, and a positive value a marriage penalty. The straightforward approach to analyzing the impact of the marriage tax on the marriage rate is to estimate the following linear probability model:
$$\begin{aligned} y_{\text {ict}}= \beta *\text {mtax}_{\text {ict}} + \gamma X_{\text {ict}} + \delta Z_{\text {mt}} + \alpha _{i} + \zeta _{c} + \eta _{t} + \varepsilon _{\text {ict}} \end{aligned}$$
(2)
where \(y_{\text {ict}}\) is a binary outcome variable for couple24\(i\) living in canton \(c\) at time \(t\), indicating whether a couple is married or not. The coefficient of interest is \(\beta\), which shows the effect of the marriage tax on the marriage rate. I include a vector of couple-level controls \({X_{\text {ict}}}\) which could potentially affect the marriage decision: age and age squared (per person), age difference, net income and net income squared, nationality, years in municipality, and number of children in the household. \(Z_{\text {mt}}\) is a vector of municipal-level controls that can influence the local marriage and labor market: population density, sex ratio25 and social assistance rate. \(\alpha _i\), \(\zeta _{c}\) and \(\eta _{t}\) are couple, canton and time fixed effects, respectively. \(\varepsilon _{\text {ict}}\) denotes the error term.
As Fisher (2013) points out, it is possible that both the marriage tax a couple faces and the decision to get married are jointly influenced by unobserved characteristics. For example, preferences for marriage and education may be correlated, but so may be education and within-household income distribution, which directly affects the size of the marriage tax. However, education may change over time and is therefore not necessarily captured by fixed effects. Another bias may arise due to measurement error: while income should be correctly reported in the administrative dataset, I cannot rule out measurement error in the size of the marriage tax, as it is estimated based on household characteristics. The calculation for the taxable income, for example, is only using deductions that can be observed from the data (see Section 3.2 for a discussion on the limitations of the tax burden estimation). Equation (2) therefore suffers from omitted variable- and measurement error bias. In order to eliminate this bias, I use a simulated instrumental variable approach to estimate the causal effect. The underlying idea is to use the institutional characteristics which are a strong predictor of the size of the endogenous regressor (here tax schedule in canton of residence) to create an exogenous variable which does not suffer from this omitted variable bias.26 Specifically, I estimate the following first stage:
$$\begin{aligned} \text {mtax}_{\text {ict}} = \xi *\text {avg}(\text {mtax}_{\text {ct}}) + \gamma X_{\text {ict}} + \delta Z_{\text {mt}}+ \alpha _{i} + \zeta _{c} + \eta _{t} + \mu _{\text {ict}} \end{aligned}$$
(3)
where the instrument is the average marriage tax per canton as predicted by the tax schedule, \(\text {avg}(\text {mtax}_{\text {ct}})\). I simulate the marriage tax a random sample of 1 000 couples27 faces in each canton-year pair by applying the respective tax code for each hypothetical couple in each canton and year.28 I use the cantonal tax rate and the population-weighted average municipal tax rate per canton and year to estimate the tax burden under joint- and individual taxation per hypothetical couple. I then average the marriage tax as a percentage of net joint income over each canton-year pair29 and merge this as an instrument to each observation in the initial dataset on a yearly basis. See Appendix A for a detailed discussion of the instrument construction and validity, including a comparison to Borusyak & Hull (2021) and the grouping IV.
To estimate the impact of the marriage tax on the marriage rate at the time of marriage, I only include couples who get married during the sample period, i.e., between 2012 and 2019.30 This circumvents a potential downward bias due to the inclusion of couples who were married decades before my sample period, when other (now unobserved) factors may have influenced the decision to get married and the marriage tax may have been very different. The same is true for couples who never get married, as it is not clear whether they remain together after my sample period. The best sample would likely be the baseline sample in addition to those who as of 2019 are not yet married but will get married in the future. As it is not possible to observe this group, I also present results when adding those who remain unmarried in 2019 to those who get married after 2012 as a robustness check in Section 4.3.31 The true effect is likely somewhere in between the baseline effect and the effect when including the not yet married.
Table 3
Descriptive statistics: married between 2012 and 2019
 
Unmarried
Married
Total
 
Mean
Std. dev.
Mean
Std. dev.
Mean
Std. dev.
Couple level
Marriage rate
    
0.815180
(0.388152)
Marriage tax
1234.161838
(2847.543321)
1493.900924
(3463.116668)
1445.895950
(3359.370446)
Marriage tax in \(\%\) of net joint income
0.508824
(2.014079)
0.667183
(2.329801)
0.637915
(2.275582)
Age difference
3.167162
(2.723504)
3.576867
(2.956851)
3.501145
(2.919465)
Both work
0.961868
(0.191515)
0.801597
(0.398798)
0.831218
(0.374559)
Both Swiss
0.820684
(0.383617)
0.510718
(0.499885)
0.568006
(0.495354)
One Swiss
0.177724
(0.382281)
0.302864
(0.459497)
0.279735
(0.448869)
Both foreigner
0.001591
(0.039860)
0.186418
(0.389444)
0.152259
(0.359272)
Net joint income
136065.871266
(62590.660978)
122259.136679
(134214.352477)
124810.897174
(124245.738560)
Number of children in HH
0.212130
(0.560857)
0.935440
(0.913853)
0.801758
(0.904289)
No children in marriage year
    
0.6110852
(0.4875064)
Years in municipality
3.245499
(5.155556)
4.010506
(4.904459)
3.869117
(4.960719)
Women
Age
30.619573
(6.856051)
33.909451
(7.703574)
33.301416
(7.661271)
Swiss
0.912590
(0.282436)
0.656183
(0.474981)
0.703572
(0.456682)
Permit C
0.043577
(0.204152)
0.135596
(0.342360)
0.118589
(0.323305)
Permit B
0.041533
(0.199520)
0.201430
(0.401069)
0.171878
(0.377274)
Other permit
0.002300
(0.047906)
0.006791
(0.082127)
0.005961
(0.076977)
Net income
57157.189971
(31706.720556)
40777.080096
(39628.841549)
43804.451776
(38812.638576)
Number of own children in HH
0.194286
(0.519869)
0.935440
(0.913853)
0.798460
(0.901936)
Men
Age
32.664232
(7.178140)
36.132725
(7.987276)
35.491678
(7.958716)
Swiss
0.906503
(0.291128)
0.668116
(0.470890)
0.712175
(0.452749)
Permit C
0.063770
(0.244344)
0.173146
(0.378374)
0.152931
(0.359921)
Permit B
0.028452
(0.166260)
0.153292
(0.360269)
0.130219
(0.336545)
Other permit
0.001275
(0.035679)
0.005445
(0.073591)
0.004674
(0.068210)
Net income
78908.681219
(48003.145384)
81482.056576
(125646.583518)
81006.445378
(115309.038869)
Number of own children in HH
0.155027
(0.459756)
0.935440
(0.913853)
0.791204
(0.900891)
Municipal level
Sex Ratio (men per woman)
0.990409
(0.025683)
0.989387
(0.026280)
0.989576
(0.026173)
Inhabitants per \(km^2\)
1371.899408
(1705.753511)
1681.075430
(2284.336363)
1623.933522
(2192.240188)
Social assistance rate
3.034602
(2.097739)
3.306710
(2.267935)
3.256419
(2.239946)
Observations
265 186
1 169 648
1 434 834
Note: Standard deviations in parentheses. Descriptive statistics for the baseline sample, which includes working-age couples who get married between 2012 and 2019. The variable No children in marriage year = 1 if there are no children present in the year of marriage
Table 3 presents descriptive statistics for the baseline sample both by marriage status and in total. The marriage rate within the sample is \(81.5\%\) and the average marriage tax is 1446 CHF, or \(0.64\%\) of net joint income. This value is slightly larger for couples which are actually married than those who are still unmarried. Both men and women in unmarried couples are more likely to work and be Swiss nationals than in married couples, and they also tend to have a larger income, driven by a larger female income. In addition unmarried couples tend to have fewer children and be younger than their married counterparts. \(61.1\%\) of couples do not have any children when they get married. The municipal-level control variables are similar across the two types of couples.
The marriage tax in Switzerland on average presents itself as a marriage penalty, while it tends to be a marriage subsidy in other countries such as the USA and Germany (Fink, 2020; Friedberg & Isaac, 2022). However, when considering the absolute value of the marriage tax, estimates for Switzerland are well within the range of other countries: The average marriage subsidy in Germany according to Fink (2020) is 893 EUR, or \(2.67\%\) of net joint income, which is around four times larger than the average marriage penalty in Switzerland. Additionally, the marriage tax for both unmarried and married couples is roughly two times larger in Switzerland than in the USA (Friedberg & Isaac, 2022): US married and unmarried couples enjoy an average marriage subsidy of 442 USD (\(0.35\%\) of net joint income) and 264 USD (\(0.25\%\)), while their Swiss equivalents experience an average marriage penalty of 1493 CHF (\(0.67\%\)) and 1234 CHF (\(0.51\%\)), respectively.
I conduct a heterogeneity analysis based on a couple’s overall income level, within-household income distribution and type of couple (age, child status). Section 2.2 shows that there are differences in the tax regimes across cantons, which could be mirrored in the impact of the marriage tax on the marriage rate. I therefore estimate equations (2) and (3) by taking into account these different types of joint taxation through interaction terms. Finally, couples may experience an increase in the marriage tax in different ways depending on whether it presents in the form of a marriage penalty or a marriage subsidy. An increase in the marriage tax for couples facing a marriage subsidy is likely to be experienced as a reduction in a subsidy, i.e., having less than previously, rather than an increase in a penalty. The theory of loss aversion shows that individuals react differently to loosing a privilege than they do to gaining something they did not have, which may play a role in the marriage tax. For example, Benzarti et al. (2020) show that the pass-through of value added tax (VAT) changes is asymmetric. The behavioral response to an increase in the VAT is much larger than to a decrease of the same size. I therefore also present results when considering the type of marriage tax, i.e., whether couples (would) pay a penalty or receive a subsidy.

