Skip to main content
Top
Published in: International Tax and Public Finance 4/2021

04-01-2021

Voluntary provision of environmental offsets under monopolistic competition

Authors: Masatoshi Yoshida, Stephen J. Turnbull

Published in: International Tax and Public Finance | Issue 4/2021

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In a general equilibrium model where individuals voluntarily provide offsets which compensate for degradation of environmental quality by consuming differentiated goods produced by monopolistically competitive firms, this paper examines how the population size affects the equilibrium levels of offsets and net contributions. The results depend on the specification of the utility function. However, when environmental quality converges to a finite level, the offsets are independent of this specification in a large economy with many individuals. Offsets are positive in the large economy, and “carbon neutrality” holds: Net contributions are zero. The comparative statics of parameters are also analyzed.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
For the voluntary provision problem of a normal, pure public good in a standard model without consumption externalities, see Chamberlin (1974), McGuire (1974), Warr (1983), Bergstrom et al. (1986), and Andreoni (1988).
 
2
One exception is Gans and Groves (2012). They assumed that consumers derive utility from their own contributions to public good provision which decrease carbon emissions caused by consumption of electricity through the market purchases of offsets and showed that the introduction of an offset market can induce a rise in net emissions in equilibrium when producers of dirty consumption goods have market power. However, they did not consider the problem of voluntary provision of public goods.
 
3
In monopolistically competitive models, Pecorino (2009), Mondal (2013), and Bag and Mondal (2014) considered how the aggregate voluntary provision level of a pure public good depends on the population size. On the other hand, Heijdra and van der Ploeg (1996), Yoshida and Kenmochi (2011), Yoshida and Turnbull (2015), and Yoshida and Turnbull (2019) considered the optimal supply problem of public goods financed by taxation. However, these researches did not consider the problem of voluntary provision of environmental offsets.
 
4
Since each monopolistic firm has fixed and constant marginal costs in this model, the profit maximization and zero-profit conditions of this firm by themselves determine the firm’s price and the output in equilibrium. For this reason, the number of monopolistic firms adjusts the social demand and supply of environmental quality rather than the monopolistic price.
 
5
The limit properties of environmental quality generalize those obtained by Chamberlin (1974) and McGuire (1974) in the standard model of pure public goods without consumption externalities. They reexamined the hypothesis of Olson (1965) that a public good will not be provided in large economies and showed that its equilibrium level converges to a finite positive number in a model with identical individuals and identical wealth endowments. Andreoni (1988) demonstrated that this limit property also holds in a generalized model with both preference and wealth heterogeneity.
 
6
A part of this model is based on Yoshida (1998). However, we do not consider human capital and overlapping generations in this paper, since we are interested in the voluntary provision problem of environmental offsets in a static model with monopolistic competition.
 
7
See Dixit and Stiglitz (1977) and Heijdra and van der Ploeg (1996) for the PFD effect.
 
8
For example, this ambient level could be the “natural” level in the Garden of Eden, or it could arise from externalities received from the economic activity of surrounding economies.
 
9
The demand function \(G_{j}^{d} = d(P,m_{j} )\) in the interior solution is derived from \(PC_{j} + G = m_{j}\), \(U_{C} = \lambda_{j} P\), and \(U_{G} = \lambda_{j}\). Note that \(U_{G} = \lambda_{j}\) implies that the marginal utility of income (\(\lambda_{j}\)) is the opportunity cost of contributing to environmental quality.
 
10
It follows from (7) and \(\mu_{i} = (P_{C} /p_{i} )^{\theta } /\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} {(P_{C} /p_{i} )^{\theta } }\) that \(\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} {\mu_{i} } q_{i} = \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} {q_{i} } x_{ij} /\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} {x_{ij} }\). Since \(y_{j} = 0\) in the boundary solution, the budget constraint (5) is represented as \(\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} {q_{i} } x_{ij} = 1\). Thus, it holds that \(\beta /\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} {\mu_{i} } q_{i} = \beta \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} {x_{ij} }\) in this solution.
 
11
We mark the equilibrium levels of endogenous variables in the model with an asterisk (\(*\)).
 
12
We do not consider the labor market equilibrium condition: \(\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} {l_{i}^{X} } + l^{Y} = L\) by Walras’s Law, since it is derived from the budget constraint (5), the production technologies, (1) and (10), the zero-profit condition of the monopolistic firms, and the market conditions: \(\sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^{L} {x_{ij} } = X_{i}\) and \(\sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^{L} {y_{j} } = Y\).
 
