Skip to main content
Top
Published in: The Review of International Organizations 3/2019

22-05-2018

When do authoritarian rulers educate: Trade competition and human capital investment in Non-Democracies

Authors: Santiago López-Cariboni, Xun Cao

Published in: The Review of International Organizations | Issue 3/2019

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper explains variations in education spending among non-democracies, focusing on policy interdependence by trade competition. Facing pressures from spending changes in competitor countries, rulers calculate the costs and benefits associated with increased education spending: education increases labor productivity; it also increases civil engagement and chances of democratization. Therefore, we expect that rulers in countries whose revenues depend less on a productive labor force and those with shorter time horizons are less likely to invest because of lower expected benefits; rulers with single-party regimes, authoritarian legislatures, and especially partisan authoritarian legislatures are more likely to invest because such institutions enable them to better survive the threats associated with increased human capital. We find empirical support for policy interdependence and the conditional effects of government revenue source, time horizon, and partisan legislatures.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
See, for example, Baum (2003), Krueger and Lindahl (2001), Glaeser et al. (2004), Sala-i Martin et al. (2004), Sianesi and Van Reenen (2003), Mankiw et al. (1992), Romer (1990), Lucas (1988), Helliwell (1994), Feng (1997), Levine and Renelt (1992), and Webber (2002).
 
2
However, recent work has started to question the importance of the democracy vs. non-democracy dimension in understanding distributive policymaking in general. For instance, Mulligan et al. (2004) find no difference in public policies between economically similar democracies and non-democracies. Ross (2006) shows that in policy outcomes such as infant and child mortality rates, democracies are not better than non-democracies despite more money spent on education and health.
 
3
Percentages are calculated by authors, using Wright (2008)’s extension of Geddes’ data of authoritarian regime types (Geddes 1999). These numbers are likely to underestimate the actual number, because there are non-democratic regimes that are not yet classified by the data set.
 
4
See, for example, Wantchekon et al. (2012), Galston (2001), Campante and Chor (2012), Finkel (2002), Evans and Rose (2012), and Aldomd and Verba (1963).
 
5
See Glaeser et al. (2007), Castelló-Climent (2008), Gibson et al. (1992), Glaeser et al. (2004), Papaioannou and Siourounis (2008), and Sanborn and Thyne (2014).
 
6
Note that the two aforementioned examples – Malaysia and Indonesia – were both stable authoritarian regimes, the former ruled by a dominant party and the latter a military dictator.
 
7
See Ansell (2008), Brown (1999), Brown (2004), Nooruddin and Simmons (2009), Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo (2001), Avelino et al. (2005), Stasavage (2005), Hecock (2006), Ames (1987), Rudra and Haggard (2005), and Huber et al. (2008).
 
8
However, evidence on the connection between democracy and tertiary education is often mixed.
 
9
As pointed out by Elis (2011), the origins of public education among many advanced countries predate democratization by a significant amount of time. These examples include Japan, Austria, Germany, and Denmark (Galor and Moav 2006; Lindert 2004).
 
10
The exceptions could be countries that monopolize a certain sector of the global market such as some large oil-exporting countries.
 
11
Education spending, given its direct effect on human capital, is different from other components of social spending. Take primary education as an example, on the one hand, there is unlikely to be pressure for more spending on primary education to compensate citizens facing increased insecurity due to globalization (compensation hypothesis). On the other hand, the efficiency hypothesis might not work, either, because governments are likely to be pressured by business leaders to improve human capital via education spending. The effects of globalization on education spending might also depend on government development strategies and the comparative advantage of the economy: those specializing in labor intensive production might try to cut social spending while those requiring increased human capital or upgrading might need further investment in education (Hecock 2006).
 
12
Many studies show a positive effect of trade openness (Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo 2001; Avelino et al. 2005). Moving to a lower, sub-national level of analysis, Hecock (2006) finds that maquila exports positively affect education spending.
 
13
Our empirical analysis finds that trade openness has no effect on education spending in authoritarian states; nor does it mediate the effect of the trade competition variable defined as the weighted average level of education spending in trade competitor countries.
 
14
Recent studies show that diffusion mechanisms are present in a variety of areas such as social welfare policies (Brooks 2005; Gilardi 2007; Cao 2010, 2012b), economic liberalization (Way 2005; Simmons 2004; Elkins et al. 2006), financial regulations (Brooks and Marcus 2012), and environmental policies (Busch et al. 2005; Ward and Cao 2012; Cao and Prakash 2010, 2012a).
 
15
We focus on export competition in this study. On how import competition creates policy diffusion between a country and its import-competitor countries, see López-Cariboni and Cao (2015).
 
16
As De Mesquita and Smith (2010) summarized: “educated people with access to transport and knowledge of the market are more productive than ignorant and isolated people.”
 
17
See, for example, Glaeser et al. (2004), Glaeser et al. (2007), Przeworski et al. (2000), Castelló-Climent (2008), Sanborn and Thyne (2014), and Feng and Zak (1999).
 
18
“Economic backwardness” is more likely when the ruling elite is somewhat entrenched but still fears replacement (Acemoglu 2006, ).
 
19
The causal chain is a long one: education spending improves productivity, which in turn increases competitiveness in global markets and ultimately increase government revenue. We acknowledge the presence of intermediate variables along the causal chain, but the fact that we find significant results shows that our theory works despite potential intermediate conditions.
 
20
For instance, in a sub-national context, Hong (Forthcoming) shows that Chinese local governments with a large natural resource sector have few incentives to invest in labor productivity enhancing social services because abundant resources decrease the need to attract outside investments which often favor higher labor quality.
 
21
We make a simplifying distinction between sectors of the economy that are resources-based and those that depend more on a productive population. However, oil, natural gas, and mineral extraction industries are different from agriculture and other primary activities based on relatively large land-endowment. We focus on the former type of natural resources because oil and minerals usually are geographically concentrated and easier for the state to control. They are often important components of non-tax government revenue.
 
22
However, Jerry J. Rawlings of Ghana and Joaquim A. Chissano of Mozambique actually won two presidential elections after democratization of the country.
 
24
The other type of threats for the ruler are those that emerge from within the ruling elite. They are often dealt by establishing narrow institutions such as consultative councils, juntas, and political bureaus (Gandhi and Przeworski 2007).
 
