Skip to main content
Top

2015 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

4. Dynamic Efficiency Measurement

Author : Finn R. Førsund

Published in: Benchmarking for Performance Evaluation

Publisher: Springer India

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

A philosophical problem for studies of inefficiency of firms is how to rationalise inefficiency. Since economics do not have any theory for inefficiency, explaining the results of efficiency analyses is notoriously more difficult than carrying out the estimations. The literature points to measures of inputs and management as not including quality dimensions as a reason for measured efficiency differences, indicating that more work needs to be done on data collection. Strategic behaviour in game situations between owners and management and between management and labour may also show up as inefficiencies. Another reason is technology differences. The frontier production function is the key to information on best practice technology. Estimation of efficiency is usually done for units observed during the same time period; thus, in this respect, the measures are static. Interpretations of dynamic efficiency measurement are offered. The vintage model of substitutability between inputs including capital before investment, but no substitution possibilities after investment, and ex post production possibilities characterised by fixed input coefficients, can rationalise inefficiency due to technology differences. Key elements in understanding structural change are the entering of capacity embodying new technology and exiting of capacity no longer able to yield positive quasi-rent. Three crucial production function concepts are identified as follows: the ex ante micro-unit production function as relevant when investing in new capacity, the ex post micro-production function, and the short-run industry production function giving the production possibilities at the industry level. Productivity measurement, taking these types of production functions into consideration, leads to different interpretations of productivity change than traditional approaches not being clear about which production function concept is used.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
Cost of adjustment is introduced in Sengupta (1995, 1996). However, it is not so easy to understand how the dynamics of his analyses actually work, cf. comments in Nemoto and Goto (2003, p. 192).
 
2
The basis of the modelling except the specific adaptation of the DEA model has much in common with the approach in Rubin (1973).
 
3
If deviation form an optimal path is called waste, confer Stigler (1976, p. 576): “…waste is not a useful economic concept. Waste is error within the framework of modern economic analysis, and it will not become a useful concept until we have a theory of error.”
 
4
As expressed in Rothschild (1971, p. 605), “Much of the current interest in cost of adjustment functions stems from their ability to provide a rigorous theoretical justification for the use of distributed lags in econometric studies of investment behavior.”
 
5
As to the Penrose effect of the importance of constrained management resources, Slater (1980, p. 521) remarks that there is no recognition in economists’ models of the role of the management; management has no role to play which bears upon the firm’s performance.
 
6
In practice merit order is based on costs, therefore the theoretical merit order based on quasi-rent will only be relevant if input prices are equal.
 