13
It holds that \(g_{j}^{ * } = g^{ * } = (G^{ * } - \bar{G})/L\) for all \(j\) in the interior equilibrium. Thus, if \(G^{ * } - \bar{G} > 0\) (\(< 0\)), then it holds that \(g^{ * } > 0\) (\(< 0\)), that is, if the equilibrium level of environmental quality is greater (smaller) than its ambient level, then net contributions are positive (negative).
 
14
In the boundary equilibrium, since \(G^{ * }\) and \(g^{ * }\) are given by \(G^{ * } = \bar{G} - \beta L/\bar{q}\) and \(g^{ * } = - \beta /\bar{q}\), we obtain the comparative static results as follows: (i) \(G_{{\bar{G}}}^{ * } = 1\) and \(g_{{\bar{G}}}^{ * } = 0\), (ii) \(G_{\beta }^{ * } = - G_{b}^{ * } < 0\) and \(g_{\beta }^{ * } = - g_{b}^{ * } < 0\), (iii) \(G_{a}^{ * } = 0\) and \(g_{a}^{ * } = 0\), and (iv) \(G_{L}^{ * } < 0\), \(g_{L}^{ * } = 0\), and \(G^{ * } \to - \infty\) as \(L \to \infty\).
 
15
In the CD case (\(\sigma = 1\)), it follows from \(c = (1 - \alpha )/\alpha\) that \(\partial G_{j}^{d} /\partial P_{C} = 0\).
 
16
The expenditure ratio of the composite good to environmental quality is different from the good–quality ratio (\(s \equiv C/G^{d}\)) because of \(s = r/P_{C}\). In the equilibrium, without the PFD effect, \(s^{ * }\) is constant, but with this effect, it depends on an endogenous variable \(N^{ * }\).
 
17
When \(\theta = \sigma\), it follows from (19) that the social demand function is independent of \(N^{ * }\), so that this function is shown by the horizontal line in the \((N{}^{ * },G^{ * } )\) space. Thus, the unique equilibrium levels of \(G^{ * }\) and \(N^{ * }\) are given by \(\hat{G}^{ * } = \bar{p}\bar{X}/\bar{r}L\) and \(\hat{N}^{ * } = (\bar{G} + L - \hat{G}^{ * } )/\bar{p}\bar{X}\), respectively.
 
18
The LHS and the RHS in (20) represent the supply and demand sides of environmental quality, respectively. When \(\bar{G} = 0\) and \(\beta = 0\), (20) is the same as (18) in Bag and Mondal (2014).
 
19
In the CD case, (20) in the CES case with the PFD effect reduces to (22) in the case without it.
 
20
The social demand function (21) without the PFD effect is shown by the line, but the function (19) with it is shown by the strictly concave curve. The reason is that with the PFD effect, \(C^{ * }\) increases due to the negative effect of a rise in \(N^{ * }\) on \(P_{C}^{ * }\) so that \(G^{ * }\) decreases, but without it, there exists no such indirect effect through a change in the price of the composite good.
 
21
When \(\beta = 0\), (23) is the same as \(G^{{\prime }} (S) = \lambda = \theta (\theta /\beta )^{\theta } [L(1 - \theta )/\alpha ]^{1 - \theta }\) which is derived from (4) and (14) in Pecorino (2009).
 
22
If it is assumed that \(H(G) = \ln G\), (24) is written as \(G^{ * } = (a\theta /L)N^{ * }\). Since this is the same as the social demand function in the case of the Cobb–Douglas function: \(u{}_{j} = C_{j}^{1/2} G^{1/2}\), the Krugman–Mondal function (18) may be interpreted as a special case of the CES function (16).
 
23
Although the composite good in the KM case is the same as the CES aggregation (3) with the PFD effect (\(\rho = \theta /(\theta - 1) > 1\)), this effect does not affect the equilibrium level of environmental quality. When \(\bar{G} = 0\), (25) is the same as Eq. (15) in Mondal (2013).
 
