Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 3-4/2018

04-07-2018

Court-ordered redistricting and the law of 1/n

Authors: Dongwon Lee, Sangwon Park

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 3-4/2018

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper examines the effect of redistricting on the law of 1/n, which posits that government spending increases with the number of legislative districts. Our analysis suggests that court-ordered redistricting in the 1960s significantly influenced the 1/n effect, because dividing districts (increasing their number) and merging districts (reducing their number) both reduce public spending. After redistricting, the positive relationship between seats and spending holds for lower chambers in bicameral legislatures. The US experience informs those interested in the design of bicameral institutions about the fiscal implications of legislative apportionment.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
More specifically, each of n legislative districts internalizes only a fraction (1/n) of the cost of all projects. See Lee (2015) for a more detailed discussion of the law of 1/n.
 
2
Some recent studies also report inconsistent findings at the local government levels (e.g., MacDonald 2008; Jordahl and Liang 2010; Petterson-Lidbom 2012).
 
3
Suppose that a winning coalition requires two-thirds of the lower house districts nested within half of the upper house districts. The share of the lower house districts needed to win the simple majority of the upper house is 1 / 3 (that is, 2 / 3 \(\times\) 1 / 2). Thus, a simple majority of the lower house is sufficient to win the upper house.
 
4
The assumption about House districts embedded in Senate districts follows the previous literature (e.g., Ansolabehere et al. 2003; Chen and Malhotra 2007. In some states, House district lines cut across the Senate district lines, but that is not critical for the main results.
 
5
Although many states had multi-member districts in the 1960s and 1970s, single-member districts became popular gradually as the courts ruled increasingly that multi-member districts hurt minority representation. See Crain (1977) for related discussions.
 
6
This setup allows us to better identify the effect of redistricting in both chambers.
 
7
We assume a closed rule in which legislators are not allowed to offer amendments once a proposal has been made.
 
8
Alternatively, a proposer can be selected from S. The alternative setup yields qualitatively similar results.
 
9
We assume that \(A > 1\) to guarantee interior solutions.
 
10
This assumption rules out weakly dominated strategies.
 
11
Remark The basic model assumes that each of m Senate districts is divided into an equal number of House districts. If that assumption is relaxed, the jth Senate district (\(j \in \{1,\ldots , m \}\)) would be divided into \(k_{j}\) House districts, where \(k_{1}\le \cdots \le k_{m}.\) Then, \(n=\sum _{j=1}^{m}k_{j}\) is the total number of House districts. In that case, we still obtain qualitatively similar results. Proofs are available upon request to the authors.
 
12
A winning coalition must include more than half of the House districts in more than half of the Senate districts. The number of House legislators required for a Senate majority is then \(\frac{1}{4} n\) (i.e., \(\frac{1}{2} m\) senators times \(\frac{1}{2} k\) representatives). A simple majority of House districts is sufficient for winning the Senate.
 
13
In equilibrium, the proposer induces a coalition member to agree on the bill with the default payoff of 0.
 
14
By totally differentiating (3), we obtain \(dg/dG= \frac{1}{n} \cdot \frac{1}{u^{\prime }(g) - \frac{{\widetilde{d}}(n)-1}{n}}\), which is greater than 0 because \(u^{\prime }(g) > \frac{{\widetilde{d}}(n)-1}{n}\) (as the proposer selects g at less than the optimal level for coalition members). Noting that \(\frac{{\widetilde{d}}(n)- 1}{n} \simeq 1/2\), dg / dG also declines in n.
 
15
The process was hectic, however. For instance, reapportionment activities were attended by litigation in most states, and state reapportionment plans often were challenged by courts. In addition, many states appealed those court decisions. For instance, in a 1972 Minnesota case, the Supreme Court established that equality of district populations did not extend so far that the lower courts could order radical changes in the size of a state legislature ( Book of the States 1972–1973).
 
16
Notice that malapportionment is an issue for both upper chambers (between the mth Senate district and other Senate districts) and lower chambers (between House districts located in the mth Senate district and other House districts).
 
17
Specifically, the payoff for a representative located within the 1st through mth Senate district is given by \(u(g) - \tau\). On the other hand, the payoff for a representative located within the mth Senate district is given by \(\left[ u(g^{\prime }) - \tau \right] + \left[ u(g^{\prime \prime }) - \tau \right]\) where \(g^{\prime }\) and \(g^{\prime \prime }\) denote the amount of spending for each segment of population.
 
