Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Review of Accounting Studies 4/2020

25-08-2020

Does it pay to ‘Be Like Mike’? Aspiratonal peer firms and relative performance evaluation

Authors: Ryan T. Ball, Jonathan Bonham, Thomas Hemmer

Published in: Review of Accounting Studies | Issue 4/2020

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We examine the manner and extent to which firms evaluate performance relative to aspirational peer firms. Guided by the predictions of an agency model, we find that CEO compensation increases in the correlation between own and aspirational peer firm performances. In addition, we define and test conditions where aggregate peer performance, which has been the primary focus of prior relative performance evaluation studies of competitive peers, is expected to have an association with CEO compensation. These conditions are supported by our empirical results. Finally, we document that our results are more pronounced when the firm-peer relationship is one-way and the peer firm is in a different industry and therefore is more aspirational.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
Key empirical papers on the relation between CEO compensation and aggregate performance of a competitive peer group are Antle and Smith (1986), Jensen and Murphy (1990), Barro and Barro (1990) Aggarwal and Samwick (1999b), Garvey and Milbourn (2003), and Albuquerque (2009), among others.
 
2
The lack of strong empirical support for the predictions from standard RPE theory has long troubled researchers, and recent studies continue to cast doubt on the framework’s sufficiency. For example, Jenter and Kanaan (2015) provide evidence that firms do not filter out common shocks when making firing decisions. In addition, Ma et al. (2017) provide empirical evidence inconsistent with firms optimally selecting peers solely on the exogenous covariance, which is predicted by standard RPE theory. They suggest that firms’ seemingly suboptimal choices result from boards not “getting it right.” However, the results of our study suggest that boards may still get it right, while the standard RPE model with competitive peers is not sufficient to capture the multi-dimensional nature of RPE.
 
3
The phrase “Be Like Mike” in the title of our study refers to a Gatorade commercial that originally aired in 1992 and again in 2015. In the commercial, footage of Michael Jordan playing basketball, juxtaposed with video of young kids imitating his moves, was used as a backdrop to the lyrics of a song: “Sometimes I dream that he is me. / You’ve got to see that’s how I dream to be. / I dream I move, I dream I groove. / Like Mike. If I could be like Mike.” The commercial embodies the spirit of our study and the results that we document.
 
4
To focus on the key assumptions and resulting empirical predictions of our model, we relegate some discussion and detailed derivations to Appendix A of this paper or refer the reader to Hemmer (2017) wherever appropriate.
 
5
A drawback of relying on the simple binomial version of Hemmer (2017) to provide intuition here is that \(p_{\tau }{<}\frac {1}{1+a}\) is required for peers being aspirational as here defined. This is, however, entirely a feature of the discrete binomial version of the model and does not carry over to the continuous Brownian version, from which the actual predictions are derived, obtained in the limit when the length of subperiods approach zero.
 
6
This is a fundamental divergence from the opposite assumption underlying the RPE literature. For a firm’s exposure to a common shock to be independent of an agent’s operational choices, the model structure has to be one of “effort-plus-noise” as, for example, in the standard LEN representation that much of the RPE literature relies on. Unfortunately, “effort-plus-noise” models do not lend themselves to the analysis of optimal contracts. (See the introduction of Jewitt (1988) for an excellent discussion of why.) Rather, the LEN RPE contract is the “best” contract available among the class of contracts that are linear in aggregate own and peer performance, and the key “common-shock filtering” result obtained from the LEN model results from restricting the analysis to focus on this exogenously specified, non-optimal contractual form. In fact, without the exogenous restriction to linear contracts, the so-called Mirrlees non-existence result applies, and all firms can attain approximate first-best solutions without the use of RPE. By contrast, the results we are testing in this paper are obtained as properties of optimal RPE contracts derived in an economic environment where optimal RPE contracts actually exist.
 
7
While the simple binomial structure we rely on is too restrictive to allow for the sign of γp to differ across peers, it is straightforward to generate parameter values in which the magnitude of γp is quite different from the perspective of the focal versus the peer firm. Moreover, in the full Brownian model from Hemmer (2017) that emerges as the limiting case of the discrete multinomial models, γp can differ across peers in both sign and magnitude for appropriately selected parameter values.
 
8
Because there can be multiple such equilibria, we cannot speak to what the agents’ actions look like in equilibrium, nor is this the focus of our study. Rather, we focus on identifying the equilibrium use of peer performance in the contracts that implement a given set of equilibrium actions.
 