7
In Førsund and Hjalmarsson (1979), introducing this measure, it was called the gross scale efficiency.
 
Literature
go back to reference Afriat, S. 1972. Efficiency estimation of production functions. International Economic Review 13(3): 568–598.CrossRef Afriat, S. 1972. Efficiency estimation of production functions. International Economic Review 13(3): 568–598.CrossRef
go back to reference Aigner, D.J., and S.F. Chu. 1968. On estimating the industry production function. American Economic Review 58(4): 826–839. Aigner, D.J., and S.F. Chu. 1968. On estimating the industry production function. American Economic Review 58(4): 826–839.
go back to reference Battese, G., and P.D.S. Rao. 2002. Technology gap, efficiency, and a stochastic metafrontier function. International Journal of Business and Economics 1(2): 87–93. Battese, G., and P.D.S. Rao. 2002. Technology gap, efficiency, and a stochastic metafrontier function. International Journal of Business and Economics 1(2): 87–93.
go back to reference Battese, G., P.D.S. Rao, and C.J. O’Donnell. 2004. A metafrontier production function for estimation of technical efficiencies and technology gaps for firms operating under different technologies. Journal of Productivity Analysis 21: 91–103.CrossRef Battese, G., P.D.S. Rao, and C.J. O’Donnell. 2004. A metafrontier production function for estimation of technical efficiencies and technology gaps for firms operating under different technologies. Journal of Productivity Analysis 21: 91–103.CrossRef
go back to reference Baumol, W.J. 1962. On the theory of expansion of the firm. The American Economic Review 52(5): 1078–1087. Baumol, W.J. 1962. On the theory of expansion of the firm. The American Economic Review 52(5): 1078–1087.
go back to reference Belifante, A. 1978. The identification of technical change in the electricity generating industry. In Production economics: a dual approach to theory and applications, ed. M. Fuss and D. McFadden, vol. 2, Chap. IV.3, pp. 149–186. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Belifante, A. 1978. The identification of technical change in the electricity generating industry. In Production economics: a dual approach to theory and applications, ed. M. Fuss and D. McFadden, vol. 2, Chap. IV.3, pp. 149–186. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
go back to reference Berg, S.A., F.R. Førsund, and E. Jansen. 1992. Malmquist indices of productivity growth during the deregulation of Norwegian banking, 1980–1989. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 94: S211–S228.CrossRef Berg, S.A., F.R. Førsund, and E. Jansen. 1992. Malmquist indices of productivity growth during the deregulation of Norwegian banking, 1980–1989. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 94: S211–S228.CrossRef
go back to reference Bogetoft, P., and J.L. Hougaard. 2003. Rational inefficiencies. Journal of Productivity Analysis 20: 243–271.CrossRef Bogetoft, P., and J.L. Hougaard. 2003. Rational inefficiencies. Journal of Productivity Analysis 20: 243–271.CrossRef
go back to reference Bye, T., and E. Holmøy. 2010. Removing policy based comparative advantage for energy intensive production: necessary adjustments of the real exchange rate and industry structure. The Energy Journal 31(1): 177–198.CrossRef Bye, T., and E. Holmøy. 2010. Removing policy based comparative advantage for energy intensive production: necessary adjustments of the real exchange rate and industry structure. The Energy Journal 31(1): 177–198.CrossRef
go back to reference Caves, D.W., L.R. Christensen, and W.E. Diewert. 1982. The economic theory of index numbers and the measurement of input, output, and productivity. Econometrica 50: 1393–1414.CrossRef Caves, D.W., L.R. Christensen, and W.E. Diewert. 1982. The economic theory of index numbers and the measurement of input, output, and productivity. Econometrica 50: 1393–1414.CrossRef
go back to reference Charnes, A., W.W. Cooper, and E. Rhodes. 1978. Measuring the efficiency of decision making units. European Journal of Operational Research 2: 429–444.CrossRef Charnes, A., W.W. Cooper, and E. Rhodes. 1978. Measuring the efficiency of decision making units. European Journal of Operational Research 2: 429–444.CrossRef
go back to reference Charnes, A., W.W. Cooper, and E. Rhodes. 1981. Evaluating program and managerial efficiency: an application of data envelopment analysis to program follow through. Management Science 27(6): 668–697.CrossRef Charnes, A., W.W. Cooper, and E. Rhodes. 1981. Evaluating program and managerial efficiency: an application of data envelopment analysis to program follow through. Management Science 27(6): 668–697.CrossRef