24
We mark the equilibrium levels of variables in the partial equilibrium with double asterisks (\(* *\)).
 
25
The comparative statics of \((L,\bar{G},\beta ,a,b)\) on the number of monopolistic firms are: (i) \(N_{L}^{ * } > 0\) in all cases, (ii) \(N_{{\bar{G}}}^{ * } > 0\) in all cases, (iii) \(N_{\beta }^{ * } = 0\) in the CD and KM cases, but \(N_{\beta }^{ * } < 0\) (\(N_{\beta }^{ * } > 0\)) in the KP case and the CES case when environmental quality and the composite good are substitutes (complements), (iv) \(N_{a}^{ * } < 0\) in all cases, (v) the sign of \(N_{b}^{ * }\) in each case is the same as that of \(N_{\beta }^{ * }\).
 
26
Since \(G_{L}^{ * }\) can be also represented as \(G_{L}^{ * } = (1 - \bar{r}G^{ * } )/(1 + \bar{r}L)\), if \(\bar{r}^{ - 1} > G^{ * } > \bar{G}\) (\(\bar{r}^{ - 1} < G^{ * } < \bar{G}\)), then it holds that \(G_{L}^{ * } > 0\) (\(< 0\)).
 
27
When the ambient level of environmental quality is zero, its equilibrium level is increasing in the population size and approaches a finite positive number in all cases. They confirm the classic results of Chamberlin (1974) and McGuire (1974).
 
28
The methods of Yoshida (1998) and Ihori (1999), who examined a related problem of voluntary provision of offsets in a dynamic model of environmental capital, may be applicable here.
 