9
This is significant because the empirical RPE literature that relies on the restriction that the exposure to economy-wide shocks is independent of the operational decisions firms make has largely been unable to establish βπ being different from zero. Hemmer (2017) demonstrates that, when the exposure to the common risk is not independent of managerial decisions (as it cannot be in this setting for the reason discussed above), it is not optimal to simply filter out the common component in the optimal RPE contract.
 
10
Many of the components of total compensation are awarded based on contemporaneous performance, and these components conform most closely to the constructs in our model. If long-term incentive payouts depend on actions taken in prior years, this component introduces noise to our measure of total compensation because actions only affect contemporaneous firm performance (based on the structure of our model). However, such timing-driven measurement error in our total compensation proxy should only affect the dependent variable, rather than the independent variables, and therefore should not bias our coefficient estimates.
 
11
For example, consider the manager of a passive market index fund that is focused on tracking the underlying market index. He or she is provided incentives to take actions (e.g., periodically rebalancing the portfolio to accommodate changes in the index) that increase the correlation of the fund’s performance with that of the market index, which primarily represents the systematic component. By contrast, a hedge fund manager may focus on emulating an aspirational peer fund manager in an effort to increase abnormal, risk-adjusted return performance, which primarily represents an idiosyncratic component. Thus the informativeness of distinguishing between these two return components crucially hinges on the ability to identify the specific nature of the strategies of the aspirational peer that the firms is attempting to emulate. While interesting, it is outside the scope of our study, so again we leave it for future research.
 
12
All test statistics are based on standard errors clustered by firm.
 
13
Similar results are obtained for all specifications using value-weighted peer performance measures instead of equal-weighted measures. Specifically, Tables 3 and 4 are replicated using value-weighted performance measures. Results are reported in Tables OA.1 and OA.2, respectively, of the online appendix.
 
14
As discussed in Section 2.2, a two-way relation would arise in the framework of Hemmer (2017) if, for example, firms find it optimal to adopt each others’ best practices or learn from each others’ successes. In addition, a one-way relation could arise if the focal firm benefits from imitating the peer’s technology or business model, whereas either (i) the peer is indifferent between imitating or differentiating from the focal firm, or (ii) the peer prefers to innovate to distinguish itself from the focal firm but declines to specify non-aspirational peers for the reasons discussed in Section 2.2. By contrast, traditional RPE models preclude one-way relations by prescribing that firms treat each other symmetrically based on the sign of their covariance when filtering common shocks from compensation.
 
15
Representative RPE studies based on industry peer groups include those by Antle and Smith (1986), Gibbons and Murphy (1990), Jensen and Murphy (1990), Barro and Barro (1990), Janakiraman et al. (1992), Aggarwal and Samwick (1999a, b), Garvey and Milbourn (2006), Rajgopal et al. (2006), and Albuquerque (2009; 2014).
 
16
The variable perfcorrjt,k is defined as the performance correlation between firm j and its peer firm k in fiscal year t. We scale by the total number of j’s peer firms in t (Njt) to increase comparability across firm-year observations.
 
