Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Social Choice and Welfare 2/2015

01-02-2015

Welfare stigma and risk taking in the welfare state

Authors: Thomas Eichner, Daniel Weinreich

Published in: Social Choice and Welfare | Issue 2/2015

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The welfare state provides social insurance for lifetime risks. In that framework welfare stigma in form of a social norm against living off (net-)transfers is introduced, and the impact of welfare stigma on self-insurance and social insurance that works through redistributive taxation is analyzed. It turns out that introducing welfare stigma reduces the socially optimal self-insurance and raises the socially optimal social insurance. It may be efficient for the society to operate at a point on its opportunity frontier where an increase in risk taking decreases mean post-tax income and welfare stigma. In the presence of moral hazard self-insurance efforts are invariant with respect to welfare stigma whereas social insurance increases upon introducing welfare stigma. Furthermore, it is shown that self-insurance and social insurance are inefficiently low or high depending on the preference intensity of the social norm.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
The relevance of (conditional) welfare stigma for the design of welfare state programs is further studied by Lindbeck (1995), Dufwenberg and Lundholm (2001), Lindbeck et al. (2003) and Lindbeck and Nyberg (2006).
 
2
It is worth mentioning that welfare stigma is also analyzed in the context of private provision of public goods (Rege 2004; Rege and Telle 2004) and tax compliance and tax evasion (Wenzel 2004; Traxler 2010).
 
3
Eichner and Wagener (2004) extend the analysis by welfare costs (administrative costs or shadow costs for public funds) and background risks. Within these extensions the efficient tax rate may be less than one.
 
4
Gong et al. (2009) analyze the case of group cooperation under uncertainty which is clearly related to social norms. However, we abstract from considering group settings.
 
5
The model at hand satisfies the location-scale condition of Meyer (1987) and Sinn (1973) and hence expected utility becomes a function of mean and variance. However, we do not assume that mean-variance preferences and expected utility need to be consistent and follow Ormiston and Schlee (2001) and Eichner (2008) and take the mean-variance framework as an approach that stands on its own.
 
6
The other case that welfare stigma increases in the share of net-transfer recipients is also analyzed.
 
7
It deserves to be mentioned that in Lindbeck et al. (1999) redistributive taxation is determined by majority voting.
 
8
We abstract from non-market income. Introducing non-market income would blow up the model without changing results and providing new insights.
 
9
Individuals are ex ante identical. After the veil of ignorance has lifted they differ with respect to income losses and incomes. Applying the law of large numbers the distribution of \(Y\) is then the ex post realized income distribution.
 
10
In the absence of welfare costs \((c=0)\) the share of net-transfer recipients cannot be influenced by variations of self-insurance efforts and we obtain the results of Sinn (1995), Sinn (1996).
 
11
One might argue that living on welfare is a matter of luck in our setting and is therefore not subject to feelings of stigma. However, Lindbeck et al. (1999) considers productivity differences, reflected by a wage distribution, which constitute the share of transfer recipients in society. From an ex ante perspective, the revelation of this distribution could then also be interpreted as a matter of luck. Nevertheless, the question of how responsible and irresponsible factors shape stigma preferences is an interesting question but not subject to our analysis.
 
12
The specific functional form in (12) can be microfounded as follows. Suppose the individual is expected utility maximizer and let \(\breve{u}\) denote the von Neumann-Morgenstern utility function of income \(y\). The utility under certainty is given by
$$\begin{aligned} u(y) = \left\{ \begin{array}{lll} \breve{u}(y) &{} \text{ for } &{} \theta \le \hat{\theta },\\ \breve{u}(y) - a \breve{\Phi }(s) &{} \text{ for } &{} \theta > \hat{\theta }, \end{array}\right. \end{aligned}$$
where \(\breve{\Phi }(s)\) represents welfare stigma. Then we obtain the expected utility
$$\begin{aligned} \mathbf E u(y) = (1-s) \mathbf E \breve{u}(y) + s \left[ \mathbf E \breve{u}(y)- a \breve{\Phi }(s) \right] = \mathbf E \breve{u}(y) - a s \breve{\Phi }(s). \end{aligned}$$
The identities \(\mathbf E \breve{u}(y) \equiv U(\mu _Y, \sigma _Y)\) and \(\Phi (s) \equiv s \breve{\Phi }(s)\) establish (12).
 