18
During the 1962–1972 period, for instance, the size of the lower chamber increased in 11 states and decreased in 14 states, and the size of the upper chamber increased in 16 states and decreased in 5 states.
 
19
In (5) and (6), \(({\widetilde{d}}(n)-1)\) refers to the number of House coalition districts, and \(n+k\) refers to the number of voters (i.e., population).
 
20
After mergers, each House district has a population of 2.
 
21
The idea behind Proposition 2 can be illustrated with a simple example. Suppose that a state legislature consists of 10 districts: 9 districts with a population of 1 and the 10th district with a population of 3. The total population is then 12. Before redistricting, the 10th district is excluded from the coalition because that district has higher project costs. Thus, the winning coalition consists of five districts (assuming that 50% of a legislature will pass the bill), but less than half of the total population. More specifically, the coalition has a vote share of 0.5 with the population share of 0.42. In case of division, the 10th district is divided into 3 districts with populations of 1. With 12 districts of equal populations, the winning coalition needs to attract one additional district. In the case of mergers, 10 districts are combined into six districts each with a population of 2. The winning coalition now consists of three districts with a total population of 6. Although the number of districts declined because of mergers, the coalition must provide projects to one additional citizen. In both cases, the extant coalition faces higher costs of proposing spending projects owing to the inclusion of additional members.
 
22
To see this, note that \(u(g)=\frac{Y}{n+k}\) both before and after redistricting (because a coalition member’s payoff is 0), implying that if g falls, Y also must fall.
 
23
More generally, the populations of more than \({\widetilde{d}}(n)\) House districts are 1, and other House districts may have populations greater than 1. In addition, more than half of the House districts located in more than \({\widetilde{d}}(m)\) Senate districts have populations of 1.
 
24
In the Baker period, only the redistricting effect occurs because the population disparities were a pre-existing condition.
 
25
Proofs are available upon request to the authors. Note that if mergers of districts follow population growth in those districts, the 1 / n effect could be negative—that is, between \(t=1\) and \(t=3\), total spending increases whereas the number of legislative districts declines. The relationship between seats and spending is then negative. If mergers of districts follow population declines, on the contrary, both total spending and the number of legislative districts fall. Because mergers of districts typically take place when those districts experience outflows of residents, we expect that the relationship between seats and spending is positive in the post-Baker period.
 
26
Alaska and Hawaii’s expenditures per capita are considered outliers, and Nebraska’s legislature is unicameral.
 
27
It would be interesting to see if the theory also holds in the pre-Baker period (i.e., before 1962). We did not examine the pre-Baker period, however, because disaggregated data on state governments before 1962 are rare and available mainly for abnormal years, such as the Great Depression and World War II.
 
28
The Citizen Ideology Index was obtained from the revised 1960–2008 Citizen Ideology Series calculated according to Berry et al. (1998).
 
29
We ignore the potential multicollinearity between \(L_{it}\) and \(U_{it}\) as the correlation between the two is not high (0.19 for the total sample period; 0.21 for the Baker period; 0.19 for the post-Baker period).
 
30
Some states amended their constitutions to alter the sizes of their legislatures, but for reasons encompassing all legislative matters, not just those related to budget allocation (Lee 2015).
 
31
On a similar note, Malhotra (2006) showed that larger government size can lead to an increase in legislative professionalism while legislature size remains fixed.
 
32
The Chow test (\(p \hbox {value} < 0.005\)) indicates a structural break between the Baker and post-Baker periods—that is, the coefficients on Lower and Upper are statistically different between the two periods at the 1% level.
 
33
Data refer to the average of 1978 and 2008.
 
34
It is possible that the insignificance can be explained by the lack of changes in upper-chamber sizes in the post-Baker period (and thus large standard errors).
 
35
Note that \({\widetilde{d}}(m){\widetilde{d}}(k)\le {\widetilde{d}}(n)\) as long as \(m\ge 3\) and \(k\ge 3.\)
 
36
Technically there are many equilibria but all have the same outcomes in terms of project sizes.
 
37
argmax \(\left[ A\log (1+g)-g\right]>0\Leftrightarrow A>1.\)
 