4.2 Results

Table 4 presents the results from estimating equations (2) and (3) using simulated instruments. The sample only contains those couples who are getting married during the sample period, i.e., between 2012 and 2019. I therefore analyze the effect of the marriage tax on the marriage rate at the time of marriage.
Table 4
Impact of marriage tax on marriage rate
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
Reduced form
Marriage tax
− 0.00973\(^{***}\)
− 0.00777\(^{***}\)
− 0.0263\(^{***}\)
− 0.207\(^{***}\)
− 0.137\(^{***}\)
− 0.132\(^{***}\)
 
(0.000776)
(0.000720)
(0.00290)
(0.0136)
(0.0118)
(0.00976)
Age female
 
0.00712\(^{***}\)
0.0497\(^{***}\)
0.104\(^{***}\)
0.0464
0.0115
  
(0.000419)
(0.0132)
(0.0158)
(0.0260)
(0.0239)
Age female\(^2\)
 
− 0.0000381\(^{***}\)
− 0.000461\(^{***}\)
− 0.00126\(^{***}\)
− 0.000921\(^{***}\)
− 0.000306\(^{***}\)
  
(0.00000553)
(0.0000235)
(0.0000660)
(0.0000575)
(0.0000191)
Age male
 
0.0163\(^{***}\)
0.115\(^{***}\)
0.134\(^{***}\)
0.0931\(^{***}\)
0.0844\(^{**}\)
  
(0.000406)
(0.0132)
(0.0153)
(0.0263)
(0.0261)
Age male\(^2\)
 
− 0.000149\(^{***}\)
− 0.000626\(^{***}\)
− 0.000884\(^{***}\)
− 0.000755\(^{***}\)
− 0.000554\(^{***}\)
  
(0.00000490)
(0.0000192)
(0.0000348)
(0.0000291)
(0.0000184)
Age difference
 
− 0.00262\(^{***}\)
− 0.0667\(^{***}\)
− 0.0642\(^{***}\)
− 0.0406
− 0.0461
  
(0.000126)
(0.0140)
(0.0161)
(0.0241)
(0.0236)
Both Swiss
 
− 0.224\(^{***}\)
− 0.397\(^{***}\)
− 0.358\(^{***}\)
− 0.351\(^{***}\)
− 0.373\(^{***}\)
  
(0.000735)
(0.00269)
(0.00637)
(0.00476)
(0.00263)
One Swiss
 
− 0.0662\(^{***}\)
− 0.193\(^{***}\)
− 0.141\(^{***}\)
− 0.148\(^{***}\)
− 0.182\(^{***}\)
  
(0.000579)
(0.00223)
(0.00629)
(0.00482)
(0.00210)
Years in municipality
 
0.00295\(^{***}\)
− 0.00156\(^{***}\)
0.00156\(^{***}\)
0.000690\(^{*}\)
− 0.00146\(^{***}\)
  
(0.0000684)
(0.000186)
(0.000333)
(0.000286)
(0.000177)
Net joint income
 
− 0.000171\(^{***}\)
0.0000572\(^{*}\)
0.00149\(^{***}\)
0.000946\(^{***}\)
− 0.000130\(^{***}\)
  
(0.0000135)
(0.0000243)
(0.000203)
(0.000143)
(0.0000152)
Net joint income\(^2\)
 
1.79e−09\(^{***}\)
− 4.32e−10\(^{*}\)
− 1.11e−08\(^{***}\)
− 7.05e−09\(^{***}\)
9.65e−10\(^{***}\)
  
(1.46e−10)
(1.80e−10)
(1.44e−09)
(1.02e−09)
(1.07e−10)
Number of children in HH
 
0.119\(^{***}\)
0.0234\(^{***}\)
0.115\(^{***}\)
0.0801\(^{***}\)
0.0114\(^{***}\)
  
(0.000563)
(0.00159)
(0.00748)
(0.00625)
(0.000635)
Sex ratio
 
0.264\(^{***}\)
1.238\(^{***}\)
9.768\(^{***}\)
2.860\(^{***}\)
1.339\(^{***}\)
  
(0.0135)
(0.0531)
(0.238)
(0.249)
(0.165)
Inhabitants per \(km^2\)
 
0.00000149\(^{***}\)
− 0.00000160\(^{***}\)
− 0.00000766\(^{***}\)
− 0.00000552\(^{***}\)
− 0.00000276\(^{***}\)
  
(0.000000153)
(0.000000438)
(0.000000854)
(0.000000675)
(0.000000460)
Social assistance rate
 
0.00149\(^{***}\)
0.000116
0.00140\(^{*}\)
− 0.000997\(^{*}\)
− 0.00280\(^{***}\)
  
(0.000170)
(0.000377)
(0.000587)
(0.000493)
(0.000381)
Constant
0.821\(^{***}\)
0.0457\(^{**}\)
   
-2.259
 
(0.000587)
(0.0165)
   
(1.432)
Observations
1 434 834
1 434 834
1 396 649
1 396 649
1 396 649
1 396 649
Couple FE
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Canton FE
No
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Time FE
No
No
No
No
Yes
Yes
Kleibergen-Paap F statistic
49906.5
41931.1
3887.4
535.2
529.1
 