13
Self-insurance affects \(\mathbf E \breve{u}(y) - a s \breve{\Phi }(s)\) from footnote 12 through \(s\) in two ways. It affects the ex-ante probability of getting a net-transfer reflected by the \(s\) before the stigma function \( \breve{\Phi }(s)\), and it changes the ex-post share of net-transfer recipients captured by \(s\) as argument of the stigma function \( \breve{\Phi }(s)\). In Sect. 25 we assume that the ex-post share effect overcompensates the ex-ante probability effect. This assumption goes back to the heart of the concept of welfare stigma (see Lindbeck et al. 1999 or Aronsson and Sjögren 2010). In view of expected utility in footnote 12 the ex-post share effect dominates, if and only if \(\Phi '(s)=\breve{\Phi }(s) +s \breve{\Phi }'(s)<0 \). The other case \(\Phi '(s) > 0\), where the ex-ante probability effect overompensates the ex-post stigma effect, is discussed in Sect. 6.
 
14
In our model expected utility and mean-standard deviation preferences are perfect substitutes. Since the interaction between individual’s choice (self-insurance or pre-tax standard deviation) and the source of uncertainty is linear, the model satisfies the location-scale property (Meyer 1987; Sinn 1983) such that all income distributions differ only by mean \(\mu _Y\) and standard deviation \(\sigma _Y\) of post-tax incomes.
 
15
Inserting the fiscal budget constraint (3) with \(\mathbf E T\) from (8) in (9), the mean post-tax income \(\mu _Y\) simplifies to \(\mu _Y = \bar{\mu }_X - c \tau (m-k \sigma _X)\). It is then obviously, that the fiscal budget is balanced in the social optimum.
 
16
More information about second-order conditions can be found in the Appendix.
 
17
For the derivation of (18) we refer to the Appendix 33.
 
18
The deviation of (21) is delegated to the Appendix 33.
 
19
Observe that each summand in the curly brackets is positive and that \(\frac{\partial \sigma ^*_X}{\partial a} > 0\).
 
20
This is line with the literature on welfare stigma. Lindbeck et al. (1999) employ a similar model structure. When individuals decide on working or not they treat the tax and transfer and therefore the share of transfer recipients in society as exogenously given. In a balanced-budget equilibrium a relationship between the tax and transfer system and the share of transfer recipients is established.
 
21
The derivation of (24) can be found in the Appendix 2.
 
22
It is worth mentioning that \(i_{\mu } =0\) is sufficient but not necessary for \( \frac{\partial \tilde{\sigma }_X}{\partial \tau }>0\).
 
23
Hence the economy is in a redistributive equilibrium.
 
24
The program for simulations is available from the authors upon request.
 
25
Given the highly stylized nature of our model the numerical example is not based on empirical data. Nevertheless, concerning the parameter \(c\) reflecting the operating costs we have chosen a value from the literature. OECD (2013) reports that administrative costs for tax administration as percentage of tax revenues range from 0.5 - 3 %. Evanc (2008) refers to different studies that estimate the compliance costs of income taxation between 2 % and 10 % of tax revenues. In the numerical example we have set the operating costs (as sum of administrative costs and compliance costs) \(c=0.075\) which amounts to 7.5 % and is in the middle of the range identified by Evanc (2008) and OECD (2013).
 
26
Observe that \(\tilde{\sigma }_X\) is independent of the norm parameter \(a\).
 
27
The sign of the indirect income effect is ambiguous.
 
28
We cannot generalize our findings from the numerical example by induction, of course. We have run several other examples in the Appendix 3. The graphs corresponding to all examples under scrutiny turned out to be qualitatively the same as those in Figs. 310.
 
29
In this case, the model could be extended by a different norm type similar to the work hours norm of Aronsson and Sjögren (2010) which focuses on the decisions at the intensive margin of labor supply.
 
30
The value \(\theta _{\mathrm {min}} = 0.3\) constitutes a lower boundary for the feasibility of the optimization problems. However, we can increase the minimum income loss to \(\theta _{\mathrm {min}} = 0.5\) without changing our results.
 