go back to reference Eide, E. 1976. Do new factories embody potential best practice technology? Empirical Economics 1(2): 119–127.CrossRef Eide, E. 1976. Do new factories embody potential best practice technology? Empirical Economics 1(2): 119–127.CrossRef
go back to reference Eisner, R., and R. Strotz. 1963. Determinants of business investment. In Impacts of monetary policy. Part I. Commission on Money and Credit, pp. 59–233. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall. Eisner, R., and R. Strotz. 1963. Determinants of business investment. In Impacts of monetary policy. Part I. Commission on Money and Credit, pp. 59–233. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.
go back to reference Färe, R., and D. Primont. 1995. Multi-output production and duality: theory and applications. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Färe, R., and D. Primont. 1995. Multi-output production and duality: theory and applications. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
go back to reference Färe, R., and S. Grosskopf. 1996. Intertemporal production frontiers: with dynamic DEA. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Färe, R., and S. Grosskopf. 1996. Intertemporal production frontiers: with dynamic DEA. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
go back to reference Färe, R., S. Grosskopf, B. Lindgren, and P. Roos. 1994. Productivity developments in Swedish hospitals: a Malmquist output index approach. In Data envelopment analysis: theory, methodology, and applications, ed. A. Charnes, W.W. Cooper, A.Y. Lewin, and L.M. Seiford, 253–272. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.CrossRef Färe, R., S. Grosskopf, B. Lindgren, and P. Roos. 1994. Productivity developments in Swedish hospitals: a Malmquist output index approach. In Data envelopment analysis: theory, methodology, and applications, ed. A. Charnes, W.W. Cooper, A.Y. Lewin, and L.M. Seiford, 253–272. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.CrossRef
go back to reference Farrell, M.J. 1957. The measurement of productive efficiency. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series A (General) 120(III):253–281. Farrell, M.J. 1957. The measurement of productive efficiency. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series A (General) 120(III):253–281.
go back to reference Fuss, M. 1978. Factor substitution in electricity generation: a test of the putty-clay hypothesis. In Production economics: a dual approach to theory and applications, ed. Melvin Fuss and Daniel McFadden, vol. 2, Chap. IV.4, pp. 187–213. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Fuss, M. 1978. Factor substitution in electricity generation: a test of the putty-clay hypothesis. In Production economics: a dual approach to theory and applications, ed. Melvin Fuss and Daniel McFadden, vol. 2, Chap. IV.4, pp. 187–213. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
go back to reference Førsund, F.R., and L. Hjalmarsson. 1974. On the measurement of productive efficiency. Swedish Journal of Economics 76(2): 141–154.CrossRef Førsund, F.R., and L. Hjalmarsson. 1974. On the measurement of productive efficiency. Swedish Journal of Economics 76(2): 141–154.CrossRef
go back to reference Førsund, F.R., and L. Hjalmarsson. 1979. Generalised Farrell measures of efficiency: an application to milk processing in Swedish dairy plants. Economic Journal 89: 294–315.CrossRef Førsund, F.R., and L. Hjalmarsson. 1979. Generalised Farrell measures of efficiency: an application to milk processing in Swedish dairy plants. Economic Journal 89: 294–315.CrossRef
go back to reference Førsund, F.R., and L. Hjalmarsson. 1987. Analyses of industrial structure: a putty-clay approach. Industrial Institute for Economic and Social Research. Stockholm: Almqvist and Wicksell International. Førsund, F.R., and L. Hjalmarsson. 1987. Analyses of industrial structure: a putty-clay approach. Industrial Institute for Economic and Social Research. Stockholm: Almqvist and Wicksell International.
go back to reference Førsund, F.R., and E.S. Jansen. 1983. Technical progress and structural change in the Norwegian aluminium industry. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 85: 113–126.CrossRef Førsund, F.R., and E.S. Jansen. 1983. Technical progress and structural change in the Norwegian aluminium industry. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 85: 113–126.CrossRef
go back to reference Førsund, F.R., L. Hjalmarsson, and T. Summa. 1996. The interplay between micro-frontier and sectoral short-run production functions. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 98(3): 365–386.CrossRef Førsund, F.R., L. Hjalmarsson, and T. Summa. 1996. The interplay between micro-frontier and sectoral short-run production functions. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 98(3): 365–386.CrossRef