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses(*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1). The sample includes couples who get married between 2012 and 2019. The average marriage tax in percent of net joint income for this group is \(0.638\%\). First Stage and reduced form results are reported in Appendix B. Column (1) presents the raw regression, while columns (2–4) gradually add controls, individual and canton fixed effects. Column (5) presents the baseline including all controls, individual, canton and time fixed effects. The final column presents the reduced form results of the baseline specification, i.e., the regression of the marriage tax on the simulated marriage tax
I present results with alternative samples in Section 4.3 and the first stage and reduced form results in Appendix B. The marriage tax is measured in percent of net joint income. A 1pp higher marriage tax decreases the probability that a couple is married in a given year by \(13.7\%\) (column (5)). As all couples in the sample are getting married at some point during the sample period, one can also think of this effect as a delay in marriage. The control variables influence the probability to be married as expected: age, children, income and the sex ratio in a municipality positively influence the probability to get married, while couples where at least one has Swiss nationality are less likely to get married. Columns (4) and (5) show that it is imperative to consider cantonal- and time variation by including canton and time fixed effects, respectively. Column (6) presents the reduced form regression of the marriage rate on the simulated marriage tax. Together with the first stage results (cf. Appendix B), it confirms the importance of using an instrumental variable approach and the strength of the instrument.
Section 2.2 shows that the marriage tax can vary considerably both across type of couple and geographically. This implies that couples may react differently to the marriage tax when it comes to the decision to get married depending on their characteristics. I therefore present the differential impact by couple- and geographical characteristics in Figure 6. It plots the point estimate and the \(95\%\) confidence interval of the interaction coefficient between the marriage tax and different indicators: income quintile, child status, age group, within household income distributions, type of joint taxation and type of marriage tax. All controls and fixed effects from the baseline estimation in column (5) of Table 4, as well as the base effects of the indicators are included. The coefficients in Figure 6 therefore show the impact of the marriage tax by subgroup. The average marriage rates per subgroup are displayed in Table 7 in Appendix A.
When considering couples from different income quintiles, we can see that those in the second to fifth income quintile react very similarly to a higher marriage tax. Their probability to be married is \(7.3-10.0\%\) lower when the marriage tax is 1pp higher, while those in the first income quintile are \(28.3\%\) less likely to be married. Couples from the lowest income quintile are likely to have a tighter budget constraint both due to lower income and wealth levels. They are also likely to consume a larger share of their income compared to couples from higher-income quintiles, and therefore save less. Put together, this indicates a higher sensitivity to both taxes in general, and to a higher marriage tax in particular for this group, as a higher marriage tax indicates a stronger reduction in consumption than for couples from higher-income quintiles.
As shown in sections 2.2 and 3.3, the tax system is constructed in a way such that couples without children in the same household tend to experience a marriage subsidy. As evident in Figure 6, this group also reacts much stronger to a higher marriage tax, being \(22.3\%\) less likely married when the marriage tax increases by 1pp. In fact, the probability that a couple with children is married is only reduced by very little when the marriage tax increases, indicating that other factors than the marriage tax are much more important in this group when deciding to be married or not. One possibility here may be that once children are present, the insurance character of marriage outweighs the potential negative effects due to a higher tax burden. For example, if a couple has children it may have a different intra-household labor supply and task distribution than without children as one individual stays home more than the other. Marriage can then act as an insurance mechanism against adverse income shocks in the case of the death of the main earner, both in terms of public and private survivor’s insurance.32
While there is little overall variation across different age groups, those in the youngest (18–30 years old) and oldest (51–64 years old) age groups react stronger to a higher marriage tax, although the difference is not statistically significant. These couples are likely to be similar in their characteristics as the couples without children in the same household. Interestingly, the analysis by within household income distribution also shows that those who should in theory profit the most—couples with the most unequal distributions—are those who react the strongest to a change in the marriage tax. It points to the possibility that a reduction in the size of the marriage subsidy, i.e., a reduction in the amount a couple can save with the marriage, is a stronger incentive than the punishment, i.e., a higher marriage penalty. This is confirmed when looking at the last group of estimates, which divides the impact by whether couples face a marriage penalty or subsidy: couples who would profit from getting married react much more strongly to an increase in the marriage tax (decrease in the subsidy they receive). The impact of the marriage tax is therefore asymmetric in the type of marriage tax, as couples are shown to be loss-averse.
I expect individuals to be more aware of the marriage tax in cantons that apply income splitting than those that apply a double tariff, i.e., that the marriage tax is more salient in the former cantons. It should be easier for individuals to estimate the effect of getting married on their tax burden if they simply have to add up their income, split it by the divisor and then apply the same tax rate as if they were single, than if they have to apply a completely separate tariff. However, Figure 6 shows that the type of joint taxation does not matter much. In fact, couples living in cantons with an income splitting approach are not significantly less likely to get married when their marriage tax increases. The results are driven by those living in double tariff cantons, who are \(5.9\%\) less likely to be married when the marriage tax increases. This implies that the salience of the marriage tax does not vary much across type of joint taxation, i.e., that couples living in double tariff or splitting cantons are roughly similarly aware of the effect of marriage on the tax burden.

4.3 Robustness checks

I present robustness checks in Table 5 where I vary the sample used for the estimation. Column (1) present the baseline results from Table 4. I additionally include all unmarried couples in column (2). This sample therefore also includes couples who as of 2019 still remain unmarried. Column (3) presents the results when using the full sample, i.e., everyone in the sample who is married irrespective of marriage date, as well as the unmarried.
Table 5
Robustness check: sample variation
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
 
Baseline
Baseline with never married
Full sample
Swiss or Permit C
Marriage tax
− 0.137\(^{***}\)
− 0.0820\(^{***}\)
− 0.0216\(^{***}\)
− 0.0795\(^{***}\)
 
(0.0118)
(0.00955)
(0.00123)
(0.0187)
Observations
1 396 649
2 465 367
7 993 474
1 030 292
Couple FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Canton FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Time FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Controls
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Kleibergen-Paap F statistic
529.1
456.9
8066.8
248.4
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses(***p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1). Columns (1) presents the baseline results from Table 4. Column (2) additionally includes all unmarried couples (i.e., those who never get married during the sample period). Column (3) includes all married and unmarried couples, including those who get married before 2012. Column (4) shows results for a subsample of the baseline which only includes individuals with Swiss nationality or a C-permit. All specifications include all controls as well as individual, canton and time fixed effects. First stage and reduced form results are reported in Appendix B
As expected, the results show the same sign with smaller magnitude the more couples are included. The impact of the marriage tax on the marriage tax decreases by roughly 11.5pp when moving from the baseline sample in column (1) to the full sample in column (3). This is likely due to the fact that including couples who got married a long time ago biases the results downward as other factors may have played a role when these couples made the decision to get married. Additionally, their income may have changed considerably since then, and with it the marriage tax they face. These results, however, confirm the baseline results and underline the importance of measuring the marriage tax at the time when the marriage decision is made. Column (4) only includes couples who submit a tax declaration, i.e., Swiss nationals and foreigners with a C-permit. The magnitude of the effect is around \(40\%\) lower than the baseline effect, but the sign remains the same.
In Section 4.1 I discussed the question of which sample is the “true” sample. The baseline sample excludes relevant individuals from the analysis (those who are planning on getting married but have not done so as of 2019), while the Baseline with Never Married sample includes irrelevant individuals (those who will grow apart after 2019 and never get married). The coefficient of column (1) in Table 5 likely includes an upward bias, while the coefficient in column (2) is downward biased. The “true” effect of a 1pp higher marriage tax in the marriage rate is therefore somewhere in between \(-13.7\%\) and \(-8.2\%\).
A couple can avoid a higher tax burden after marriage either through a change in income (for example through a change in labor supply) or by moving to an area with a lower marriage tax. In fact, Panel (a) in Figure 7 shows that the share of couples in which both individuals work is stable leading up to marriage, but declines gradually thereafter, indicating a potential avoidance of the marriage tax through a reduction in labor supply rather than a delay of marriage.33 Similarly, even though the share of couples moving to a new municipality is low on average, there is a slight increase in the years leading up to the marriage. Most couples move in the year after the marriage (Panel (b)). To address these two concerns, I show the estimation results when limiting the sample to couples who did not change either their work status (columns (1—3)) or their residence (columns (4–5)) between 2012 and 2019 in Table 6. The impact when only looking at couples who did not change the extensive margin of their labor supply is similar to the baseline result (column (1)). Moreover, the reduced marriage rate due to the marriage tax seems to be driven by those couples where always both individuals are working over the entire sample period (column (2)), while those where only one individual is working are not significantly less likely to marry (column (3)). This result is to be expected, considering that the marriage tax is stronger for double earner couples than for single-earner couples.
Table 6
Robustness check: avoidance behavior
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
 
Work status
Living in municipality
 
Never changed
Always both
Always one
Either pre 2012
Both pre 2012
Marriage tax
− 0.111\(^{***}\)
− 0.128\(^{***}\)
− 0.00861
− 0.112\(^{***}\)
− 0.0827\(^{***}\)
 
(0.0181)
(0.0330)
(0.0150)
(0.0136)
(0.0192)
Observations
463 133
367 264
95 869
718 347
396 937
Couple FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Canton FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Time FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Controls
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Kleibergen-Paap F statistic
328.7
123.7
74.21
408.0
265.6
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses(*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1). Column (1) only includes couples who never changed their work status over the sample period, while columns (2) and (3) show those where always both worked or always only one worked, respectively. The final two columns are subsamples of the baseline, where I only include couples where either one (column (4)) or both (column (5)) have lived in the municipality before 2012 already. All specifications include all controls as well as individual, canton and time fixed effects. First stage and reduced form results are reported in Appendix B
Column (4) of Table 6 shows the results conditional on either individual of a couple living in the municipality already before 2012. Column (5) additional conditions on both individuals living in said municipality before 2012. These results therefore exclude couples who move as a result of the marriage tax. While slightly smaller in magnitude, the results are in line with the baseline results.34
One concern may be that only sampling couples from the 2012 dataset is not a suitable choice for an instrument, as the couples may change over time. I therefore estimate the baseline IV regressions using different versions of the instruments, where for each version I draw the random sample from the data of a different year. Figure 8 plots the point estimate and the \(95\%\) confidence interval for each version. The estimates are very similar to each other, with all results being significantly different from zero.