Literature
go back to reference Andersen TM (2013) Incentive and insurance effects of income taxation. Bull Econ Res, in press Andersen TM (2013) Incentive and insurance effects of income taxation. Bull Econ Res, in press
go back to reference Andersen TM (2008) Unemployment insurance and taxation: incentives vs. insurance, discussion paper. Sept 2008 Andersen TM (2008) Unemployment insurance and taxation: incentives vs. insurance, discussion paper. Sept 2008
go back to reference Aronsson T, Sjögren T (2010) Optimal income taxation and social norms in the labor market. Int Tax Public Financ 17(1):67–89CrossRef Aronsson T, Sjögren T (2010) Optimal income taxation and social norms in the labor market. Int Tax Public Financ 17(1):67–89CrossRef
go back to reference Besley T, Coate S (1992) Understanding welfare stigma: taxpayer resentment and statistical discrimination. J Public Econ 48(2):165–183CrossRef Besley T, Coate S (1992) Understanding welfare stigma: taxpayer resentment and statistical discrimination. J Public Econ 48(2):165–183CrossRef
go back to reference Bird EJ (2001) Does the welfare state induce risk-taking? J Public Econ 80:357–383CrossRef Bird EJ (2001) Does the welfare state induce risk-taking? J Public Econ 80:357–383CrossRef
go back to reference Clark AE (2003) Unemployment as a social norm: psychological evidence from panel data. J Labor Econ 21(2):323–351CrossRef Clark AE (2003) Unemployment as a social norm: psychological evidence from panel data. J Labor Econ 21(2):323–351CrossRef
go back to reference Conlin M, Lynn M, O’Donoghue T (2003) The norm of restaurant tipping. J Econ Behav Org 52(3):297–321CrossRef Conlin M, Lynn M, O’Donoghue T (2003) The norm of restaurant tipping. J Econ Behav Org 52(3):297–321CrossRef
go back to reference Dufwenberg M, Lundholm M (2001) Social norms and moral hazard. Econ J 111(473):506–525CrossRef Dufwenberg M, Lundholm M (2001) Social norms and moral hazard. Econ J 111(473):506–525CrossRef
go back to reference Eaton J, Rosen HS (1980a) Optimal redistributive taxation and uncertainty. Quart J Econ 95(2):357–364CrossRef Eaton J, Rosen HS (1980a) Optimal redistributive taxation and uncertainty. Quart J Econ 95(2):357–364CrossRef
go back to reference Eaton J, Rosen HS (1980b) Taxation, human capital, and uncertainty. Am Econ Rev 70(4):705–715 Eaton J, Rosen HS (1980b) Taxation, human capital, and uncertainty. Am Econ Rev 70(4):705–715
go back to reference Eaton J, Rosen HS (1980c) Labor supply, uncertainty and efficient taxation. J Public Econ 14(3):365–374CrossRef Eaton J, Rosen HS (1980c) Labor supply, uncertainty and efficient taxation. J Public Econ 14(3):365–374CrossRef
go back to reference Ehrlich I, Becker GS (1972) Market insurance, self-insurance, and self-protection. J Polit Econ 80(4):623–648CrossRef Ehrlich I, Becker GS (1972) Market insurance, self-insurance, and self-protection. J Polit Econ 80(4):623–648CrossRef
go back to reference Eichner T, Wagener A (2004) The Welfare State in a Changing Environment. International Tax and Public Finance 11(3):313–331CrossRef Eichner T, Wagener A (2004) The Welfare State in a Changing Environment. International Tax and Public Finance 11(3):313–331CrossRef
go back to reference Elster J (1989) Social norms and economic theory. J Econ Perspect 3(4):99–117CrossRef Elster J (1989) Social norms and economic theory. J Econ Perspect 3(4):99–117CrossRef
go back to reference Evanc C (2008) Taxation compliance and administrative costs an overview. In: Lang M, Obermair C, Schuch J, Staringer C, Wenninger P (eds) Tax compliance costs in an enlarged European community. Vienna and Kluwer Law International, Linde Verlag, London, pp 447–468 Evanc C (2008) Taxation compliance and administrative costs an overview. In: Lang M, Obermair C, Schuch J, Staringer C, Wenninger P (eds) Tax compliance costs in an enlarged European community. Vienna and Kluwer Law International, Linde Verlag, London, pp 447–468