25
How authoritarian legislature works still is an ongoing research topic, for an online discussion from experts, see http://​themonkeycage.​org/​2012/​12/​what-do-legislatures-in-authoritarian-regimes-do/​.
 
26
Legitimizing the authoritarian regime through popular mobilization in legislative elections could be an additional potential mechanism (Levitsky and Way 2002; Schedler 2006).
 
27
Data on education spending are from the UNESCO Institute for Statistics, the Edstats dataset from the World Bank. Results for spending as a percentage of total government spending are similar and available upon request.
 
28
While excluding capital expenditures, this variable provides information for a large number of countries over time. An alternative measure is current and capital public education expenditure. This data is however very sparse and provides a much smaller number of observations with shorter country time series: for 1970-2009, almost half of the countries have less than 10 observations and almost 30% of countries have fewer than 5 observations. As robustness checks, we did run the same analysis using current and capital public education expenditure as the dependent variable. We find strong evidence for policy interdependence.
 
29
For a more detailed explanation of the spatial lag variable, see Section A of the Online Appendix.
 
30
Note that the ECM is arithmetically equivalent to a general ADL specification (De Boef and Luke 2008; Keele et al. 2016), and that the spatio-temporal autoregressive model (STAR) is in fact an ADL model with spatial lags. Model selection for TSCS depends on both theoretical and empirical considerations. Potential concerns are the order of integration and whether there exists equation balance in the model (Grant and Lebo 2016). We performed different panel unit root tests for both the education spending data and the spatial lag of education spending. The tests are panel unit root test either based on a pooled statistic (Levin et al. 2002), or a group-mean test averaging augmented Dickey-Fuller regressions for each time series (Im et al. 2003). The evidence suggests we are dealing with stationary data on both sides of the equation. We also performed these tests with unbounded time series data (Lebo and Grant 2016; Grant and Lebo 2016), by taking education spending measured in constant US dollars. Again, unit root tests confirm that our data is most likely to be I(0). This strengthens our confidence in reporting reliable hypothesis testing and long-run multipliers for the substantive interpretation size effects (Grant and Lebo 2016; Keele et al. 2016).
 
31
In some of our specifications where we still observe serially correlated disturbances due to the the persistence of education spending data and different sample sizes, we include lagged differences of the dependent variable as a means of purging the remaining autocorrelation.
 
32
Results remain unchanged after controlling for aggregate signs of external competitiveness like the external trade balance and consumption prices.
 
33
Including the Polity score in specifications with other institutional variables such as legislatures or authoritarian regime types might be redundant, because for some countries, it might pick up certain level of the same information contained in other institutions variables. Excluding the Polity score, however, does not change the main results: regression tables are available upon request from authors.
 
34
The per capita income data comes from expanded times series by Gleditsch (2002), updated in 2013. The output gap is estimated as the difference between real GDP per capita and the underlying growth trends, as a percentage of the trend. A Hodrick-Prescott filter (H-P) is used to estimate the underlying growth trend. The H-P filter implements long-run moving average to de-trend the output series. See: (Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo 2001, 584).
 
35
Data are from the World Bank, World Development Indicators (The World Bank 2012).
 
36
Using total government spending does not changes the results, but it significantly shrinks the sample size. Data are from the IMF-GFS and the World Development Indicators (The World Bank 2012).
 
37
We follow the standard Bewley transformation of error correction model to calculate the long-run multipliers and their corresponding standard errors. See De Boef and Luke (2008).
 
38
Adding changes and their interactions with domestic conditional variables makes no difference to the conclusions we arrive from the empirical analysis.
 
39
Another way that trade openness could affect education spending is through its mediating effect with trade competitors’ education expenditures. Not all countries are equally open to trade. The same level of spending increase in competitor countries might have a larger impact on a more open economy. We need to test an interactive effect between trade openness and trade competitors’ education expenditure changes. We have tried various openness variables (imports, exports, and total trade) and trade liberalization index (e.g., the KOF index Dreher 2006; Gygli et al. 2018); they do not mediate the effect of interdependence. However, we do find that our results regarding education spending races among trade competitor countries are more important for the period of 1990-2009 (high global economic integration) than for the period of 1970s and 1980s (low economic integration) for developing nations. See Section I of the Online Appendix for more details.
 
40
Oil and natural resource rents data are from the World Bank, World Development Indicators. Since both variables are highly skewed, we log transform the data before estimating the models. Taking into account of production costs is very important given the significant cross-country variation in the cost of producing a barrel of oil: in the United Kingdom, it costs $52.50 to produce a barrel of oil; in Brazil, it costs nearly $49; on the other hand, Saudia Arabia and Kuwait can pump a barrel of oil for less than $10 – see http://​money.​cnn.​com/​2015/​11/​24/​news/​oil-prices-production-costs/​index.​html, accessed on November 30, 2017. Ross (2012) offers an alternative measure of oil and gas wealth by dividing the total value of oil and gas production by a country’s population. We think this is a very important measure for a country’s overall oil and gas wealth. But it does not take into account the aforementioned cross-country variation in the cost of production which significantly affects the amount of rents that can be captured by an autocratic ruler. Nevertheless, we conducted robustness checks using this oil income per capita variable. The detailed results are in Section D of the online appendix: we observe a very similar finding – rulers with no natural resources engage in education races; as oil and gas income per capita increases, the effect of interdependence becomes insignificant.
 
41
The results here need to be interpreted with caution regarding the substantive effect, especially for areas around extreme values such as those close to the maximum value of the oil variable, because on the maximum side, there are not many observations in the data. As a function of this, the confidence intervals of coefficient estimates when the resource variables approach their maximum values are often large and overlap with the confidence intervals when the values of the resource variables are close to 0 (Fig. 3).
 
42
See also Cheibub (1998) who uses predicted hazard rates for leadership failure.
 
43
Also, shortened time-horizons may affect education spending negatively if education spending among trade competitor countries is high.
 
44
Data are from the World Bank, World Development Indicators.
 
45
Section H of the online appendix has more detailed discussion on model estimates.
 
46
We thank one reviewer for raising this interesting alternative causal mechanism.
 
47
It is possible that these two proxies might not be able to pick up enough variation in the political strength of of teachers’ unions, especially in cross-country context.
 