5 Conclusion

Joint income taxation of married couples can change the tax burden a couple faces when getting married. If tax differentials matter, we should see differences in the marriage rate in Switzerland, where the marriage tax varies considerably across couple characteristics and municipalities. Using local variation and simulated instrumental variables, I show that a 1pp higher marriage tax decreases the probability that a couple is married by \(13.7\%\). This is mainly driven by couples without children living in the same household, as well as couples who are located at the lower end of the income distribution—both types that are likely to experience a marriage subsidy. When distinguishing the effect by whether couples initially receive a subsidy or pay a penalty, the results are not symmetric. Couples display loss aversion, as subsidy-receiving couples reduce their likelihood to get married when they loose part of their subsidy through an increase in the marriage tax. Couples facing a marriage penalty, on the other hand, are not less likely to get married when their marriage tax (penalty) increases.
From a policy perspective, my analysis shows that couples do react to the tax system in Switzerland when it comes to the decision to get married. Policymakers should consider the distortionary effects of joint income taxation on the marriage rate, especially due to its importance for social- and intra-household insurance and potential long-run demographic effects due to its potential impact on fertility. Joint income taxation can also distort intra-household labor allocation and affect the labor market in general, as it increases the marginal tax rate and decreases the labor supply of the secondary earner (LaLumia, 2008; Bick and Fuchs-Schündeln, 2018; Kalíšková, 2014; Selin, 2014). From a macroeconomic perspective, a lower labor supply of the secondary (often female) earner implies investment losses in education, lower levels of output, as well as higher take-up rates of social assistance due to old-age poverty in the long run. In fact, Ferrant & Kolev (2016) estimate that gender discrimination in social institutions could be responsible for an income loss of up to \(16\%\) of global GDP. Further research should therefore consider the labor market implications of joint income taxation in Switzerland, especially in the context of investment into education and output losses due to lower productivity.

Acknowledgements

I thank Monika Bütler, Caroline Chuard, Patrick Chuard and Veronica Schmiedgen for valuable feedback and comments. Further thanks go to participants of the PhD Seminar at the University of St. Gallen (2021), the Workshop of the Swiss Network on Public Economics (SNoPE, 2022), the CESifo Area Conference on Public Economics (2022), the Annual Congress of the Swiss Society of Economics and Statistics (SSES, 2022) and the Annual Congress of the International Institute for Public Finance (IIPF, 2022). I am grateful to the Swiss Federal Statistical Office (FSO) and the Swiss Central Compensation Office (CCO) for generously providing the data.
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendix

Appendix A: Sample selection and descriptive statistics

To identify the unmarried couples in the STATPOP dataset I employ the following algorithm:
1.
Select only households without married couples.
 
2.
Keep private households and those where the oldest person is at least 16 years old.
 
3.
Drop individuals below the age of 18.
 
4.
Keep only households with adults of opposite sex.
 
5.
Drop individuals if their registered father or mother ID is the same as the ID of another remaining household member (adult children living with their parents) or if a registered child ID is the same as the ID of another household member (parents living with an adult child and the child’s partner).35
5.1.
Repeat the previous step to take care of three generation households.
 
 
6.
Drop individuals if they have the same father or mother ID as another household member (to rule out siblings).36
 
7.
Keep only households if the number of the remaining household members is equal to two (to rule out remaining shared apartments as well as single individuals).
 
8.
Keep only households if the remaining individuals are of opposite sex.
 
The remaining individuals should then be unmarried couples who are living together, but are taxed individually. It is possible that the remaining dataset includes individuals who are of the opposite sex, but simply roommates and not a couple. However, I assume the share of these living arrangements to be relatively small.37
Table 7
Average marriage rate per subgroup
Subgroup
Marriage rate
Subgroup
Marriage rate
Subgroup
Marriage rate
Quintile: first
0.93
Age: 18-30
0.72
HH: 0-10/90-100
0.95
Quintile: second
0.88
Age: 31-40
0.88
HH: 11-20/80-89
0.90
Quintile: third
0.78
Age: 41-50
0.88
HH: 21-30/70-79
0.87
Quintile: fourth
0.73
Age: 51-64
0.89
HH: 31-40/60-69
0.80
Quintile: fifth
0.79
Double tariff
0.81
HH: 41-50/50-59
0.69
Children: no
0.67
Splitting
0.82
Subsidy
0.84
Children: yes
0.95
Other
0.82
Penalty
0.80
Note: Average marriage rate per subgroup. HH refers to within-household income distribution

Appendix B: Simulated instrument

The simulated instrument is based on a random sample of 1 000 couples from the 2012 dataset and is constructed as follows:
1.
Randomly choose 1 000 couples from the 2012 dataset
 
2.
Append such that each couple appears 8*26 (years*cantons) times
 
3.
Calculate tax burden under joint and individual taxation for each couple using population-weighted average municipal tax rate per canton
 
4.
Take average per canton-year pair, which is the simulated instrument
 
Instrument exogeneity There is no reason why the simulated marriage tax should influence a couple’s decision to get married other than through the direct impact it has on the marriage tax this couple faces (exclusion restriction). At the same time it is saved to assume that the actual marriage tax and the simulated marriage tax are highly correlated, as they both depend heavily on the tax system a couple faces, which varies across cantons. Additionally, there is no reason why the marriage decision should influence the simulated marriage tax (no reverse causality between the dependent variable and the instrument).
Instrument relevance As stated above, the simulated marriage tax and the actual marriage tax are highly correlated as they both depend mainly on the tax system. The first stage results reported in Appendix B show a high correlation between the marriage tax and the simulated marriage tax.
Comparison to Borusyak-Hull IV (\(z^{BH}\)) Let the endogenous regressor \(\text {mtax}_{\text {ict}}=x_{\text {ict}}\). Borusyak & Hull (2021) suggest an alternative approach to improve efficiency and the first stage of the classical simulated instrument by re-centering \(x_{ict}\) using each couple’s expected instrument \(\mu _{\text {it}}\). In the context of this paper, instead of applying a canton’s tax system to a random sample of couples to find the instrument \(\text {avg}(\text {mtax}_{\text {ct}})\), they suggest to apply the tax system of each canton to each couple and take the couple’s average across all cantons as the expected instrument per couple, \(\mu _{\text {it}}\). This can then be used to re-center the endogenous regressor \(x_{ict}\), i.e., the instrument for endogenous regressor \(x_{\text {ict}}\) is then \(z^{BH}_{\text {it}}=x_{\text {ict}}-\mu _{\text {it}}\). Their motivation for this approach is mainly power gains from an improved first stage as couples for whom \(x_{\text {ict}}=\mu _{\text {it}}\) are effectively removed under this alternative approach. I refrain from this here, as my endogenous regressor and instrument are not binary variables as in the classical Medicaid eligibility literature they are studying. I therefore do not have couples who face the exact same marriage tax in each canton, i.e., \(x_{\text {ict}} \ne \mu _{\text {it}}\)38. Additionally, the first-stage results show a high correlation between instrument and endogenous regressor, as do the F-statistics.
Comparison to grouping IV Note that in the grouping IV literature it is common to additionally construct separate instruments based on cohort-specific trends, i.e., age and education level. I abstain from this as education level is not known in my group and does not influence the marriage tax except for its potential influence on the income level. I further do not create age cohorts, as during my sample period all individuals face the same tax schedules irrespective of their age. Unlike in the traditional use of the grouping instrumental variable (see the literature on the elasticity of taxable income: Blundell et al. (1998); Gruber and Saez (2002); Weber (2014)), where individuals from different age-education cohorts face different income shocks due to tax reforms, I am interested in the marriage tax couples face given their actual income. Creating age-education cohorts therefore does not improve the instruments’ relevance. Using other variables such as income, within-household income distribution or whether children are present to create cohorts would invalidate the instrumental variable approach, as these are choice variables, which directly influence the income level. Constructing cohorts based on these variables would therefore make the instrument suffer from the same omitted variable bias as the marriage tax.
Sampling concerns Using the 2012 data as a base year may be an issue if the characteristics across individuals and couples change drastically over the years. Table 8 therefore presents descriptive statistics of the full dataset by year. Note that the column labelled “Total” shows the average over all years.39 The characteristics of the couples do not change drastically over the years, especially the number of children in the household as well as the work status remains relatively stable. The net joint income rises from 2012 to 2019 by approximately CHF 5 000, but this should not be a major issue for the simulated instruments construction, especially as the marriage tax is measured as a percentage of joint income and therefore inflation is not an issue. In fact, the robustness check in Figure 8 shows that the results are robust to a variation in the data used for the random sample.
Table 8
Descriptive statistics by year
 