Literature
go back to reference Andreoni, J. (1988). Privately provided public goods in a large economy: The limits of altruism. Journal of Public Economics, 35, 57–73.CrossRef Andreoni, J. (1988). Privately provided public goods in a large economy: The limits of altruism. Journal of Public Economics, 35, 57–73.CrossRef
go back to reference Bag, P. K., & Mondal, D. (2014). Group size paradox and public goods. Economics Letters, 125, 215–218.CrossRef Bag, P. K., & Mondal, D. (2014). Group size paradox and public goods. Economics Letters, 125, 215–218.CrossRef
go back to reference Bergstrom, T. C., Blume, L., & Varian, H. (1986). On the private provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 29, 25–49.CrossRef Bergstrom, T. C., Blume, L., & Varian, H. (1986). On the private provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 29, 25–49.CrossRef
go back to reference Chamberlin, J. (1974). Provision of public goods as a function of group size. American Political Science Review, 68, 707–716.CrossRef Chamberlin, J. (1974). Provision of public goods as a function of group size. American Political Science Review, 68, 707–716.CrossRef
go back to reference Dixit, A. K., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1977). Monopolistic competition and optimal product diversity. American Economic Review, 67, 297–308. Dixit, A. K., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1977). Monopolistic competition and optimal product diversity. American Economic Review, 67, 297–308.
go back to reference Gans, J. S., & Groves, V. (2012). Carbon offset provision with guilt-ridden consumers. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 21, 243–269.CrossRef Gans, J. S., & Groves, V. (2012). Carbon offset provision with guilt-ridden consumers. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 21, 243–269.CrossRef
go back to reference Heijdra, B. J., & van der Ploeg, F. (1996). Keynesian multipliers and the cost of public funds under monopolistic competition. Economic Journal, 106, 1284–1296.CrossRef Heijdra, B. J., & van der Ploeg, F. (1996). Keynesian multipliers and the cost of public funds under monopolistic competition. Economic Journal, 106, 1284–1296.CrossRef
go back to reference Ihori, T. (1999). Environmental externalities and growth. In R. Sato, R. V. Ramachandran, & K. Mino (Eds.), Global competition and integration. New York: Kluwer Academic Press. Ihori, T. (1999). Environmental externalities and growth. In R. Sato, R. V. Ramachandran, & K. Mino (Eds.), Global competition and integration. New York: Kluwer Academic Press.
go back to reference Kotchen, M. J. (2009). Voluntary provision of public goods for bads: A theory of the environmental offsets. Economic Journal, 119, 883–899.CrossRef Kotchen, M. J. (2009). Voluntary provision of public goods for bads: A theory of the environmental offsets. Economic Journal, 119, 883–899.CrossRef
go back to reference Krugman, P. R. (1980). Scale economies, product differentiation, and the pattern of trade. American Economic Review, 70, 950–959. Krugman, P. R. (1980). Scale economies, product differentiation, and the pattern of trade. American Economic Review, 70, 950–959.
go back to reference Krugman, P. R. (1981). Intraindustry specialization and the gains from trade. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 959–973.CrossRef Krugman, P. R. (1981). Intraindustry specialization and the gains from trade. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 959–973.CrossRef
go back to reference Lapatinas, A., Eftichios, A. L., & Sartzetakis, S. (2019). Environmental projects in the presence of corruption. International Tax and Public Finance, 26, 103–144.CrossRef Lapatinas, A., Eftichios, A. L., & Sartzetakis, S. (2019). Environmental projects in the presence of corruption. International Tax and Public Finance, 26, 103–144.CrossRef
go back to reference Lappi, P. (2017). Emissions trading, non-compliance and bankable permits. International Tax and Public Finance, 24, 1081–1099.CrossRef Lappi, P. (2017). Emissions trading, non-compliance and bankable permits. International Tax and Public Finance, 24, 1081–1099.CrossRef
go back to reference McGuire, M. C. (1974). Group size, group homogeneity, and the aggregate provision of a pure public good under Cournot Behavior. Public Choice, 18, 107–126.CrossRef McGuire, M. C. (1974). Group size, group homogeneity, and the aggregate provision of a pure public good under Cournot Behavior. Public Choice, 18, 107–126.CrossRef
go back to reference Mondal, D. (2013). Public good provision under monopolistic competition. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 15, 378–396.CrossRef Mondal, D. (2013). Public good provision under monopolistic competition. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 15, 378–396.CrossRef
go back to reference Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
go back to reference Pecorino, P. (2009). Monopolistic competition, growth and public good provision. Economic Journal, 119, 298–307.CrossRef Pecorino, P. (2009). Monopolistic competition, growth and public good provision. Economic Journal, 119, 298–307.CrossRef
go back to reference Shibata, H. (1998). Voluntary control of public bad is independent of aggregate wealth: The second neutrality theorem. Public Finance, 53, 269–284. Shibata, H. (1998). Voluntary control of public bad is independent of aggregate wealth: The second neutrality theorem. Public Finance, 53, 269–284.
go back to reference Vicary, S. (2000). Donations to a public goods in a large economy. European Economic Review, 44, 609–618.CrossRef Vicary, S. (2000). Donations to a public goods in a large economy. European Economic Review, 44, 609–618.CrossRef
go back to reference Warr, P. G. (1983). The private provision of a public good is independent of the distribution of income. Economics Letters, 13, 207–211.CrossRef Warr, P. G. (1983). The private provision of a public good is independent of the distribution of income. Economics Letters, 13, 207–211.CrossRef
go back to reference Yoshida, M. (1998). Nash equilibrium dynamics of environmental and human capital. International Tax and Public Finance, 5, 357–377.CrossRef Yoshida, M. (1998). Nash equilibrium dynamics of environmental and human capital. International Tax and Public Finance, 5, 357–377.CrossRef
go back to reference Yoshida, M., & Kenmochi, T. (2011). Multiplier effects of public services in a two-sector model of monopolistic competition. Japanese Economic Review, 62, 272–288.CrossRef Yoshida, M., & Kenmochi, T. (2011). Multiplier effects of public services in a two-sector model of monopolistic competition. Japanese Economic Review, 62, 272–288.CrossRef
go back to reference Yoshida, M., & Turnbull, S. J. (2015). The balanced budget multiplier and labour intensity in home production. International Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3, 23–30.CrossRef Yoshida, M., & Turnbull, S. J. (2015). The balanced budget multiplier and labour intensity in home production. International Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3, 23–30.CrossRef
go back to reference Yoshida, M., & Turnbull, S. J. (2019). Optimal provision of public intermediate goods with imperfect competition: A note. International Journal of Economic Theory, 15, 209–222.CrossRef Yoshida, M., & Turnbull, S. J. (2019). Optimal provision of public intermediate goods with imperfect competition: A note. International Journal of Economic Theory, 15, 209–222.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Voluntary provision of environmental offsets under monopolistic competition
Authors
Masatoshi Yoshida
Stephen J. Turnbull
Publication date
04-01-2021
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
International Tax and Public Finance / Issue 4/2021
Print ISSN: 0927-5940
Electronic ISSN: 1573-6970
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-020-09630-5

Other articles of this Issue 4/2021

International Tax and Public Finance 4/2021 Go to the issue