Literature
go back to reference Aggarwal, R., & Samwick, A. (1999a). Executive compensation, strategic competition, and relative performance evaluation: Theory and evidence. Journal of Political Economy, 54(6), 1999–2043. Aggarwal, R., & Samwick, A. (1999a). Executive compensation, strategic competition, and relative performance evaluation: Theory and evidence. Journal of Political Economy, 54(6), 1999–2043.
go back to reference Aggarwal, R., & Samwick, A. (1999b). The other side of the trade-off: The impact of risk on executive compensation. Journal of Political Economy, 107(1), 65–105.CrossRef Aggarwal, R., & Samwick, A. (1999b). The other side of the trade-off: The impact of risk on executive compensation. Journal of Political Economy, 107(1), 65–105.CrossRef
go back to reference Albuquerque, A. (2009). Peer firms in relative performance evaluation. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 48(1), 69–89.CrossRef Albuquerque, A. (2009). Peer firms in relative performance evaluation. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 48(1), 69–89.CrossRef
go back to reference Albuquerque, A. (2014). Do growth-option firms use less relative performance evaluation? The Accounting Review, 89(1), 27–60.CrossRef Albuquerque, A. (2014). Do growth-option firms use less relative performance evaluation? The Accounting Review, 89(1), 27–60.CrossRef
go back to reference Antle, R., & Smith, A. (1986). An empirical evaluation of the relative performance evaluation of corporate executives. Journal of Accounting Research, 24 (1), 1–39.CrossRef Antle, R., & Smith, A. (1986). An empirical evaluation of the relative performance evaluation of corporate executives. Journal of Accounting Research, 24 (1), 1–39.CrossRef
go back to reference Ball, R.T., & Gallo, L. (2020). A mixed data sampling approach to accounting research. Working paper, University of Michigan. Ball, R.T., & Gallo, L. (2020). A mixed data sampling approach to accounting research. Working paper, University of Michigan.
go back to reference Ball, R.T., Gallo, L., & Ghysels, E. (2019). Tilting the evidence: The role of firm-level earnings attributes in the relation between aggregated earnings and gross domestic product. Review of Accounting Studies, 24(2), 570–592.CrossRef Ball, R.T., Gallo, L., & Ghysels, E. (2019). Tilting the evidence: The role of firm-level earnings attributes in the relation between aggregated earnings and gross domestic product. Review of Accounting Studies, 24(2), 570–592.CrossRef
go back to reference Barro, J., & Barro, R. (1990). Pay, performance and turnover of bank CEOs. Journal of Labor Economics, 8(4), 448–481.CrossRef Barro, J., & Barro, R. (1990). Pay, performance and turnover of bank CEOs. Journal of Labor Economics, 8(4), 448–481.CrossRef
go back to reference Bearden, W., & Etzel, M. (1982). Reference group influence on product and brand purchase decisions. Journal of Consumer Research, 9(2), 183–194.CrossRef Bearden, W., & Etzel, M. (1982). Reference group influence on product and brand purchase decisions. Journal of Consumer Research, 9(2), 183–194.CrossRef
go back to reference Bertrand, M., & Mullainathan, S. (2001). Are CEOs rewarded for luck? The ones without principals are. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(3), 901–932.CrossRef Bertrand, M., & Mullainathan, S. (2001). Are CEOs rewarded for luck? The ones without principals are. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(3), 901–932.CrossRef
go back to reference Core, J., & Guay, W. (1999). The use of equity grants to manage optimal equity incentive. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 28(2), 151–184.CrossRef Core, J., & Guay, W. (1999). The use of equity grants to manage optimal equity incentive. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 28(2), 151–184.CrossRef
go back to reference Core, J., Holthausen, R., & Larcker, D. (1999). Corporate governance, chief executive officer compensation, and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 51(3), 371–406.CrossRef Core, J., Holthausen, R., & Larcker, D. (1999). Corporate governance, chief executive officer compensation, and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 51(3), 371–406.CrossRef
go back to reference Dikolli, S., Hofmann, C., & Pfeiffer, T. (2013). Relative performance evaluation and peer performance summarization errors. Review of Accounting Studies, 18(1), 34–85.CrossRef Dikolli, S., Hofmann, C., & Pfeiffer, T. (2013). Relative performance evaluation and peer performance summarization errors. Review of Accounting Studies, 18(1), 34–85.CrossRef
go back to reference Garvey, G., & Milbourn, T. (2003). Incentive compensation when executives can hedge the market: Evidence of relative performance evaluation in the cross section. Journal of Finance, 58(4), 1157–1582.CrossRef Garvey, G., & Milbourn, T. (2003). Incentive compensation when executives can hedge the market: Evidence of relative performance evaluation in the cross section. Journal of Finance, 58(4), 1157–1582.CrossRef
go back to reference Garvey, G., & Milbourn, T. (2006). Asymmetric benchmarking in compensation: Executives are rewarded for good luck but not penalized for bad. Journal of Financial Economics, 82(1), 197–225.CrossRef Garvey, G., & Milbourn, T. (2006). Asymmetric benchmarking in compensation: Executives are rewarded for good luck but not penalized for bad. Journal of Financial Economics, 82(1), 197–225.CrossRef