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
Total
Couple level
Marriage tax
759.5
792.3
837.0
895.2
951.3
1001.3
1045.7
1014.9
917.7
 
(3496.2)
(3533.0)
(3585.1)
(3632.5)
(3679.1)
(3716.6)
(3773.4)
(3828.6)
(3665.1)
Marriage tax in \(\%\) of net joint income
0.150
0.159
0.178
0.210
0.241
0.268
0.283
0.222
0.216
 
(2.449)
(2.458)
(2.464)
(2.476)
(2.480)
(2.484)
(2.496)
(2.551)
(2.485)
Married
0.850
0.841
0.834
0.827
0.821
0.816
0.808
0.803
0.824
 
(0.357)
(0.366)
(0.372)
(0.378)
(0.383)
(0.387)
(0.394)
(0.397)
(0.381)
Both work
0.780
0.785
0.789
0.792
0.795
0.798
0.795
0.778
0.789
 
(0.414)
(0.411)
(0.408)
(0.406)
(0.404)
(0.402)
(0.404)
(0.415)
(0.408)
Net joint income
126607.9
127649.9
129014.5
129855.8
130258.4
131341.6
131773.3
130880.0
129758.4
 
(115449.0)
(121645.4)
(136124.9)
(124667.9)
(108804.0)
(219217.3)
(121640.0)
(164586.6)
(144075.3)
Number of children in HH
0.944
0.934
0.930
0.928
0.930
0.931
0.930
0.933
0.932
 
(1.071)
(1.069)
(1.068)
(1.065)
(1.063)
(1.061)
(1.061)
(1.063)
(1.065)
Years in municipality
11.80
11.85
11.82
11.79
11.74
11.77
11.78
11.99
11.82
 
(11.32)
(11.33)
(11.25)
(11.18)
(11.11)
(11.08)
(11.03)
(11.06)
(11.16)
Women
Age
41.92
42.10
42.24
42.33
42.41
42.54
42.74
43.01
42.43
 
(10.78)
(10.81)
(10.83)
(10.83)
(10.83)
(10.82)
(10.81)
(10.76)
(10.81)
Swiss
0.840
0.834
0.827
0.822
0.816
0.813
0.810
0.811
0.821
 
(0.367)
(0.372)
(0.378)
(0.383)
(0.387)
(0.390)
(0.392)
(0.392)
(0.383)
Net income
35319.3
36237.5
37065.1
37918.1
38643.8
39380.2
40248.0
40770.6
38304.0
 
(35505.6)
(37168.8)
(37571.5)
(39841.1)
(40310.9)
(51611.6)
(40139.2)
(42241.7)
(40987.6)
Men
Age
44.16
44.34
44.47
44.55
44.62
44.75
44.93
45.20
44.65
 
(10.85)
(10.89)
(10.91)
(10.92)
(10.92)
(10.93)
(10.91)
(10.87)
(10.91)
Swiss
0.834
0.828
0.822
0.818
0.813
0.810
0.809
0.810
0.818
 
(0.372)
(0.377)
(0.383)
(0.386)
(0.390)
(0.392)
(0.393)
(0.392)
(0.386)
Net income
91288.6
91412.4
91949.5
91937.7
91614.6
91961.4
91525.3
90109.4
91454.3
 
(109247.9)
(115256.6)
(129456.0)
(117125.2)
(99111.9)
(187615.5)
(113650.3)
(158207.6)
(132505.7)
Municipal level
Sex ratio (men per woman)
0.983
0.985
0.987
0.990
0.990
0.991
0.991
0.992
0.989
 
(0.0265)
(0.0266)
(0.0263)
(0.0263)
(0.0260)
(0.0259)
(0.0259)
(0.0259)
(0.0263)
Inhabitants per \(km^2\)
1344.4
1353.1
1377.0
1400.7
1418.7
1431.7
1453.8
1441.0
1404.7
 
(1874.5)
(1901.7)
(1939.5)
(1978.7)
(1999.9)
(2020.4)
(2039.1)
(2037.3)
(1978.4)
Social assistance rate
2.991
3.053
3.077
3.088
3.151
3.178
3.088
3.010
3.080
 
(2.293)
(2.278)
(2.232)
(2.218)
(2.237)
(2.247)
(2.165)
(2.135)
(2.224)
Note: Standard deviations in parentheses. Selected descriptive statistics are presented for working age couples only, i.e., where the woman is between 18 and 64 years old and the man is between 18 and 65 years old

Appendix C: Tables and Figures (online)

Tables 10 , 11, 12, 13 and 14
Table 9
Sample selection
Step
Observations
Couples living in Switzerland (2012 – 2019)
11 269 715
Married couples:
 
   Age difference \(>12\) years
− 540 143
   Not living with their spouse
− 260 249
Not in working age
− 662 587
Either self-employed
− 1 337 346
Zero joint income
− 207 821
Couples living together (2012 – 2019)
8 261 569
Married before 2012
− 5 639 801
Never married
− 1 186 934
Baseline sample
1 434 834
Note: Step-by-step sample selection as described in Section 3.2. Each step shows the amount of observations (couple-year level) that are dropped due to the imposed restrictions. The full sample used in the descriptive evidence section contains all couples living together between 2012 and 2019 (8 261 569 observations), while the baseline sample used for the empirical estimation in Section 4 contains all couples who became married between 2012 and 2019 (1 434 834 observations)
Table 10
First stage & reduced form of table 4
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
First stage: marriage tax
Simulated marriage tax
1.002\(^{***}\)
1.044\(^{***}\)
1.011\(^{***}\)
0.975\(^{***}\)
0.970\(^{***}\)
 
(0.00449)
(0.00510)
(0.0162)
(0.0421)
(0.0422)
Reduced form: marriage rate
Simulated marriage tax
− 0.0130\(^{***}\)
− 0.0180\(^{***}\)
− 0.0266\(^{***}\)
− 0.202\(^{***}\)
− 0.132\(^{***}\)
 
(0.00117)
(0.00115)
(0.00289)
(0.00982)
(0.00976)
Observations
1 434 834
1 434 834
1 396 649
1 396 649
1 396 649
Couple FE
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Canton FE
No
No
No
Yes
Yes
Time FE
No
No
No
no
Yes
Controls
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses(*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1). First stage and reduced form results for the baseline sample as presented in Table 4. Columns (2–5) include the full set of controls as presented in Table 4
Table 11
Heterogeneous effects: couple characteristics
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
 
Income quintile
Children
Age group
within HH distribution
1st quintile
− 0.283\(^{***}\)
   
 
(0.0274)
   
2nd quintile
− 0.0999\(^{***}\)
   
 
(0.00961)
   
3rd quintile
− 0.0744\(^{***}\)
   
 
(0.00698)
   
4th quintile
− 0.0770\(^{***}\)
   
 
(0.00699)
   
5th quintile
− 0.0726\(^{***}\)
   
 
(0.00759)
   
No Children
 
− 0.223\(^{***}\)
  
  
(0.0192)
  
