Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Review of Industrial Organization 3/2021

16-07-2020

Comparing Cournot and Bertrand Equilibria in the Presence of Spatial Barriers and R&D

Authors: Kuang-Cheng Andy Wang, Yi-Jie Wang, Wen-Jung Liang

Published in: Review of Industrial Organization | Issue 3/2021

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We compare the equilibria under Bertrand and Cournot competition in the spatial barbell model where spatial barriers and process R&D are involved. We show that when the market becomes more competitive by switching from Cournot to Bertrand competition, R&D investment may increase (decrease) depending upon a low (high) transport rate. Next, we find that under Cournot competition total output, consumer surplus, and welfare are higher, but profit is lower than is true for Bertrand competition, when the transport rate is high, which overturns the traditional result.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
Theoretically, Schumpeter (1943) argues that firms are more innovative in a weaker competitive market, while Arrow (1962) reaches the opposite conclusion. The empirical evidence on the relationship between competition and innovation is also mixed. See, for example, Aghion et al. (2005) and Tang (2006).
 
2
Some studies—such as Delbono and Denicolo (1990), Mukherjee (2011), and Chang et al. (2017)—also compare the equilibria between Cournot and Bertrand competition.
 
3
If the firms engage in Bertrand competition in each market, then each firm has the opportunity to price discriminate between the two markets by charging a limit price that is slightly lower than the rival’s marginal cost plus transport cost in its advantageous market, and a limit price that equals its own marginal cost plus transport cost in the remote market.
 
4
By equating the equilibrium price with the monopoly price, we can obtain the cap on the transport rate in (5). Note that the condition—\( \left| {c_{A} - c_{B} } \right| \le t[\left( {1 - x_{B}^{U} } \right) - x_{A}^{U} ] \)—is needed in deriving (5) to ensure that the high-cost firm can survive. Intuitively, as the monopoly profit is the largest profit that the firms can earn, the firms will keep charging the monopoly price to earn this largest profit even though they are capable of charging a limit price that is higher than the monopoly price when the transport rate is higher than \( \overline{t} \). Accordingly, we define \( \overline{t} \) as the cap on the transport rate under Bertrand competition, because all of the results for those transport rates that are higher than \( \overline{t} \) are the same as the result at \( \overline{t} \).
 
5
Note that the total output and then the price in each market could differ across the two markets, if the markets and the firms are asymmetric. However, they are identical across the two markets in equilibrium when the markets and the firms are symmetric.
 
6
The second-order and the stability conditions are all fulfilled.
 
7
From the cap of t in (5), we can obtain this inequality.
 
8
The restriction, \( \gamma > 8/3 \), is the stability condition under Cournot competition, which can ensure that both the second-order condition under Cournot competition and the stability condition under Bertrand competition are satisfied. The proof can be provided by the authors upon request.
 
9
By substituting the equilibrium values of \( \varepsilon_{i}^{{U^{*} }} \) and (x A U* , x B U* ) = (0, 0), which are solved in stages 1 and 2, into \( \bar{t} \) in (5), we can rewrite \( \bar{t} \) in a reduced form denoted by \( \overline{\overline{t}} = \gamma \left( {1 - c} \right)/\left( {2\gamma - 1} \right) \), which contains exogenous variables only. \( \overline{\overline{t}} \) is denoted as a threshold of the transport rate, which will lead the limit price to be equal to the monopoly price in the equilibrium under Bertrand competition. The restriction t < \( \overline{\overline{t}} \) corresponds to the case where the monopolist will never charge a limit price that is higher than the monopoly price in the equilibrium under Bertrand competition.
 
10
Provided that the firms’ locations are (x A U* , x B U* ) = (x A C* , x B C* ) = (0, 0) under Bertrand competition and Cournot competition, respectively, we can obtain from (2), (3), and (7) that \( q_{ki}^{U} = 1 - t - c + \varepsilon_{i}^{{U^{*} }} \), and \( q_{Li}^{C} + q_{Ri}^{C} = \left[ {2\left( {1 - c + \varepsilon_{i}^{{C^{*} }} } \right) - t} \right]/3 \), i = A, B. Thus, Bertrand total output is greater than Cournot total output for the same t and εi, where \( t < \overline{\overline{t}} \).
 