48
We have also replicated estimates from the main paper clustering standard errors to correct for potential time-wise heteroscedasticity and cross-sectional heteroscedasticity and correlation. As shown by Section L and Table 14 of the online appendix, there is no significant difference compared to spatial OLS models in the main paper.
 
49
This type of quality improvements can happen in relatively short periods, which allow for increased market shares in export destinations by selling better quality products with only moderate changes in price.
 
50
Even at the extensive margin, geographic diversification is more important than the upgrading process that leads to product diversification.
 
51
We have argued that partisan legislatures matter because they better enable the two important instruments for authoritarian regime survival: policy concessions and cooptation. Future analysis should look at via which instrument(s) partisan legislature affects regime survival.
 
52
For instance, Boix (1997) finds that left-wing governments spend heavily in physical and human capital formation to raise the productivity of factors and the competitiveness of the economy.
 
53
Interestingly, we find no evidence for an education spending race in developed country democracies and a negative and significant long-term effect of trade competition in developing country democracies. Details are reported in the Online Appendix, Section C. Why developing country democracies would spend less on education when their trade competitor countries spend more? Our speculation is that when trade competitors invest in education which causes actual or perceived loss of competitiveness for a developing democracy, the country reacts by increasing compensation to trade losers using “short-term-solution” policy instruments (e.g., subsidies) at the expense of the education spending.
 
54
Of course, mass mobilization is not a perfect measure of collective action. But in autocracies, mass mobilization is probably among the few ways for the public to express political demands.
 