Children
 
− 0.0306\(^{***}\)
  
  
(0.00319)
  
\(18-30\) years old
  
− 0.158\(^{***}\)
 
   
(0.0138)
 
\(31-40\) years old
  
− 0.107\(^{***}\)
 
   
(0.00959)
 
\(41-50\) years old
  
− 0.110\(^{***}\)
 
   
(0.0102)
 
\(51-65\) years old
  
− 0.157\(^{***}\)
 
   
(0.0299)
 
0-10/90-100
   
− 0.222\(^{***}\)
    
(0.0206)
11-20/80-89
   
− 0.117\(^{***}\)
    
(0.0115)
21-30/70-79
   
− 0.0888\(^{***}\)
    
(0.00849)
31-40/60-69
   
− 0.0908\(^{***}\)
    
(0.00859)
41-50/50-59
   
− 0.119\(^{***}\)
    
(0.0109)
Observations
1 396 649
1 396 649
1 396 649
1 396 649
Kleibergen-Paap F statistic
62.98
166.6
101.8
103.2
Couple FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Canton FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Time FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Controls
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses(*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1). The sample contains all couples who get married between 2012 and 2019. Results show the interaction effect between the mentioned dummy indicator and the marriage tax as presented in Figure 6. Column (1) distinguishes by income quintile, column (2) by child status, column (3) by age and column (4) by within household income distribution
Table 12
Heterogeneous effects: type of joint taxation & marriage tax
 
(1)
(2)
 
Type of joint taxation
Penalty/subsidy
Double tariff
− 0.0586\(^{***}\)
 
 
(0.00806)
 
Splitting
− 0.00469
 
 
(0.00455)
 
Other
0.0307
 
 
(0.0267)
 
Subsidy
 
− 0.434\(^{***}\)
  
(0.0593)
Penalty
 
0.215\(^{***}\)
  
(0.0398)
Observations
1 396 649
1 396 649
Kleibergen-Paap F statistic
26.19
33.86
Couple FE
Yes
Yes
Canton FE
No
Yes
Time FE
Yes
Yes
Controls
Yes
Yes
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses(*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1). The sample contains all couples who get married between 2012 and 2019. Results show the interaction effect between the mentioned dummy indicator and the marriage tax as presented in Figure 6. Column (1) distinguishes by type of joint taxation and column (2) by marriage penalty/subsidy
Table 13
First stage & reduced form of table 5
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
 
Baseline
Baseline with never married
Full sample
Swiss or permit C
First stage: marriage tax
Simulated marriage tax
0.970\(^{***}\)
0.696\(^{***}\)
1.086\(^{***}\)
0.636\(^{***}\)
 
(0.0422)
(0.0326)
(0.0121)
(0.0403)
Reduced form: marriage rate
Simulated marriage tax
− 0.132\(^{***}\)
− 0.0571\(^{***}\)
− 0.0235\(^{***}\)
− 0.0505\(^{***}\)
 
(0.00976)
(0.00598)
(0.00130)
(0.0137)
Observations
1 396 649
2 465 367
7 993 474
1 030 292
Couple FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Canton FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Time FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Controls
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses(*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1). First stage and reduced form results for Table 5. Column (1) includes the baseline sample. Column (2) additionally includes all unmarried couples (i.e., those who never get married during the sample period). Column (3) includes all married and unmarried couples, including those who get married before 2012. Column (4) is a subsample of the baseline which only includes individuals with Swiss nationality or a C-permit. All specifications include all controls as well as individual, canton and time fixed effects
Table 14
First stage & reduced form of table 6
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
 
Work status
Living in municipality
 
Never changed
Always both
Always one
Either pre 2012
Both pre 2012
First stage: marriage tax
Simulated marriage tax
0.503\(^{***}\)
1.923\(^{***}\)
0.864\(^{***}\)
1.048\(^{***}\)
0.862\(^{***}\)
 
(0.0452)
(0.223)
(0.0477)
(0.0519)
(0.0529)
Reduced form: marriage rate
Simulated marriage tax
− 0.0957
− 0.0641
− 0.0166
− 0.117\(^{***}\)
− 0.0713\(^{***}\)
   
(0.0284)
(0.0130)
(.0207)
Observations
463 133
367 264
95 869
718 347
396 937
Couple FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Canton FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Time FE
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Controls
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses(*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1). First stage and reduced form results for Table 6. Column (1) only includes couples who never changed their work status over the sample period, while columns (2) and (3) show those where always both worked or always only one worked, respectively. The final two columns are subsamples of the baseline, where I only include couples where either one (column (4)) or both (column (5)) have lived in the municipality before 2012 already. All specifications include all controls as well as individual, canton and time fixed effects
Footnotes
1
See Auten et al. (1989), Auten and Joulfaian (2001) and Burman and Randolph (1994) for the effect of taxes on capital gains realizations, Dickert-Conlin and Chandra (1999) for birth and Kopczuk and Slemrod (2003) for death timing.
 
2
I define the marriage tax as the difference between a couple’s tax burden when evaluated jointly and when evaluated individually, as a percentage of net joint income.
 
3
See Fink (2020), Frazier and McKeehan (2018) and Alm and Whittington (1997) for the effect on marriage timing as well as Fisher (2013), Alm and Whittington (1999), Alm et al. (1999) and Friedberg & Isaac (2022) for the effect on the marriage decision.
 
4
i.e., paying more or less, respectively, when married compared to when simply cohabitating. The terms cohabitating and unmarried are used interchangeably in this paper.
 
5
For example, take a couple with two children living in the city of Geneva in 2019, where each individual earns CHF 125’000 a year. They would pay CHF 11’531 more taxes when being married than when simply cohabitating. This is assuming that one individual claims both children for tax purposes (ESTV, 2021b).
 
6
I discuss the reasons for—and implications of—this choice in more detail in Sections 4.1 and 4.3.
 
7
This is also evident by the fact that according to survey data, the cohabitation rate (share of unmarried couples in all opposite sex couples living together) was \(23.4\%\) in Switzerland but only \(12.2\%\) in the USA in 2018 (FSO, 2019; USCB, 2018).
 
8
Registered partnerships are only open to same-sex couples in Switzerland (same-sex marriage came into effect in July 2022). From a tax perspective, registered partners are treated the same as married couples and can be seen as equivalent. This paper only focuses on opposite sex couples.
 
9
In 2015, wealth tax amounted to 3.62% and income taxation of natural persons to 38.8% of the overall tax revenue in Switzerland (Brülhart et al., 2022; ESTV, 2018).
 
10
The reformed, catholic and roman-catholic churches also raise an individual tax on income and wealth. However, the tax burden on these is relatively small and I refrain from including it, meaning that I assume that all individuals are not members of a church and therefore not subject to church taxation.
 
11
Children are taxed separately for income generated through employment, however. Since this income is generally very small and falls below the threshold for taxation, it is negligible. The canton of Ticino does not tax the income generated through employment of children at all, unless they are self-employed.
 
12
High and low income refer to gross household income of CHF 250000 and 100000, which in 2019 was the equivalent of USD 217391 and 86956 when considering purchasing power parity (OECD, 2023). However, incomes tend to be higher in Switzerland than in the USA. The median yearly gross income averaged over the analyzed time period (2012–2019) was CHF 78170 (FSO, 2023a).
 
13
where each individual earns \(50\%\) of overall household income
 
14
See Table 3 for an exhaustive list of variables used in the regression analysis.
 
15
The algorithm considers the following household constellations and filters accordingly: adult children living with (one of) their parents; parents living with an adult child and the child’s partner; siblings; roommates in shared apartments.
 
16
This is done as part of the algorithm for unmarried couples, see step 5 in Appendix A.
 
17
All these steps reduce the size of the dataset by roughly \(26\%\), of which almost half is due to the removal of the self-employed. See Table 9 in Appendix B for exact numbers.
 
18
This excludes deductions for payments of insurance premiums and voluntary contributions to the second and third pillar of the Swiss retirement system as they vary across couples.
 
19
I calculate the taxable income on cantonal and federal level separately for each couple, as different deductions apply.
 
20
I apply the child deductions and tax schedule to the parent with whom the child lives. If children live with both their parents, I apply the deductions to the parent with the higher net income, i.e., income after social contributions but before deductions.
 