go back to reference Fehr E, Fischbacher U, Gächter S (2002) Strong reciprocity, human cooperation, and the enforcement of social norms. Human Nature 13(1):1–25CrossRef Fehr E, Fischbacher U, Gächter S (2002) Strong reciprocity, human cooperation, and the enforcement of social norms. Human Nature 13(1):1–25CrossRef
go back to reference Gong M, Baron J, Kunreuther H (2009) Group cooperation under uncertainty. J Risk Uncertain 39(3):251–270CrossRef Gong M, Baron J, Kunreuther H (2009) Group cooperation under uncertainty. J Risk Uncertain 39(3):251–270CrossRef
go back to reference Homans GC (1974) Social behavior: its elementary form. Harcourt, Brace and World, New York Homans GC (1974) Social behavior: its elementary form. Harcourt, Brace and World, New York
go back to reference Lajeri-Chaherli F (2003) Partial derivatives, comparative risk behavior and concavity of utility functions. Math Soc Sci 46:81–99CrossRef Lajeri-Chaherli F (2003) Partial derivatives, comparative risk behavior and concavity of utility functions. Math Soc Sci 46:81–99CrossRef
go back to reference Lajeri F, Nielsen LT (2000) Parametric characterizations of risk aversion. Econ Theory 15:469–475CrossRef Lajeri F, Nielsen LT (2000) Parametric characterizations of risk aversion. Econ Theory 15:469–475CrossRef
go back to reference Lindbeck A (1995) Hazardous welfare-state dynamics. Am Econ Rev 85(2):9–15 Lindbeck A (1995) Hazardous welfare-state dynamics. Am Econ Rev 85(2):9–15
go back to reference Lindbeck A, Nyberg S, Weibull JW (1999) Social norms and economic incentives in the welfare state. Q J Econ 114(1):1–35CrossRef Lindbeck A, Nyberg S, Weibull JW (1999) Social norms and economic incentives in the welfare state. Q J Econ 114(1):1–35CrossRef
go back to reference Lindbeck A, Nyberg S, Weibull JW (2003) Social norms and welfare state dynamics. J Eur Econ Assoc 1(2–3):533–542CrossRef Lindbeck A, Nyberg S, Weibull JW (2003) Social norms and welfare state dynamics. J Eur Econ Assoc 1(2–3):533–542CrossRef
go back to reference Lindbeck A, Nyberg S (2006) Raising children to work hard: altruism, work norms, and social insurance. Q J Econ 121(4):1473–1503 Lindbeck A, Nyberg S (2006) Raising children to work hard: altruism, work norms, and social insurance. Q J Econ 121(4):1473–1503
go back to reference Linde J, Sonnemans J (2012) Social comparison and risky choices. J Risk Uncertain 44(1):45–72CrossRef Linde J, Sonnemans J (2012) Social comparison and risky choices. J Risk Uncertain 44(1):45–72CrossRef
go back to reference Maccheroni F, Marinacci M, Rustichini A, Taboga M (2009) Portfolio selection with monotone mean-variance preferences. Math Financ 19(3):487–521CrossRef Maccheroni F, Marinacci M, Rustichini A, Taboga M (2009) Portfolio selection with monotone mean-variance preferences. Math Financ 19(3):487–521CrossRef
go back to reference Markowitz H (1952) Portfolio selection. J Financ 7(1):77–91 Markowitz H (1952) Portfolio selection. J Financ 7(1):77–91
go back to reference Meltzer AH, Richard SF (1981) A rational theory of the size of government. J Polit Econ 89(5):914–927CrossRef Meltzer AH, Richard SF (1981) A rational theory of the size of government. J Polit Econ 89(5):914–927CrossRef
go back to reference Meyer J (1987) Two-moment decision models and expected utility maximization. Am Econ Rev 77(3):421–430 Meyer J (1987) Two-moment decision models and expected utility maximization. Am Econ Rev 77(3):421–430
go back to reference Mirrlees JA (1971) An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. Rev Econ Stud 38(2):175–208CrossRef Mirrlees JA (1971) An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. Rev Econ Stud 38(2):175–208CrossRef
go back to reference Moffitt R (1983) An economic model of welfare stigma. Am Econ Rev 73(5):1023–1035 Moffitt R (1983) An economic model of welfare stigma. Am Econ Rev 73(5):1023–1035