55
This shift in focus to educational inequality is also raised by a recent review essay by Gift and Wibbels (2014).
 
Literature
go back to reference Acemoglu, D.J.A. (2006). Robinson Economic backwardness in political perspective. American Political Science Review, 100(1), 115–131.CrossRef Acemoglu, D.J.A. (2006). Robinson Economic backwardness in political perspective. American Political Science Review, 100(1), 115–131.CrossRef
go back to reference Aldomd, G., & Verba, S. (1963). The civic culture: Political attitudes and democracy in five nations princeton. NJ: Princeton University Press. Aldomd, G., & Verba, S. (1963). The civic culture: Political attitudes and democracy in five nations princeton. NJ: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Ames, B. (1987). Political Survival: Politicians and Public Policy in Latin America Vol. 12. Berkeley: University of California Press. Ames, B. (1987). Political Survival: Politicians and Public Policy in Latin America Vol. 12. Berkeley: University of California Press.
go back to reference Ansell, B.W. (2008). Traders, teachers, and tyrants: democracy, globalization, and public investment in education. International Organization, 62(02), 289–322.CrossRef Ansell, B.W. (2008). Traders, teachers, and tyrants: democracy, globalization, and public investment in education. International Organization, 62(02), 289–322.CrossRef
go back to reference Ansell, B.W. (2010). From the ballot to the blackboard: the redistributive political economy of education. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Ansell, B.W. (2010). From the ballot to the blackboard: the redistributive political economy of education. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Avelino, G., Hunter, D.S., Brown, W. (2005). The effects of capital mobility, trade openness, and democracy on social spending in Latin America, 1980-1999. American Journal of Political Science, 49(3), 625–641.CrossRef Avelino, G., Hunter, D.S., Brown, W. (2005). The effects of capital mobility, trade openness, and democracy on social spending in Latin America, 1980-1999. American Journal of Political Science, 49(3), 625–641.CrossRef
go back to reference Balassa, B. (1981). The newly industrializing countries in the world economy. New York: Pergamon Press. Balassa, B. (1981). The newly industrializing countries in the world economy. New York: Pergamon Press.
go back to reference Baum, M.A.D.A. (2003). Lake The political economy of growth: Democracy and human capital. American Journal of Political Science, 47(2), 333–347.CrossRef Baum, M.A.D.A. (2003). Lake The political economy of growth: Democracy and human capital. American Journal of Political Science, 47(2), 333–347.CrossRef
go back to reference Blanco, L., & Grier, R. (2012). Natural resource dependence and the accumulation of physical and human capital in Latin America. Resources Policy, 37(3), 281–295.CrossRef Blanco, L., & Grier, R. (2012). Natural resource dependence and the accumulation of physical and human capital in Latin America. Resources Policy, 37(3), 281–295.CrossRef
go back to reference Boix, C. (1997). Political parties and the supply side of the economy: The provision of physical and human capital in advanced economies, 1960-90. American Journal of Political Science, 41(3), 814–845.CrossRef Boix, C. (1997). Political parties and the supply side of the economy: The provision of physical and human capital in advanced economies, 1960-90. American Journal of Political Science, 41(3), 814–845.CrossRef
go back to reference Boix, C., & Stokes, S.C. (2003). Endogenous Democratization. World Politics, 55(4), 517–549.CrossRef Boix, C., & Stokes, S.C. (2003). Endogenous Democratization. World Politics, 55(4), 517–549.CrossRef
go back to reference Bourguignon, F., & Verdier, T. (2000). Oligarchy, Democracy, Inequality and Growth. Journal of Development Economics, 62(2), 285–313.CrossRef Bourguignon, F., & Verdier, T. (2000). Oligarchy, Democracy, Inequality and Growth. Journal of Development Economics, 62(2), 285–313.CrossRef
go back to reference Brady, H.E., Verba, S., Schlozman, K.L. (1995). Beyond ses: a resource model of political participation. The American Political Science Review, 89(2), 271–294.CrossRef Brady, H.E., Verba, S., Schlozman, K.L. (1995). Beyond ses: a resource model of political participation. The American Political Science Review, 89(2), 271–294.CrossRef
go back to reference Brooks, S.M. (2005). Interdependent and domestic foundations of policy change: The diffusion of pension privatization around the world. International Studies Quarterly, 49(2), 273–294.CrossRef Brooks, S.M. (2005). Interdependent and domestic foundations of policy change: The diffusion of pension privatization around the world. International Studies Quarterly, 49(2), 273–294.CrossRef
go back to reference Brooks, S.M. (2007). When does diffusion matter? explaining the spread of structural pension reforms across nations. The Journal of Politics, 69, 701–715.CrossRef Brooks, S.M. (2007). When does diffusion matter? explaining the spread of structural pension reforms across nations. The Journal of Politics, 69, 701–715.CrossRef
go back to reference Brooks, S.M., & Marcus, J. (2012). Kurtz paths to financial policy diffusion: Statist legacies in latin america’s globalization. International Organization, 66(1), 95–128.CrossRef Brooks, S.M., & Marcus, J. (2012). Kurtz paths to financial policy diffusion: Statist legacies in latin america’s globalization. International Organization, 66(1), 95–128.CrossRef
go back to reference Brown, D.S. (1999). Wendy hunter democracy and social spending in latin america, 1980-92. American Political Science Review, 93(4), 779–790.CrossRef Brown, D.S. (1999). Wendy hunter democracy and social spending in latin america, 1980-92. American Political Science Review, 93(4), 779–790.CrossRef
go back to reference Brown, D.S. (2004). Wendy hunter democracy and human capital formation. Comparative Political Studies, 37(7), 842–864.CrossRef Brown, D.S. (2004). Wendy hunter democracy and human capital formation. Comparative Political Studies, 37(7), 842–864.CrossRef
go back to reference Busch, P.-O., Tews, H., Kerstin, J. (2005). The global diffusion of regulatory instruments: The making of a new international environmental regime. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 598, 146–167.CrossRef Busch, P.-O., Tews, H., Kerstin, J. (2005). The global diffusion of regulatory instruments: The making of a new international environmental regime. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 598, 146–167.CrossRef
go back to reference Cameron, D.R. (1978). The expansion of the public economy: a comparative analysis. American Political Science Review, 72(4), 1243–1261.CrossRef Cameron, D.R. (1978). The expansion of the public economy: a comparative analysis. American Political Science Review, 72(4), 1243–1261.CrossRef
go back to reference Campante, F.R., & Chor, D. (2012). Schooling, political participation, and the economy. Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(4), 841–859.CrossRef Campante, F.R., & Chor, D. (2012). Schooling, political participation, and the economy. Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(4), 841–859.CrossRef
go back to reference Campbell, D.E. (2006). Why we vote: How schools and communities shape our civic life. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Campbell, D.E. (2006). Why we vote: How schools and communities shape our civic life. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Cao, X., & Prakash, A. (2010). Trade competition and domestic pollution: a panel study, 1980–2003. International Organization, 64(03), 481–503.CrossRef Cao, X., & Prakash, A. (2010). Trade competition and domestic pollution: a panel study, 1980–2003. International Organization, 64(03), 481–503.CrossRef