21
See Table 8 in Appendix A for year-by-year descriptive statistics.
 
22
The income quintiles in terms of net joint income are as follows: \({1}-{69 763}\) CHF (First), \({69 764}-{99 184}\) CHF (Second), \({99 185}-{124 689}\) CHF (Third), \({124 690}-{162 336}\) CHF (Fourth), \(>{162 336}\) CHF (Fifth).
 
23
The bins are \(0/100-10/90 \%\), \(11/89-20/80 \%\), \(21/79-30/70 \%\), \(31/69-40/60 \%\) and \(41/59-50/50 \%\).
 
24
The estimation is done on couple level for the following reason: Income taxes are not directly deducted from the salary for the large majority of individuals in Switzerland. Rather, individuals (couples, if married) submit a tax declaration in the year after the relevant tax year, based on which the income tax owed per individual (couple) is calculated. It can therefore be assumed that it is not necessarily clear to most couples who pays which percentage of the overall tax burden, as the tax is not directly deducted from the salary. In addition, I only include couples (both unmarried and married); therefore, the estimation on an individual and couple level should yield the same results.
 
25
Sex ratio is defined as number of men per woman in that municipality.
 
26
See also Currie and Gruber (1996) for a discussion of this approach. This type of instrument has been used extensively in the literature on the elasticity of taxable income as well, where it is better known as the grouping instrumental variable (Blundell et al., 1998; Gruber & Saez, 2002; Weber, 2014).
 
27
sampled from the 2012 data
 
28
I therefore get \(1000*26*8\) = 208 000 initial observations.
 
29
\(26*8\) = 208 final observations
 
30
This reduces the sample to 1434834 observations. The baseline sample makes up \(17.4\%\) of the overall sample of all couples living together between 2012 and 2019 (see Table 9 in Appendix B).
 
31
For completeness, I also present results when additionally adding those who were married before 2012.
 
32
The second pillar of the Swiss pension system also includes an insurance against death or disability, which in the case of the former is paid out to the surviving spouse and children. If a couple is unmarried, only the children would benefit from this insurance mechanism in most cases. The same is true for public survivor’s insurance through the first pillar of the Swiss pension system.
 
33
In line with this, Figure 9 in Appendix B shows that the average net joint income and the average tax rate per couple rise leading up to the marriage and decline one year after a couple gets married.
 
34
Most municipalities in Switzerland are rather small, with the average and median inhabitants per municipality in 2021 being 3 964 and 1 555, respectively (FSO, 2021). In addition, commuting for work over larger distances, i.e., across cantons, is fairly common. It is therefore very likely that individuals from different municipalities meet and become a couple. Conditioning on one person having lived in the municipality before 2012 (as in column (5)) is therefore a more appropriate robustness check.
 
35
I identify possible partners as having a maximum age difference of 12 years (the \(95^{th}\) percentile of the age difference among married couples in the dataset). If two potential couples are living together (i.e., a mother living with her adult daughter, her partner and the partner’s adult son together), I assume the parents to be the couple and drop the children.
 
36
This function is conservative: if the parents are unknown, individuals are assumed to be siblings.
 
37
Only \(2.3\%\) of the Swiss population are living in a shared flat arrangement, i.e., with roommates they are not related to and are not their partner. \(42\%\) of shared flats contain individuals of both genders, however, these flats may contain more than two individuals (FSO, 2023b).
 
38
Their concern is mainly arising due to individuals who are eligible for Medicaid in all or none of the states, respectively. Naturally, this should not be an issue in this case with a continuous instrument and endogenous regressor, as the Swiss tax system makes it impossible for a couple to face exactly the same marriage tax in each canton.
 
39
Due to a lack of space, I am only presenting a selection of the variables in this table; however, the conclusions apply to all variables.
 