go back to reference Ghysels, E., Santa-Clara, P., & Valkanov, R. (2005). There is a risk-return trade-off after all. Journal of Financial Economics, 76(3), 509–548.CrossRef Ghysels, E., Santa-Clara, P., & Valkanov, R. (2005). There is a risk-return trade-off after all. Journal of Financial Economics, 76(3), 509–548.CrossRef
go back to reference Gibbons, R., & Murphy, K. (1990). Relative performance evaluation for chief executive officers. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 43, 30S–51S.CrossRef Gibbons, R., & Murphy, K. (1990). Relative performance evaluation for chief executive officers. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 43, 30S–51S.CrossRef
go back to reference Hemmer, T. (2017). Optimal dynamic relative performance evaluation. Working paper Rice University. Hemmer, T. (2017). Optimal dynamic relative performance evaluation. Working paper Rice University.
go back to reference Holmström, B. (1982). Moral hazard in teams. Bell Journal of Economics, 13(2), 324–340.CrossRef Holmström, B. (1982). Moral hazard in teams. Bell Journal of Economics, 13(2), 324–340.CrossRef
go back to reference Holmström, B., & Milgrom, P. (1987). Aggregation and linearity in the provision of intertemporal incentives. Econometrica, 55(2), 303–328.CrossRef Holmström, B., & Milgrom, P. (1987). Aggregation and linearity in the provision of intertemporal incentives. Econometrica, 55(2), 303–328.CrossRef
go back to reference Janakiraman, S., Lambert, R., & Larcker, D. (1992). An empirical investigation of the relative performance evaluation hypothesis. Journal of Accounting Research, 30(1), 53–69.CrossRef Janakiraman, S., Lambert, R., & Larcker, D. (1992). An empirical investigation of the relative performance evaluation hypothesis. Journal of Accounting Research, 30(1), 53–69.CrossRef
go back to reference Jayaraman, S., Milbourn, T., & Seo, H. (2018). Product market peers and relative performance evaluation. Working paper University of Rochester Washington University in St. Louis, and University of Amsterdam. Jayaraman, S., Milbourn, T., & Seo, H. (2018). Product market peers and relative performance evaluation. Working paper University of Rochester Washington University in St. Louis, and University of Amsterdam.
go back to reference Jensen, M., & Murphy, K. (1990). Performance pay and top-management incentives. Journal of Political Economy, 98(2), 225–264.CrossRef Jensen, M., & Murphy, K. (1990). Performance pay and top-management incentives. Journal of Political Economy, 98(2), 225–264.CrossRef
go back to reference Jenter, D., & Kanaan, F. (2015). CEO turnover and relative performance evaluation. Journal of Finance, 70(5), 2155–2183.CrossRef Jenter, D., & Kanaan, F. (2015). CEO turnover and relative performance evaluation. Journal of Finance, 70(5), 2155–2183.CrossRef
go back to reference Jewitt, I. (1988). Justifying the first-order approach to principal-agent problems. Econometrica, 56(5), 1177–1190.CrossRef Jewitt, I. (1988). Justifying the first-order approach to principal-agent problems. Econometrica, 56(5), 1177–1190.CrossRef
go back to reference Ma, P., Shin, J. E., & Wang, C. (2017). Relative performance benchmarks: Do boards get it right? Working paper. University of Minnesota University of Toronto, and Harvard University. Ma, P., Shin, J. E., & Wang, C. (2017). Relative performance benchmarks: Do boards get it right? Working paper. University of Minnesota University of Toronto, and Harvard University.
go back to reference Merton, R., & Rossi, A. (1968). Contributions to the theory of reference group behavior. In Merton, R. (Eds.), Social Theory and Social Structure (pp. 279–334). New York: The Free Press. Merton, R., & Rossi, A. (1968). Contributions to the theory of reference group behavior. In Merton, R. (Eds.), Social Theory and Social Structure (pp. 279–334). New York: The Free Press.
go back to reference Rajgopal, S., Shevlin, T., & Zamora, V. (2006). CEOs outside employment opportunities and the lack of relative performance evaluation in compensation contracts. Journal of Finance, 61(4), 1813–1844.CrossRef Rajgopal, S., Shevlin, T., & Zamora, V. (2006). CEOs outside employment opportunities and the lack of relative performance evaluation in compensation contracts. Journal of Finance, 61(4), 1813–1844.CrossRef
go back to reference Rosen, S. (1982). Authority, control, and the distribution of earnings. Bell Journal of Economics, 13(2), 311–323.CrossRef Rosen, S. (1982). Authority, control, and the distribution of earnings. Bell Journal of Economics, 13(2), 311–323.CrossRef
go back to reference Smith Jr., C., & Watts, R. (1992). The investment opportunity set and corporate financing, dividend and compensation policies. Journal of Financial Economics, 32(3), 263–292.CrossRef Smith Jr., C., & Watts, R. (1992). The investment opportunity set and corporate financing, dividend and compensation policies. Journal of Financial Economics, 32(3), 263–292.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Does it pay to ‘Be Like Mike’? Aspiratonal peer firms and relative performance evaluation
Authors
Ryan T. Ball
Jonathan Bonham
Thomas Hemmer
Publication date
25-08-2020
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Review of Accounting Studies / Issue 4/2020
Print ISSN: 1380-6653
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7136
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-020-09540-1

Other articles of this Issue 4/2020

Review of Accounting Studies 4/2020 Go to the issue