go back to reference Cao, X., & Prakash, A. (2012a). Trade competition and environmental regulations: Domestic political constraints and issue visibility. The Journal of Politics, 74(01), 66–82.CrossRef Cao, X., & Prakash, A. (2012a). Trade competition and environmental regulations: Domestic political constraints and issue visibility. The Journal of Politics, 74(01), 66–82.CrossRef
go back to reference Cao, X. (2012b). Global networks and domestic policy convergence: a network explanation of policy changes. World Politics, 64(3), 375–425.CrossRef Cao, X. (2012b). Global networks and domestic policy convergence: a network explanation of policy changes. World Politics, 64(3), 375–425.CrossRef
go back to reference Castelló, A., & Doménech, R. (2002). Human capital inequality and economic growth: Some new evidence. The Economic Journal, 112(478), C187–C200.CrossRef Castelló, A., & Doménech, R. (2002). Human capital inequality and economic growth: Some new evidence. The Economic Journal, 112(478), C187–C200.CrossRef
go back to reference Castelló-Climent, A. (2008). On the distribution of education and democracy. Journal of Development Economics, 87(2), 179–190.CrossRef Castelló-Climent, A. (2008). On the distribution of education and democracy. Journal of Development Economics, 87(2), 179–190.CrossRef
go back to reference Cheibub, J. (1998). Antonio political regimes and the extractive capacity of governments: Taxation in democracies and dictatorships. World Politics, 50, 349–376.CrossRef Cheibub, J. (1998). Antonio political regimes and the extractive capacity of governments: Taxation in democracies and dictatorships. World Politics, 50, 349–376.CrossRef
go back to reference Cheibub, J., Antonio, V., Gandhi, J., Raymond, J. (2010). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice, 143(1-2), 67–101.CrossRef Cheibub, J., Antonio, V., Gandhi, J., Raymond, J. (2010). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice, 143(1-2), 67–101.CrossRef
go back to reference Dahlum, S., & Wig, T. (Forthcoming). Educating Demonstrators: Education and Mass Protest in Africa. Journal of Conflict Resolution. Dahlum, S., & Wig, T. (Forthcoming). Educating Demonstrators: Education and Mass Protest in Africa. Journal of Conflict Resolution.
go back to reference De Boef, S., & Luke, S. (2008). Taking time seriously. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 184–200.CrossRef De Boef, S., & Luke, S. (2008). Taking time seriously. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 184–200.CrossRef
go back to reference De Mesquita, B.B., & Smith, A. (2010). Leader survival, revolutions, and the nature of government finance. American Journal of Political Science, 54(4), 936–950.CrossRef De Mesquita, B.B., & Smith, A. (2010). Leader survival, revolutions, and the nature of government finance. American Journal of Political Science, 54(4), 936–950.CrossRef
go back to reference Dee, T.S. (2004). Are there civic returns to education? Journal of Public Economics, 88(9-10), 1697–1720.CrossRef Dee, T.S. (2004). Are there civic returns to education? Journal of Public Economics, 88(9-10), 1697–1720.CrossRef
go back to reference Doner, R.F., Ritchie, B.K., Slater, D. (2005). Systemic Vulnerability and the Origins of Developmental States: Northeast and Southeast Asia in Comparative Perspective. Vol. 59 . Doner, R.F., Ritchie, B.K., Slater, D. (2005). Systemic Vulnerability and the Origins of Developmental States: Northeast and Southeast Asia in Comparative Perspective. Vol. 59 .
go back to reference Dreher, A. (2006). Does Globalization Affect Growth? Evidence from a new Index of Globalization. Applied Economics, 38(10), 1091–1110.CrossRef Dreher, A. (2006). Does Globalization Affect Growth? Evidence from a new Index of Globalization. Applied Economics, 38(10), 1091–1110.CrossRef
go back to reference Duflo, E. (2001). Schooling and labor market consequences of school construction in indonesia: Evidence from an unusual policy experiment. American Economic Review, 91(4), 795–813.CrossRef Duflo, E. (2001). Schooling and labor market consequences of school construction in indonesia: Evidence from an unusual policy experiment. American Economic Review, 91(4), 795–813.CrossRef
go back to reference Elis, R. (2011). Redistribution Under Oligarchy: Trade, Regional Inequality, and the Origins of Public Schooling in Argentina, 1862’1912. Elis, R. (2011). Redistribution Under Oligarchy: Trade, Regional Inequality, and the Origins of Public Schooling in Argentina, 1862’1912.
go back to reference Elkins, Z., Guzman, A., Simmons, B.A. (2006). Competing for capital: the diffusion of bilateral investment treaties, 1960-2000. International Organization, 60, 811–846.CrossRef Elkins, Z., Guzman, A., Simmons, B.A. (2006). Competing for capital: the diffusion of bilateral investment treaties, 1960-2000. International Organization, 60, 811–846.CrossRef
go back to reference Evans, G., & Rose, P. (2012). Understanding education’s influence on support for democracy in Sub-Saharan africa. Journal of Development Studies, 48(4), 498–515.CrossRef Evans, G., & Rose, P. (2012). Understanding education’s influence on support for democracy in Sub-Saharan africa. Journal of Development Studies, 48(4), 498–515.CrossRef
go back to reference Feng, Y. (1997). Democracy, political stability and economic growth. British Journal of Political Science, 27(3), 391–418.CrossRef Feng, Y. (1997). Democracy, political stability and economic growth. British Journal of Political Science, 27(3), 391–418.CrossRef
go back to reference Feng, Y., & Zak, P.J. (1999). The determinants of democratic transitions. The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 43(2), 162–177.CrossRef Feng, Y., & Zak, P.J. (1999). The determinants of democratic transitions. The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 43(2), 162–177.CrossRef
go back to reference Finkel, S.E. (2002). Civic education and the mobilization of political participation in developing democracies. The Journal of Politics, 64(4), 994–1020.CrossRef Finkel, S.E. (2002). Civic education and the mobilization of political participation in developing democracies. The Journal of Politics, 64(4), 994–1020.CrossRef
go back to reference Franzese, R.J, & Hays, J.C. (2008). Hays interdependence in comparative politics: substance, Theory, Empirics, Substance. Comparative Political Studies, 41 (4-5), 742–780.CrossRef Franzese, R.J, & Hays, J.C. (2008). Hays interdependence in comparative politics: substance, Theory, Empirics, Substance. Comparative Political Studies, 41 (4-5), 742–780.CrossRef
go back to reference Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2006). Das human kapital: a theory of the demise of the class structure. The Review of Economic Studies, 73(1), 85–117.CrossRef Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2006). Das human kapital: a theory of the demise of the class structure. The Review of Economic Studies, 73(1), 85–117.CrossRef
go back to reference Galor, O., Vollrath, O., Dietrich, M. (2009). Inequality in landownership, the emergence of Human-Capital promoting institutions, and the great divergence. Review of Economic Studies, 76(1), 143–179.CrossRef Galor, O., Vollrath, O., Dietrich, M. (2009). Inequality in landownership, the emergence of Human-Capital promoting institutions, and the great divergence. Review of Economic Studies, 76(1), 143–179.CrossRef