Literature
go back to reference Alm, J., Dickert-Conlin, S., & Whittington, L. A. (1999). Policy watch: the marriage penalty. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(3), 193–204.CrossRef Alm, J., Dickert-Conlin, S., & Whittington, L. A. (1999). Policy watch: the marriage penalty. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(3), 193–204.CrossRef
go back to reference Alm, J., & Whittington, L. A. (1995). Income taxes and the marriage decision. Applied Economics, 27(1), 25–31.CrossRef Alm, J., & Whittington, L. A. (1995). Income taxes and the marriage decision. Applied Economics, 27(1), 25–31.CrossRef
go back to reference Alm, J., & Whittington, L. A. (1997). Income taxes and the timing of marital decisions. Journal of Public Economics, 64(2), 219–240.CrossRef Alm, J., & Whittington, L. A. (1997). Income taxes and the timing of marital decisions. Journal of Public Economics, 64(2), 219–240.CrossRef
go back to reference Alm, J., & Whittington, L. A. (1999). For love or money? The impact of income taxes on marriage. Economica, 66(263), 297–316.CrossRef Alm, J., & Whittington, L. A. (1999). For love or money? The impact of income taxes on marriage. Economica, 66(263), 297–316.CrossRef
go back to reference Auten, G., Burman, L. E., & Randolph, W. C. (1989). Estimation and interpretation of capital gains realization behavior: evidence from panel data. National Tax Journal, 42(3), 353–374.CrossRef Auten, G., Burman, L. E., & Randolph, W. C. (1989). Estimation and interpretation of capital gains realization behavior: evidence from panel data. National Tax Journal, 42(3), 353–374.CrossRef
go back to reference Auten, G., & Joulfaian, D. (2001). Bequest taxes and capital gains realizations. Journal of Public Economics, 81, 213–229.CrossRef Auten, G., & Joulfaian, D. (2001). Bequest taxes and capital gains realizations. Journal of Public Economics, 81, 213–229.CrossRef
go back to reference Baker, M., Kantarevic, J., & Hanna, E. (2004). The married widow: Marriage penalties matter. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(4), 634–664.CrossRef Baker, M., Kantarevic, J., & Hanna, E. (2004). The married widow: Marriage penalties matter. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(4), 634–664.CrossRef
go back to reference Benzarti, Y., Carloni, D., Harju, J., & Kosonen, T. (2020). What goes up may not come down: Asymmetric incidence of value-added taxes. Journal of Political Economy, 128(12), 4438–4474.CrossRef Benzarti, Y., Carloni, D., Harju, J., & Kosonen, T. (2020). What goes up may not come down: Asymmetric incidence of value-added taxes. Journal of Political Economy, 128(12), 4438–4474.CrossRef
go back to reference Bick, A., & Fuchs-Schündeln, N. (2018). Taxation and labour supply of married couples across countries: A macroeconomic analysis. Review of Economic Studies, 85, 1543–1576.CrossRef Bick, A., & Fuchs-Schündeln, N. (2018). Taxation and labour supply of married couples across countries: A macroeconomic analysis. Review of Economic Studies, 85, 1543–1576.CrossRef
go back to reference Blundell, R., Duncan, A., & Meghir, C. (1998). Estimating labor supply responses using tax reforms. Econometrica, 66(4), 827–861.CrossRef Blundell, R., Duncan, A., & Meghir, C. (1998). Estimating labor supply responses using tax reforms. Econometrica, 66(4), 827–861.CrossRef
go back to reference Borusyak, K. and Hull, P. (2021). Efficient Estimation with Non-Random Exposure to Exogenous Shocks. Working Paper. Borusyak, K. and Hull, P. (2021). Efficient Estimation with Non-Random Exposure to Exogenous Shocks. Working Paper.
go back to reference Brülhart, M., Gruber, J., Krapf, M., & Schmidheiny, K. (2022). Behavioral Responses to Wealth Taxes: Evidence from Switzerland. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 14(4), 111–150. Brülhart, M., Gruber, J., Krapf, M., & Schmidheiny, K. (2022). Behavioral Responses to Wealth Taxes: Evidence from Switzerland. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 14(4), 111–150.
go back to reference Bundesamt für Statistik, STATPOP, 2021. Proprietary Data. Bundesamt für Statistik, STATPOP, 2021. Proprietary Data.
go back to reference Burman, L. E., & Randolph, W. C. (1994). Measuring permanent responses to capital-gains tax changes in panel data. American Economic Review, 84(4), 794–809. Burman, L. E., & Randolph, W. C. (1994). Measuring permanent responses to capital-gains tax changes in panel data. American Economic Review, 84(4), 794–809.
go back to reference Cohen, A., Dehejia, R., & Romanov, D. (2013). Financial incentives and fertility. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(1), 1–20.CrossRef Cohen, A., Dehejia, R., & Romanov, D. (2013). Financial incentives and fertility. Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(1), 1–20.CrossRef
go back to reference Currie, J., & Gruber, J. (1996). Health insurance eligibility, utilization of medical care, and child health. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(2), 431–466.CrossRef Currie, J., & Gruber, J. (1996). Health insurance eligibility, utilization of medical care, and child health. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(2), 431–466.CrossRef
go back to reference Dickert-Conlin, S., & Chandra, A. (1999). Taxes and the timing of births. Journal of Political Economy, 107(1), 161–177.CrossRef Dickert-Conlin, S., & Chandra, A. (1999). Taxes and the timing of births. Journal of Political Economy, 107(1), 161–177.CrossRef
go back to reference ESTV. (2018). Kurzer Überblick über die Einkommenssteuer Natürlicher Personen. Eidgenössische Steuerverwaltung: Technical report. ESTV. (2018). Kurzer Überblick über die Einkommenssteuer Natürlicher Personen. Eidgenössische Steuerverwaltung: Technical report.
go back to reference ESTV. (2019). Das Schweizerische Steuersystem. Eidgenössische Steuerverwaltung: Technical report. ESTV. (2019). Das Schweizerische Steuersystem. Eidgenössische Steuerverwaltung: Technical report.
go back to reference Ferrant, G. and Kolev, A. (2016). Does Gender Discrimination in Social Institutions matter for Long-term Growth? Cross-country evidence. OECD Development Centre Working Paper No. 330. Ferrant, G. and Kolev, A. (2016). Does Gender Discrimination in Social Institutions matter for Long-term Growth? Cross-country evidence. OECD Development Centre Working Paper No. 330.
go back to reference Fink, A. (2020). German income taxation and the timing of marriage. Applied Economics, 52(5), 475–489.CrossRef Fink, A. (2020). German income taxation and the timing of marriage. Applied Economics, 52(5), 475–489.CrossRef
go back to reference Fisher, H. (2013). The effect of marriage tax penalties and subsidies on marital status. Fiscal Studies, 34(4), 437–465.CrossRef Fisher, H. (2013). The effect of marriage tax penalties and subsidies on marital status. Fiscal Studies, 34(4), 437–465.CrossRef
go back to reference Frazier, N., & McKeehan, M. (2018). Hesitating at the altar: An update on taxes and the timing of marriage. Public Finance Review, 46(5), 743–763.CrossRef Frazier, N., & McKeehan, M. (2018). Hesitating at the altar: An update on taxes and the timing of marriage. Public Finance Review, 46(5), 743–763.CrossRef
go back to reference González, L. (2013). The effect of a universal child benefit on conceptions, abortions, and early maternal labor supply. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 5(3), 160–180. González, L. (2013). The effect of a universal child benefit on conceptions, abortions, and early maternal labor supply. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 5(3), 160–180.
go back to reference Gruber, J., & Saez, E. (2002). The elasticity of taxable income. Journal of Public Economics, 84, 1–32.CrossRef Gruber, J., & Saez, E. (2002). The elasticity of taxable income. Journal of Public Economics, 84, 1–32.CrossRef
go back to reference Gutiérrez, E., & Becerra, P. S. (2012). The relationship between civil unions and fertility in France: Preliminary evidence. Review of Economics of the Household, 10(1), 115–132.CrossRef Gutiérrez, E., & Becerra, P. S. (2012). The relationship between civil unions and fertility in France: Preliminary evidence. Review of Economics of the Household, 10(1), 115–132.CrossRef
go back to reference Heuveline, P., & Timberlake, J. M. (2004). The role of cohabitation in family formation: The United States in comparative perspective. Journal of Marriage and Family, 66, 1214–1230.CrossRef Heuveline, P., & Timberlake, J. M. (2004). The role of cohabitation in family formation: The United States in comparative perspective. Journal of Marriage and Family, 66, 1214–1230.CrossRef
go back to reference Lalive, R., & Zweimüller, J. (2009). How does parental leave affect fertility and return to work? Evidence from two natural experiments. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(3), 1363–1402.CrossRef Lalive, R., & Zweimüller, J. (2009). How does parental leave affect fertility and return to work? Evidence from two natural experiments. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(3), 1363–1402.CrossRef
go back to reference LaLumia, S. (2008). The effects of joint taxation of married couples on labor supply and non-wage income. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 1698–1719.CrossRef LaLumia, S. (2008). The effects of joint taxation of married couples on labor supply and non-wage income. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 1698–1719.CrossRef
go back to reference Kalíšková, K. (2014). Labor supply consequences of family taxation: Evidence from the Czech Republic. Labour Economics, 30, 234–244.CrossRef Kalíšková, K. (2014). Labor supply consequences of family taxation: Evidence from the Czech Republic. Labour Economics, 30, 234–244.CrossRef
go back to reference Kopczuk, W., & Slemrod, J. (2003). Dying to save taxes: Evidence from estate-tax returns on the death elasticity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(2), 256–265.CrossRef Kopczuk, W., & Slemrod, J. (2003). Dying to save taxes: Evidence from estate-tax returns on the death elasticity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(2), 256–265.CrossRef
go back to reference Malkova, O. (2018). Can maternity benefits have long-term effects on childbearing? Evidence from Soviet Russia. Review of Economics and Statistics, 100(4), 691–703.CrossRef Malkova, O. (2018). Can maternity benefits have long-term effects on childbearing? Evidence from Soviet Russia. Review of Economics and Statistics, 100(4), 691–703.CrossRef
go back to reference Milligan, K. (2005). Subsidizing the stork: New evidence on tax incentives and fertility. Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(3), 539–555.CrossRef Milligan, K. (2005). Subsidizing the stork: New evidence on tax incentives and fertility. Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(3), 539–555.CrossRef
go back to reference Persson, P. (2020). Social insurance and the marriage market. Journal of Political Economy, 128(1), 252–300.CrossRef Persson, P. (2020). Social insurance and the marriage market. Journal of Political Economy, 128(1), 252–300.CrossRef
go back to reference Raute, A. (2019). Can financial incentives reduce the baby gap? Evidence from a reform in maternity leave benefits. Journal of Public Economics, 169, 203–222.CrossRef Raute, A. (2019). Can financial incentives reduce the baby gap? Evidence from a reform in maternity leave benefits. Journal of Public Economics, 169, 203–222.CrossRef
go back to reference Rindfuss, R. R., & VandenHeuvel, A. (1990). Cohabitation: A precursor to marriage or an alternative to being single? Population and Development Review, 16(4), 703–726.CrossRef Rindfuss, R. R., & VandenHeuvel, A. (1990). Cohabitation: A precursor to marriage or an alternative to being single? Population and Development Review, 16(4), 703–726.CrossRef
go back to reference Selin, H. (2014). The rise in female employment and the role of tax incentives. an empirical analysis of the Swedish individual tax reform of 1971. International Tax and Public Finance, 21, 894–922.CrossRef Selin, H. (2014). The rise in female employment and the role of tax incentives. an empirical analysis of the Swedish individual tax reform of 1971. International Tax and Public Finance, 21, 894–922.CrossRef
go back to reference Weber, C. E. (2014). Toward obtaining a consistent estimate of the elasticity of taxable income using difference-in-differences. Journal of Public Economics, 117, 90–103.CrossRef Weber, C. E. (2014). Toward obtaining a consistent estimate of the elasticity of taxable income using difference-in-differences. Journal of Public Economics, 117, 90–103.CrossRef
go back to reference Zentrale Ausgleichsstelle, IK, 2021. Proprietary Data. Zentrale Ausgleichsstelle, IK, 2021. Proprietary Data.
Metadata
Title
Till taxes keep us apart? The impact of the marriage tax on the marriage rate
Author
Nadia Myohl
Publication date
27-06-2023
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
International Tax and Public Finance / Issue 2/2024
Print ISSN: 0927-5940
Electronic ISSN: 1573-6970
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-023-09784-y

Other articles of this Issue 2/2024

International Tax and Public Finance 2/2024 Go to the issue