Literature
go back to reference Ansolabehere, S., Gerber, A., & Snyder, J. (2002). Equal votes, equal money: Court-ordered redistricting and public expenditures in the American states. American Political Science Review, 96(4), 767–777.CrossRef Ansolabehere, S., Gerber, A., & Snyder, J. (2002). Equal votes, equal money: Court-ordered redistricting and public expenditures in the American states. American Political Science Review, 96(4), 767–777.CrossRef
go back to reference Ansolabehere, S., Snyder, J. M, Jr., & Ting, M. M. (2003). Bargaining in bicameral legislatures: When and why does malapportionment matter? American Political Science Review, 97(3), 471–481.CrossRef Ansolabehere, S., Snyder, J. M, Jr., & Ting, M. M. (2003). Bargaining in bicameral legislatures: When and why does malapportionment matter? American Political Science Review, 97(3), 471–481.CrossRef
go back to reference Baqir, R. (2002). Districting and government overspending. Journal of Political Economy, 110, 1318–1354.CrossRef Baqir, R. (2002). Districting and government overspending. Journal of Political Economy, 110, 1318–1354.CrossRef
go back to reference Baron, D. P., & Ferejohn, J. A. (1989). Bargaining in legislatures. American Political Science Review, 83(4), 1181–1206.CrossRef Baron, D. P., & Ferejohn, J. A. (1989). Bargaining in legislatures. American Political Science Review, 83(4), 1181–1206.CrossRef
go back to reference Berry, W. D., Ringquist, E. J., Fording, R. C., & Hanson, R. L. (1998). Measuring citizen and government ideology in the American States, 1960–93. American Journal of Political Science, 42(1), 327–348.CrossRef Berry, W. D., Ringquist, E. J., Fording, R. C., & Hanson, R. L. (1998). Measuring citizen and government ideology in the American States, 1960–93. American Journal of Political Science, 42(1), 327–348.CrossRef
go back to reference Bohn, H., & Inman, R. P. (1996). Balanced budget rules and public deficits: Evidence from the U.S. states. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 45, 13–76.CrossRef Bohn, H., & Inman, R. P. (1996). Balanced budget rules and public deficits: Evidence from the U.S. states. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 45, 13–76.CrossRef
go back to reference Bradbury, J. C., & Crain, W. M. (2001). Legislative organization and government spending: cross-country evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 82, 309–325.CrossRef Bradbury, J. C., & Crain, W. M. (2001). Legislative organization and government spending: cross-country evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 82, 309–325.CrossRef
go back to reference Bradbury, J. C., & Stephenson, E. R. (2003). Local government structure and public expenditures. Public Choice, 115, 185–198.CrossRef Bradbury, J. C., & Stephenson, E. R. (2003). Local government structure and public expenditures. Public Choice, 115, 185–198.CrossRef
go back to reference Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.CrossRef Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Chen, J. (2010). The effect of electoral geography on pork barreling in bicameral legislatures. American Journal of Political Science, 54(2), 301–322.CrossRef Chen, J. (2010). The effect of electoral geography on pork barreling in bicameral legislatures. American Journal of Political Science, 54(2), 301–322.CrossRef
go back to reference Chen, J., & Malhotra, N. (2007). The law of k/n: The effect of chamber size on government spending in bicameral legislatures. American Political Science Review, 101(4), 657–676.CrossRef Chen, J., & Malhotra, N. (2007). The law of k/n: The effect of chamber size on government spending in bicameral legislatures. American Political Science Review, 101(4), 657–676.CrossRef
go back to reference Council of State Governments. (1962–2008). The book of the states. Lexington: Council of State Governments. Council of State Governments. (1962–2008). The book of the states. Lexington: Council of State Governments.
go back to reference Crain, W. M. (1999). Districts, diversity, and fiscal biases: Evidence from the American states. The Journal of Law & Economics, 42(2), 675–698.CrossRef Crain, W. M. (1999). Districts, diversity, and fiscal biases: Evidence from the American states. The Journal of Law & Economics, 42(2), 675–698.CrossRef
go back to reference Dearden, J. A., & Husted, T. A. (1993). Do governors get what they want? An alternative examination of the line-item veto. Public Choice, 77, 707–723.CrossRef Dearden, J. A., & Husted, T. A. (1993). Do governors get what they want? An alternative examination of the line-item veto. Public Choice, 77, 707–723.CrossRef
go back to reference Egger, P., & Koethenbuerger, M. (2010). Government spending and legislative organization: Quasi-experimental evidence from Germany. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2(4), 200–212. Egger, P., & Koethenbuerger, M. (2010). Government spending and legislative organization: Quasi-experimental evidence from Germany. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2(4), 200–212.