go back to reference OECD (2013) Tax administration 2013: Comparative information on OECD and other advanced emerging economies. OECD Publishing OECD (2013) Tax administration 2013: Comparative information on OECD and other advanced emerging economies. OECD Publishing
go back to reference Ormiston MB, Schlee EE (2001) Mean-variance preferences and investor behaviour. Econ J 111(474):849–861CrossRef Ormiston MB, Schlee EE (2001) Mean-variance preferences and investor behaviour. Econ J 111(474):849–861CrossRef
go back to reference Rege M (2004) Social norms and private provision of public goods. J Public Econ Theory 6(1):65–77CrossRef Rege M (2004) Social norms and private provision of public goods. J Public Econ Theory 6(1):65–77CrossRef
go back to reference Rege M, Telle K (2004) The impact of social approval and framing on cooperation in public good situations. J Public Econ 88(7):1625–1644CrossRef Rege M, Telle K (2004) The impact of social approval and framing on cooperation in public good situations. J Public Econ 88(7):1625–1644CrossRef
go back to reference Roberts K (1977) Voting over income tax schedules. J Public Econ 8(3):329–340CrossRef Roberts K (1977) Voting over income tax schedules. J Public Econ 8(3):329–340CrossRef
go back to reference Sherif M (1936) The psychology of social norms. Harper and Brothers, New York Sherif M (1936) The psychology of social norms. Harper and Brothers, New York
go back to reference Sinn H-W (1983) Economic decisions under uncertainty. North Holland, Amsterdam Sinn H-W (1983) Economic decisions under uncertainty. North Holland, Amsterdam
go back to reference Sinn H-W (1995) A theory of the welfare state. Scand J Econ 97(4):495–526CrossRef Sinn H-W (1995) A theory of the welfare state. Scand J Econ 97(4):495–526CrossRef
go back to reference Sinn H-W (1996) Social insurance, incentives and risk taking. Int Tax Public Financ 3(3):259–280CrossRef Sinn H-W (1996) Social insurance, incentives and risk taking. Int Tax Public Financ 3(3):259–280CrossRef
go back to reference Stutzer A, Lalive R (2004) The role of social work norms in job searching and subjective well-being. J Eur Econ Assoc 2(4):696–719CrossRef Stutzer A, Lalive R (2004) The role of social work norms in job searching and subjective well-being. J Eur Econ Assoc 2(4):696–719CrossRef
go back to reference Traxler C (2010) Social norms and conditional cooperative taxpayers. Eur J Polit Econ 26(1):89–103CrossRef Traxler C (2010) Social norms and conditional cooperative taxpayers. Eur J Polit Econ 26(1):89–103CrossRef
go back to reference Varian HR (1980) Redistributive taxation as social insurance. J Public Econ 14(1):49–68CrossRef Varian HR (1980) Redistributive taxation as social insurance. J Public Econ 14(1):49–68CrossRef
go back to reference Wenzel M (2004) An analysis of norm processes in tax compliance. J Econ Psychol 25(2):213–228CrossRef Wenzel M (2004) An analysis of norm processes in tax compliance. J Econ Psychol 25(2):213–228CrossRef
go back to reference Yamamura E (2008) Impact of formal and informal deterrents on driving behavior. J Socio-Econ 37(6):2505–2512CrossRef Yamamura E (2008) Impact of formal and informal deterrents on driving behavior. J Socio-Econ 37(6):2505–2512CrossRef
go back to reference Yamamura E (2011) Effects of social norms and fractionalization on voting behaviour in Japan. Appl Econ 43(11):1385–1398CrossRef Yamamura E (2011) Effects of social norms and fractionalization on voting behaviour in Japan. Appl Econ 43(11):1385–1398CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Welfare stigma and risk taking in the welfare state
Authors
Thomas Eichner
Daniel Weinreich
Publication date
01-02-2015
Publisher
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Published in
Social Choice and Welfare / Issue 2/2015
Print ISSN: 0176-1714
Electronic ISSN: 1432-217X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-014-0836-5

Other articles of this Issue 2/2015

Social Choice and Welfare 2/2015 Go to the issue

Premium Partner