11
By differentiating the equations in footnote 10 with respect to t, we can derive that \( \partial q_{ki}^{U} /\partial t = - 1 < \left( {4/3} \right)\left( {\partial \left( {q_{Li}^{C} + q_{Ri}^{C} } \right)/\partial t} \right) = - 4/9 \) for any given εi.
 
12
The difference between Cournot and Bertrand R&D is increasing in the transport rate, which can be proved by differentiating (15) with respect to t as \( \partial \left( {\varepsilon_{i}^{{C^{*} }} - \varepsilon_{i}^{{U^{*} }} } \right)/\partial t = \left( {5\gamma - 4} \right)/\left[ {\left( {\gamma - 1} \right)\left( {9\gamma - 8} \right)} \right] > 0 \) where γ > 8/3.
 
13
Note that the total profit is the sum of the two firms’ profits. As the markets are symmetric, the two firms’ profits are identical, regardless of the competition mode.
 
14
Differentiating Bertrand firm i’s profit with respect to t yields \( \frac{{d\pi_{i}^{U} }}{dt} = \frac{{\partial \pi_{i}^{U} }}{\partial t} + \frac{{\partial \pi_{i}^{U} }}{{\partial \varepsilon_{j}^{U} }}\frac{{\partial \varepsilon_{j}^{U} }}{\partial t}, i \ne j, i,j = A,B. \) The first and second terms on the right-hand side of the above equation denote the direct and R&D effects, respectively.
 
15
Differentiating Cournot firm i’s profit with respect to t yields \( \frac{{d\pi_{i}^{C} }}{dt} = \left[ {\frac{{\partial \pi_{Li}^{C} }}{\partial t} + \frac{{\partial \pi_{Ri}^{C} }}{\partial t}} \right] + \left[ {\frac{{\partial \pi_{Li}^{C} }}{{\partial \varepsilon_{j}^{C} }}\frac{{\partial \varepsilon_{j}^{C} }}{\partial t} + \frac{{\partial \pi_{Ri}^{C} }}{{\partial \varepsilon_{j}^{C} }}\frac{{\partial \varepsilon_{j}^{C} }}{\partial t}} \right], i \ne j, i,j = A,B. \) The first and second terms on the right-hand side of the above equation denote the direct and R&D effects, respectively.
 
16
The total surplus is the sum of the areas beneath the demand curves and above the marginal production cost curves in the two markets.
 
17
Recall that γ > 8/3. We find from footnote 9 and (15) that \( t_{0} < \overline{\overline{t}} \).
 
18
Recall that γ > 8/3 and footnote 9. We can obtain that \( \overline{\overline{t}} - t_{1} = 2\left( {1 - c} \right)\left( {\gamma - 1} \right)/\left[ {\left( {2\gamma - 1} \right)\left( {6\gamma - 5} \right)} \right] > 0 \).
 
19
Recall that γ > 8/3 and footnote 9. We can figure out that
$$ \overline{\overline{t}} - t_{2} = \frac{{\gamma \left( {1 - c} \right)\left[ {\sqrt {\left( {9\gamma^{2} + 2\gamma - 4} \right)\left( {9\gamma - 8} \right)^{2} \left( {\gamma - 1} \right)^{2} } \left( {2\gamma - 1} \right) + H_{5} } \right]}}{{H_{1} \left( {2\gamma - 1} \right)}} > 0, $$
where \( H_{5} = 54\gamma^{4} - 186\gamma^{3} + 242\gamma^{2} - 142\gamma + 32 > 0 \).
 
20
By manipulating, we obtain from footnote 9 and (19) that
$$ t_{3} - \overline{\overline{t}} = \frac{{\gamma (1 - c)\left\lfloor {\sqrt {(4\gamma - 3)(9\gamma - 8)} (2\gamma - 1) - (12\gamma^{2} - 15\gamma + 4)} \right\rfloor }}{{(20\gamma^{2} - 27\gamma + 8)(2\gamma - 1)}} .$$
Based on the restriction that γ > 8/3, the denominator is positive. Moreover, through manipulations we can show that the numerator is negative. It follows that \( t_{3} - \overline{\overline{t}} < 0 \).
 