go back to reference Galston, W.A. (2001). Political knowledge, political engagement,and civic education. Annual Review of Political Science, 4, 217–234.CrossRef Galston, W.A. (2001). Political knowledge, political engagement,and civic education. Annual Review of Political Science, 4, 217–234.CrossRef
go back to reference Gandhi, J., & Przeworski, A. (2006). Cooperation, cooptation, and rebellion under dictatorships. Economics & Politics, 18(1), 1–26.CrossRef Gandhi, J., & Przeworski, A. (2006). Cooperation, cooptation, and rebellion under dictatorships. Economics & Politics, 18(1), 1–26.CrossRef
go back to reference Gandhi, J., & Przeworski, A. (2007). Authoritarian Institutions and the Survival of Autocrats. Comparative Political Studies, 40(11), 1279–1301.CrossRef Gandhi, J., & Przeworski, A. (2007). Authoritarian Institutions and the Survival of Autocrats. Comparative Political Studies, 40(11), 1279–1301.CrossRef
go back to reference Geddes, B. (1999). Authoritarian breakdown: Empirical test of a game theoretic argument. In Annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Vol. 2. Atlanta. Geddes, B. (1999). Authoritarian breakdown: Empirical test of a game theoretic argument. In Annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Vol. 2. Atlanta.
go back to reference Geddes, B, Frantz, J., Erica, W. (2014). Autocratic breakdown and regime transitions: a new data set. Perspectives on Politics 12(1). Geddes, B, Frantz, J., Erica, W. (2014). Autocratic breakdown and regime transitions: a new data set. Perspectives on Politics 12(1).
go back to reference Gibson, J.L., Tedin, R.M., Duch, K.L. (1992). Democratic values and the transformation of the Soviet-Union. Journal of Politics, 54(2), 329–371.CrossRef Gibson, J.L., Tedin, R.M., Duch, K.L. (1992). Democratic values and the transformation of the Soviet-Union. Journal of Politics, 54(2), 329–371.CrossRef
go back to reference Gift, T., & Wibbels, E. (2014). Reading, writing, and the regrettable status of education research in comparative politics. Annual Review of Political Science, 17 (1), 291–312.CrossRef Gift, T., & Wibbels, E. (2014). Reading, writing, and the regrettable status of education research in comparative politics. Annual Review of Political Science, 17 (1), 291–312.CrossRef
go back to reference Gilardi, F. (2010). Who Learns from What in Policy Diffusion Processes? American Journal of Political Science, 54(3), 650–666.CrossRef Gilardi, F. (2010). Who Learns from What in Policy Diffusion Processes? American Journal of Political Science, 54(3), 650–666.CrossRef
go back to reference Glaeser, E.L., La Porta, R., Lopez-de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. (2004). Do Institutions Cause Growth? Journal of Economic Growth, 9(3), 271–303.CrossRef Glaeser, E.L., La Porta, R., Lopez-de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. (2004). Do Institutions Cause Growth? Journal of Economic Growth, 9(3), 271–303.CrossRef
go back to reference Glaeser, E.L., Ponzetto, G.A.M., Shleifer, A. (2007). Why does democracy need education? Journal of Economic Growth, 12(2), 77–99.CrossRef Glaeser, E.L., Ponzetto, G.A.M., Shleifer, A. (2007). Why does democracy need education? Journal of Economic Growth, 12(2), 77–99.CrossRef
go back to reference Gleditsch, K.S. (2002). Expanded trade and GDP data. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(5), 712–724.CrossRef Gleditsch, K.S. (2002). Expanded trade and GDP data. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(5), 712–724.CrossRef
go back to reference Goldberg, P.N. (2007). Pavcnik distributional effects of trade liberalization in developing countries. Journal of Economic Literature, 45(1), 39–82.CrossRef Goldberg, P.N. (2007). Pavcnik distributional effects of trade liberalization in developing countries. Journal of Economic Literature, 45(1), 39–82.CrossRef
go back to reference Grant, T., & Lebo, M.J. (2016). Error correction methods with political time series. Political Analysis, 24(1), 3–30.CrossRef Grant, T., & Lebo, M.J. (2016). Error correction methods with political time series. Political Analysis, 24(1), 3–30.CrossRef
go back to reference Gygli, S., Haelg, F., Sturm, J.-E. (2018). The KOF globalisation index: Revisited. KOF working paper No.439. Gygli, S., Haelg, F., Sturm, J.-E. (2018). The KOF globalisation index: Revisited. KOF working paper No.439.
go back to reference Gylfason, T. (2001). Natural resources, education, and economic development. European Economic Review, 45(4-6), 847–859.CrossRef Gylfason, T. (2001). Natural resources, education, and economic development. European Economic Review, 45(4-6), 847–859.CrossRef
go back to reference Hecock, R. (2006). Douglas Electoral competition, globalization, and subnational education spending in Mexico, 1999–2004. American Journal of Political Science, 50 (4), 950–961.CrossRef Hecock, R. (2006). Douglas Electoral competition, globalization, and subnational education spending in Mexico, 1999–2004. American Journal of Political Science, 50 (4), 950–961.CrossRef
go back to reference Helliwell, J.F. (1994). Empirical linkages between democracy and Economic-Growth. British Journal Of Political Science, 24, 225–248.CrossRef Helliwell, J.F. (1994). Empirical linkages between democracy and Economic-Growth. British Journal Of Political Science, 24, 225–248.CrossRef
go back to reference Henn, C., Papageorgiou, C., Spatafora, N. (2015). Export quality in advanced and developing economies: Evidence from a new dataset Technical report World Trade Organization (WTO), Economic Research and Statistics Division. Henn, C., Papageorgiou, C., Spatafora, N. (2015). Export quality in advanced and developing economies: Evidence from a new dataset Technical report World Trade Organization (WTO), Economic Research and Statistics Division.
go back to reference Hong, J.Y. (Forthcoming). How Natural Resources Affect Authoritarian Leaders’ Provision of Public Services: Evidence from China. The Journal of Politics. Hong, J.Y. (Forthcoming). How Natural Resources Affect Authoritarian Leaders’ Provision of Public Services: Evidence from China. The Journal of Politics.
go back to reference Huber, E., Mustillo, T., Stephens, J.D. (2008). Politics and social spending in Latin America. The Journal of Politics, 70(2), 420–436.CrossRef Huber, E., Mustillo, T., Stephens, J.D. (2008). Politics and social spending in Latin America. The Journal of Politics, 70(2), 420–436.CrossRef
go back to reference Im, K.S., Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y. (2003). Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics, 115(1), 53–74.CrossRef Im, K.S., Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y. (2003). Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics, 115(1), 53–74.CrossRef
go back to reference Kadera, K.M., Crescenzi, M.J.C., Shannon, M.L. (2003). Democratic survival, peace and war. American Journal of Political Science, 47(2), 234–247.CrossRef Kadera, K.M., Crescenzi, M.J.C., Shannon, M.L. (2003). Democratic survival, peace and war. American Journal of Political Science, 47(2), 234–247.CrossRef
go back to reference Kaufman, R.R., & Segura-Ubiergo, A. (2001). Globalization, domestic politics, and social spending in Latin America. World Politics, 53(4), 553–87.CrossRef Kaufman, R.R., & Segura-Ubiergo, A. (2001). Globalization, domestic politics, and social spending in Latin America. World Politics, 53(4), 553–87.CrossRef