go back to reference Elis, R., Malhotra, N., & Meredith, M. (2009). Apportionment cycles as natural experiments. Political Analysis, 17(4), 358–376.CrossRef Elis, R., Malhotra, N., & Meredith, M. (2009). Apportionment cycles as natural experiments. Political Analysis, 17(4), 358–376.CrossRef
go back to reference Gilligan, T. W., & Matsusaka, J. G. (1995). Deviations from constituent interests: The role of legislative structure and political parties in the states. Economic Inquiry, 33(3), 383–401.CrossRef Gilligan, T. W., & Matsusaka, J. G. (1995). Deviations from constituent interests: The role of legislative structure and political parties in the states. Economic Inquiry, 33(3), 383–401.CrossRef
go back to reference Gilligan, T. W., & Matsusaka, J. G. (2001). Fiscal policy, legislative size, and political parties: Evidence from state and local governments in the first half of the 20th century. National Tax Journal, 54(1), 57–82.CrossRef Gilligan, T. W., & Matsusaka, J. G. (2001). Fiscal policy, legislative size, and political parties: Evidence from state and local governments in the first half of the 20th century. National Tax Journal, 54(1), 57–82.CrossRef
go back to reference Jordahl, H., & Liang, C.-Y. (2010). Merged municipalities, higehr debt: On free-riding and the common pool problem in politics. Public Choice, 143, 157–172.CrossRef Jordahl, H., & Liang, C.-Y. (2010). Merged municipalities, higehr debt: On free-riding and the common pool problem in politics. Public Choice, 143, 157–172.CrossRef
go back to reference Lee, D. (2015). Supermajority rule and the law of 1/n. Public Choice, 164, 251–274.CrossRef Lee, D. (2015). Supermajority rule and the law of 1/n. Public Choice, 164, 251–274.CrossRef
go back to reference Lee, D. (2016). Supermajority rule and bicameral bargaining. Public Choice, 169, 53–75.CrossRef Lee, D. (2016). Supermajority rule and bicameral bargaining. Public Choice, 169, 53–75.CrossRef
go back to reference MacDonald, L. (2008). The impact of government structure on local public expenditures. Public Choice, 136, 457–473.CrossRef MacDonald, L. (2008). The impact of government structure on local public expenditures. Public Choice, 136, 457–473.CrossRef
go back to reference Malhotra, N. (2006). Government growth and professionalism in U.S. State Legislatures. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 31(4), 563–584.CrossRef Malhotra, N. (2006). Government growth and professionalism in U.S. State Legislatures. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 31(4), 563–584.CrossRef
go back to reference Perotti, R., & Kontopoulos, Y. (2002). Fragmented fiscal policy. Journal of Public Economics, 86, 191–222.CrossRef Perotti, R., & Kontopoulos, Y. (2002). Fragmented fiscal policy. Journal of Public Economics, 86, 191–222.CrossRef
go back to reference Petterson-Lidbom, P. (2012). Does the size of the legislature affect the size of government? Evidence from two natural experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 96, 269–278.CrossRef Petterson-Lidbom, P. (2012). Does the size of the legislature affect the size of government? Evidence from two natural experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 96, 269–278.CrossRef
go back to reference Primo, D. M. (2006). Stop us before we spending again: Institutional constraints on government spending. Economics & Politics, 18, 269–297.CrossRef Primo, D. M. (2006). Stop us before we spending again: Institutional constraints on government spending. Economics & Politics, 18, 269–297.CrossRef
go back to reference Primo, D. M., & Snyder, J. M. (2008). Distributive politics and the law of 1/n. Journal of Politics, 70(2), 477–486.CrossRef Primo, D. M., & Snyder, J. M. (2008). Distributive politics and the law of 1/n. Journal of Politics, 70(2), 477–486.CrossRef
go back to reference Riker, W. H. (1962). The theory of political coalitions. New Haven: Yale University Press. Riker, W. H. (1962). The theory of political coalitions. New Haven: Yale University Press.
go back to reference Schaltegger, C. A., & Feld, L. P. (2009). Do large cabinets favor large governments? Evidence on the fiscal commons problem for Swiss Contons. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 35–47.CrossRef Schaltegger, C. A., & Feld, L. P. (2009). Do large cabinets favor large governments? Evidence on the fiscal commons problem for Swiss Contons. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 35–47.CrossRef
go back to reference Weingast, B., Shepsle, K., & Johnson, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 642–664.CrossRef Weingast, B., Shepsle, K., & Johnson, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 642–664.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Court-ordered redistricting and the law of 1/n
Authors
Dongwon Lee
Sangwon Park
Publication date
04-07-2018
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 3-4/2018
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0579-4

Other articles of this Issue 3-4/2018

Public Choice 3-4/2018 Go to the issue