Literature
go back to reference Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., & Howitt, P. (2005). Competition and innovation: An inverted-U relationship. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 701–728. Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., & Howitt, P. (2005). Competition and innovation: An inverted-U relationship. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 701–728.
go back to reference Arrow, K. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In R. Nelson (Ed.), The rate and direction of inventive activity (pp. 609–626). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRef Arrow, K. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In R. Nelson (Ed.), The rate and direction of inventive activity (pp. 609–626). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference d’Aspremont, C., Gabzewicz, J., & Thisse, J. F. (1979). On Hotelling’s stability in competition. Econometrica, 47(5), 1145–1150.CrossRef d’Aspremont, C., Gabzewicz, J., & Thisse, J. F. (1979). On Hotelling’s stability in competition. Econometrica, 47(5), 1145–1150.CrossRef
go back to reference Delbono, F., & Denicolo, V. (1990). R&D investment in a symmetric and homogeneous oligopoly. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 8, 297–313.CrossRef Delbono, F., & Denicolo, V. (1990). R&D investment in a symmetric and homogeneous oligopoly. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 8, 297–313.CrossRef
go back to reference Hwang, H., & Mai, C. C. (1990). Effects of spatial price discrimination on output, welfare, and location. American Economic Review, 80, 567–575. Hwang, H., & Mai, C. C. (1990). Effects of spatial price discrimination on output, welfare, and location. American Economic Review, 80, 567–575.
go back to reference Liang, W. J., Hwang, H., & Mai, C. C. (2006). Spatial discrimination: Bertrand vs. Cournot with asymmetric demands. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 36(6), 790–802.CrossRef Liang, W. J., Hwang, H., & Mai, C. C. (2006). Spatial discrimination: Bertrand vs. Cournot with asymmetric demands. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 36(6), 790–802.CrossRef
go back to reference Lin, P., & Saggi, K. (2002). Product differentiation, process R&D, and the nature of market competition. European Economic Review, 46, 201–211.CrossRef Lin, P., & Saggi, K. (2002). Product differentiation, process R&D, and the nature of market competition. European Economic Review, 46, 201–211.CrossRef
go back to reference Mukherjee, A. (2011). Competition, innovation and welfare. Manchester School, 79(6), 1045–1057.CrossRef Mukherjee, A. (2011). Competition, innovation and welfare. Manchester School, 79(6), 1045–1057.CrossRef
go back to reference Qiu, L. (1997). On the dynamic efficiency of Bertrand and Cournot equilibria. Journal of Economic Theory, 75, 213–229.CrossRef Qiu, L. (1997). On the dynamic efficiency of Bertrand and Cournot equilibria. Journal of Economic Theory, 75, 213–229.CrossRef
go back to reference Schumpeter, J. (1943). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. London: Allen & Unwin. Schumpeter, J. (1943). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. London: Allen & Unwin.
go back to reference Singh, N., & Vives, X. (1984). Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly. Rand Journal of Economics, 15, 546–554.CrossRef Singh, N., & Vives, X. (1984). Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly. Rand Journal of Economics, 15, 546–554.CrossRef
go back to reference Sun, C. H., & Lai, F. C. (2014). Spatial price discrimination in a symmetric barbell model: Bertrand vs. Cournot. Papers in Regional Science, 93, 141–158.CrossRef Sun, C. H., & Lai, F. C. (2014). Spatial price discrimination in a symmetric barbell model: Bertrand vs. Cournot. Papers in Regional Science, 93, 141–158.CrossRef
go back to reference Tang, J. (2006). Competition and innovation behavior. Research Policy, 35, 68–82.CrossRef Tang, J. (2006). Competition and innovation behavior. Research Policy, 35, 68–82.CrossRef
go back to reference Wang, K. C. A., Tseng, C. C., & Liang, W. J. (2016). Patent licensing in the presence of trade barriers. Japanese Economic Review, 67(3), 329–347.CrossRef Wang, K. C. A., Tseng, C. C., & Liang, W. J. (2016). Patent licensing in the presence of trade barriers. Japanese Economic Review, 67(3), 329–347.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Comparing Cournot and Bertrand Equilibria in the Presence of Spatial Barriers and R&D
Authors
Kuang-Cheng Andy Wang
Yi-Jie Wang
Wen-Jung Liang
Publication date
16-07-2020
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Review of Industrial Organization / Issue 3/2021
Print ISSN: 0889-938X
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7160
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-020-09775-x

Other articles of this Issue 3/2021

Review of Industrial Organization 3/2021 Go to the issue

Premium Partner