go back to reference Keele, L., Linn, S., McLaughlin Webb, C. (2016). Erratum for Keele, Linn, and Webb, (2016). Political Analysis. Keele, L., Linn, S., McLaughlin Webb, C. (2016). Erratum for Keele, Linn, and Webb, (2016). Political Analysis.
go back to reference Kosack, S. (2013). The logic of Pro-Poor policymaking: Political entrepreneurship and mass education. British Journal of Political Science, pp. 1–36. Kosack, S. (2013). The logic of Pro-Poor policymaking: Political entrepreneurship and mass education. British Journal of Political Science, pp. 1–36.
go back to reference Krueger, A.B., & Lindahl, M. (2001). Education for Growth: Why and For Whom? Journal of Economic Literature, 39(4), 1101–1136.CrossRef Krueger, A.B., & Lindahl, M. (2001). Education for Growth: Why and For Whom? Journal of Economic Literature, 39(4), 1101–1136.CrossRef
go back to reference Kurtz, M.J., & Brooks, S.M. (2011). Conditioning the resource curse: globalization, Human Capital, and Growth in Oil-Rich Nations. Comparative Political Studies, 44(6), 747–770.CrossRef Kurtz, M.J., & Brooks, S.M. (2011). Conditioning the resource curse: globalization, Human Capital, and Growth in Oil-Rich Nations. Comparative Political Studies, 44(6), 747–770.CrossRef
go back to reference Larreguy, H, Montiel, C.E., Querubin, O.P. (2017). Political Brokers: Partisans or Agents? Evidence from the Mexican Teachers’ Union. American Journal of Political Science, 61(4), 877–891.CrossRef Larreguy, H, Montiel, C.E., Querubin, O.P. (2017). Political Brokers: Partisans or Agents? Evidence from the Mexican Teachers’ Union. American Journal of Political Science, 61(4), 877–891.CrossRef
go back to reference Lebo, M.J., & Grant, T. (2016). Equation balance and dynamic political modeling. Political Analysis, 24(1), 69–82.CrossRef Lebo, M.J., & Grant, T. (2016). Equation balance and dynamic political modeling. Political Analysis, 24(1), 69–82.CrossRef
go back to reference Levin, A., Lin, C.F., Chu, C.S.J. (2002). Unit root tests in panel data: Asymptotic and finite-sample properties. Journal of Econometrics, 108(1), 1–24.CrossRef Levin, A., Lin, C.F., Chu, C.S.J. (2002). Unit root tests in panel data: Asymptotic and finite-sample properties. Journal of Econometrics, 108(1), 1–24.CrossRef
go back to reference Levine, R., & Renelt, D. (1992). A sensitivity analysis of Cross-Country growth regressions. The American Economic Review, 82(4), 942–963. Levine, R., & Renelt, D. (1992). A sensitivity analysis of Cross-Country growth regressions. The American Economic Review, 82(4), 942–963.
go back to reference Levitsky, S., & Way, L. (2002). The rise of competitive authoritarianism. Journal of democracy, 13(2), 51–65.CrossRef Levitsky, S., & Way, L. (2002). The rise of competitive authoritarianism. Journal of democracy, 13(2), 51–65.CrossRef
go back to reference Lindert, P.H. (2004). Growing public social spending and economic growth since the eighteenth century. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Lindert, P.H. (2004). Growing public social spending and economic growth since the eighteenth century. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference López-Cariboni, S., & Cao, X. (2015). Import competition and policy diffusion. Politics & Society, 43(4), 471–502.CrossRef López-Cariboni, S., & Cao, X. (2015). Import competition and policy diffusion. Politics & Society, 43(4), 471–502.CrossRef
go back to reference Lucas, R.E. Jr. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of monetary economics, 22(1), 3–42.CrossRef Lucas, R.E. Jr. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of monetary economics, 22(1), 3–42.CrossRef
go back to reference Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D., Weil, D.N. (1992). Gregory a contribution to the empirics of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 407–437.CrossRef Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D., Weil, D.N. (1992). Gregory a contribution to the empirics of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 407–437.CrossRef
go back to reference Marshall, M.G., Jaggers, K., Gurr, T.R. (2011). Polity IV project: Dataset users’ manual. Center for Systemic Peace, Polity IV Project. Marshall, M.G., Jaggers, K., Gurr, T.R. (2011). Polity IV project: Dataset users’ manual. Center for Systemic Peace, Polity IV Project.
go back to reference Miller, M.K. (2012). Economic development, violent leader removal, and democratization. American Journal of Political Science, 56(4), 1002–1020.CrossRef Miller, M.K. (2012). Economic development, violent leader removal, and democratization. American Journal of Political Science, 56(4), 1002–1020.CrossRef
go back to reference Morrison, K.M. (2009). Oil, nontax revenue, and the redistributional foundations of regime stability. International Organization, 107–138. Morrison, K.M. (2009). Oil, nontax revenue, and the redistributional foundations of regime stability. International Organization, 107–138.
go back to reference Mulligan, C.B., Gil, R., Sala-i Martin, X. (2004). Do Democracies Have Different Public Policies than Nondemocracies? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18 (1), 51–74.CrossRef Mulligan, C.B., Gil, R., Sala-i Martin, X. (2004). Do Democracies Have Different Public Policies than Nondemocracies? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18 (1), 51–74.CrossRef
go back to reference Nooruddin, I., & Simmons, J.W. (2009). Openness, uncertainty, and social spending: Implications for the Globalization-Welfare state debate. International Studies Quarterly, 53(3), 841–866.CrossRef Nooruddin, I., & Simmons, J.W. (2009). Openness, uncertainty, and social spending: Implications for the Globalization-Welfare state debate. International Studies Quarterly, 53(3), 841–866.CrossRef
go back to reference Papaioannou, E., & Siourounis, G. (2008). Economic and social factors driving the third wave of democratization. Journal of Comparative Economics, 36(3), 365–387.CrossRef Papaioannou, E., & Siourounis, G. (2008). Economic and social factors driving the third wave of democratization. Journal of Comparative Economics, 36(3), 365–387.CrossRef
go back to reference Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M.E., Limongi, J.A., Fernando, C. (2000). Democracy and development: Political institutions and Well-Being in the world, (pp. 1950–1990). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M.E., Limongi, J.A., Fernando, C. (2000). Democracy and development: Political institutions and Well-Being in the world, (pp. 1950–1990). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Reiter, D. (2001). Does Peace Nurture Democracy?. The Journal of Politics, 63(3), 935–948.CrossRef Reiter, D. (2001). Does Peace Nurture Democracy?. The Journal of Politics, 63(3), 935–948.CrossRef
go back to reference Reuter, O.J., & Robertson, G.B. (2015). Legislatures, cooptation, and social protest in contemporary authoritarian regimes. The Journal of Politics, 77(1), 235–248.CrossRef Reuter, O.J., & Robertson, G.B. (2015). Legislatures, cooptation, and social protest in contemporary authoritarian regimes. The Journal of Politics, 77(1), 235–248.CrossRef
go back to reference Romer, P.M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), S71–S102. Romer, P.M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), S71–S102.
go back to reference Ross, M. (2006). Is democracy good for the poor ? American Journal of Political Science, 50(4), 860–874.CrossRef Ross, M. (2006). Is democracy good for the poor ? American Journal of Political Science, 50(4), 860–874.CrossRef
go back to reference Ross, M.L. (2012). The Oil Curse. How Petroleum Wealth Shapes the Development of Nations, Princeton University Press, Princeton. Ross, M.L. (2012). The Oil Curse. How Petroleum Wealth Shapes the Development of Nations, Princeton University Press, Princeton.
go back to reference Rousseau, D.L., Gelpi, C., Reiter, D., Huth, P.K. (1996). Assessing the dyadic nature of the democratic peace, 1918-88. American Political Science Review, 90(03), 512–533.CrossRef Rousseau, D.L., Gelpi, C., Reiter, D., Huth, P.K. (1996). Assessing the dyadic nature of the democratic peace, 1918-88. American Political Science Review, 90(03), 512–533.CrossRef
go back to reference Rudra, N. (2004). Openness, welfare spending, and inequality in the developing world. International Studies Quarterly, 48(3), 683–709.CrossRef Rudra, N. (2004). Openness, welfare spending, and inequality in the developing world. International Studies Quarterly, 48(3), 683–709.CrossRef
go back to reference Rudra, N., & Haggard, S. (2005). Globalization, democracy, and effective welfare spending in the developing world. Comparative Political Studies, 38(9), 1015–1049.CrossRef Rudra, N., & Haggard, S. (2005). Globalization, democracy, and effective welfare spending in the developing world. Comparative Political Studies, 38(9), 1015–1049.CrossRef
go back to reference Sala-i Martin, X., Doppelhofer, G., Miller, R.I. (2004). Determinants of Long-Term growth: a bayesian averaging of classical estimates (BACE) approach. The American Economic Review, 94(4), 813–835.CrossRef Sala-i Martin, X., Doppelhofer, G., Miller, R.I. (2004). Determinants of Long-Term growth: a bayesian averaging of classical estimates (BACE) approach. The American Economic Review, 94(4), 813–835.CrossRef
go back to reference Sanborn, H., & Thyne, C. (2014). Learning Democracy: Education and the Fall of Authoritarian Regimes. British Journal of Political Science, 44(4), 773–797.CrossRef Sanborn, H., & Thyne, C. (2014). Learning Democracy: Education and the Fall of Authoritarian Regimes. British Journal of Political Science, 44(4), 773–797.CrossRef
go back to reference Schedler, A. (2006). Electoral authoritarianism: The dynamics of unfree competition. Schedler, A. (2006). Electoral authoritarianism: The dynamics of unfree competition.
go back to reference Sianesi, B., & Van Reenen, J. (2003). The returns to education: Macroeconomics. Journal of Economic Surveys, 17(2), 157–200.CrossRef Sianesi, B., & Van Reenen, J. (2003). The returns to education: Macroeconomics. Journal of Economic Surveys, 17(2), 157–200.CrossRef
go back to reference Simmons, B.A. (2004). Zachary elkins the globalization of liberalization: Policy diffusion in the international political economy. American Political Science Review, 98, 171–189.CrossRef Simmons, B.A. (2004). Zachary elkins the globalization of liberalization: Policy diffusion in the international political economy. American Political Science Review, 98, 171–189.CrossRef
go back to reference Simmons, B.A., Dobbin, F., Garrett, G. (2006). Introduction: The international diffusion of liberalism. International Organization, 60, 781–810.CrossRef Simmons, B.A., Dobbin, F., Garrett, G. (2006). Introduction: The international diffusion of liberalism. International Organization, 60, 781–810.CrossRef
go back to reference Smith, B. (2005). Life of the party: The origins of regime breakdown and persistence under single-party rule. World Politics, 57(03), 421–451.CrossRef Smith, B. (2005). Life of the party: The origins of regime breakdown and persistence under single-party rule. World Politics, 57(03), 421–451.CrossRef
go back to reference Stasavage, D. (2005). Democracy and education spending in africa. American Journal of Political Science, 49(2), 343–358.CrossRef Stasavage, D. (2005). Democracy and education spending in africa. American Journal of Political Science, 49(2), 343–358.CrossRef
go back to reference The World Bank. (2012). World development indicators. Washington: The World Bank (producer and distributor). The World Bank. (2012). World development indicators. Washington: The World Bank (producer and distributor).
go back to reference Verba, S., Nie Nie, N.H., Kimw, J.-O. (1978). Participation and political equality: A seven-nation comparison, University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Verba, S., Nie Nie, N.H., Kimw, J.-O. (1978). Participation and political equality: A seven-nation comparison, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
go back to reference Wantchekon, L., Novta, N., Klašnja, M. (2012). Education and Human Capital Externalities: Evidence from Colonial Benin. Wantchekon, L., Novta, N., Klašnja, M. (2012). Education and Human Capital Externalities: Evidence from Colonial Benin.
go back to reference Ward, H., & Cao, X. (2012). Domestic and international influences on green taxation. Comparative Political Studies, 45(9), 1075–1103.CrossRef Ward, H., & Cao, X. (2012). Domestic and international influences on green taxation. Comparative Political Studies, 45(9), 1075–1103.CrossRef
go back to reference Way, C.R. (2005). Political insecurity and the diffusion of financial market regulation. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 598, 125–144.CrossRef Way, C.R. (2005). Political insecurity and the diffusion of financial market regulation. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 598, 125–144.CrossRef
go back to reference Webber, D. (2002). Policies to stimulate growth: should we invest in health or education? Applied Economics, 34(13), 1633–1643.CrossRef Webber, D. (2002). Policies to stimulate growth: should we invest in health or education? Applied Economics, 34(13), 1633–1643.CrossRef
go back to reference Wibbels, E., & Ahlquist, J.S. (2011). Development, trade, and social insurance. International Studies Quarterly, 55(1), 125–149.CrossRef Wibbels, E., & Ahlquist, J.S. (2011). Development, trade, and social insurance. International Studies Quarterly, 55(1), 125–149.CrossRef
go back to reference Wright, J. (2008). Do authoritarian institutions constrain? how legislatures affect economic growth and investment. American Journal of Political Science, 52(2), 322–343.CrossRef Wright, J. (2008). Do authoritarian institutions constrain? how legislatures affect economic growth and investment. American Journal of Political Science, 52(2), 322–343.CrossRef
go back to reference Wright, J., & Escriba-Folch, A. (2012). Authoritarian institutions and regime survival: Transitions to democracy and subsequent autocracy. British Journal of Political Science, 42, 283–309.CrossRef Wright, J., & Escriba-Folch, A. (2012). Authoritarian institutions and regime survival: Transitions to democracy and subsequent autocracy. British Journal of Political Science, 42, 283–309.CrossRef
go back to reference Zagha, R., & Nankani, G.T. (2005). Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning from a Decade of Reform. World Bank Publications. Zagha, R., & Nankani, G.T. (2005). Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning from a Decade of Reform. World Bank Publications.
Metadata
Title
When do authoritarian rulers educate: Trade competition and human capital investment in Non-Democracies
Authors
Santiago López-Cariboni
Xun Cao
Publication date
22-05-2018
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
The Review of International Organizations / Issue 3/2019
Print ISSN: 1559-7431
Electronic ISSN: 1559-744X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-018-9311-x

Other articles of this Issue 3/2019

The Review of International Organizations 3/2019 Go to the issue