go back to reference Gould, J.P. 1968. Adjustment costs in the theory of investment of the firm. Review of Economic Studies 35(1): 47–55.CrossRef Gould, J.P. 1968. Adjustment costs in the theory of investment of the firm. Review of Economic Studies 35(1): 47–55.CrossRef
go back to reference Gini, C. 1931. On the circular test of index numbers. Metron (International Review of Statistics) 9(2): 3–24. Gini, C. 1931. On the circular test of index numbers. Metron (International Review of Statistics) 9(2): 3–24.
go back to reference Grifell-Tatjé, E., and C.A.K. Lovell. 1995. A note on the Malmquist productivity index. Economics Letters 47(2): 169–175.CrossRef Grifell-Tatjé, E., and C.A.K. Lovell. 1995. A note on the Malmquist productivity index. Economics Letters 47(2): 169–175.CrossRef
go back to reference Haavelmo, T. 1960. A Study in the Theory of Investment. Chicago: Chicago University Press. Haavelmo, T. 1960. A Study in the Theory of Investment. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
go back to reference Hamermesh, D.S., and G.A. Pfann. 1996. Adjustment costs in factor demand. Journal of Economic Literature 34(September): 1264–1292. Hamermesh, D.S., and G.A. Pfann. 1996. Adjustment costs in factor demand. Journal of Economic Literature 34(September): 1264–1292.
go back to reference Haskel, J., and A. Sanchis. 1995. Privatisation and X-inefficiency: a bargaining approach. The Journal of Industrial Economics 43(3): 301–321.CrossRef Haskel, J., and A. Sanchis. 1995. Privatisation and X-inefficiency: a bargaining approach. The Journal of Industrial Economics 43(3): 301–321.CrossRef
go back to reference Haskel, J., and A. Sanchis. 2000. A bargaining model of Farrell inefficiency. International Journal of Industrial Organization 18: 5–556.CrossRef Haskel, J., and A. Sanchis. 2000. A bargaining model of Farrell inefficiency. International Journal of Industrial Organization 18: 5–556.CrossRef
go back to reference Hayami, Y., and V.W. Ruttan. 1970. Agricultural productivity differences among countries. American Economic Review 60(5): 895–911. Hayami, Y., and V.W. Ruttan. 1970. Agricultural productivity differences among countries. American Economic Review 60(5): 895–911.
go back to reference Heckscher, E. 1918. Svenska produktionsproblem (Swedish production problems). Stockholm: Bonniers. Heckscher, E. 1918. Svenska produktionsproblem (Swedish production problems). Stockholm: Bonniers.
go back to reference Johansen, L. 1972. Production functions. An integration of micro and macro, short run and long run aspects. Amsterdam-London: North-Holland. Johansen, L. 1972. Production functions. An integration of micro and macro, short run and long run aspects. Amsterdam-London: North-Holland.
go back to reference Johansen, L., and A. Sørsveen. 1967. Notes on the measurement of real capital in relation to economic planning models. Review of Income and Wealth, Series 13: 175–197.CrossRef Johansen, L., and A. Sørsveen. 1967. Notes on the measurement of real capital in relation to economic planning models. Review of Income and Wealth, Series 13: 175–197.CrossRef
go back to reference Jorgenson, D.W. 1966. The embodiment hypothesis. Journal of Political Economy 74(1): 1–17.CrossRef Jorgenson, D.W. 1966. The embodiment hypothesis. Journal of Political Economy 74(1): 1–17.CrossRef
go back to reference Leibenstein, H. 1966. Allocative efficiency vs. “X-efficiency”. American Economic Review 56(3): 392–415. Leibenstein, H. 1966. Allocative efficiency vs. “X-efficiency”. American Economic Review 56(3): 392–415.
go back to reference Lewin, A.Y., and J.W. Minton. 1986. Determining organizational effectiveness: another look, and an agenda for research. Management Science 32(5): 514–538. Lewin, A.Y., and J.W. Minton. 1986. Determining organizational effectiveness: another look, and an agenda for research. Management Science 32(5): 514–538.
go back to reference Lucas, R.E. 1967. Adjustment costs and the theory of supply. The Journal of Political Economy 75(4): 321–334.CrossRef Lucas, R.E. 1967. Adjustment costs and the theory of supply. The Journal of Political Economy 75(4): 321–334.CrossRef
go back to reference Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of economics, 8th edn. (1966). London-Melbourne-Toronto: Macmillan. Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of economics, 8th edn. (1966). London-Melbourne-Toronto: Macmillan.
go back to reference Maywald, K. 1957. The best and the average in productivity studies and in long-term forecasting. The Productivity Measurement Review 9: 37–49. Maywald, K. 1957. The best and the average in productivity studies and in long-term forecasting. The Productivity Measurement Review 9: 37–49.
go back to reference Mitchell, W.C. 1937. The social sciences and national planning. In Planned society. Yesterday today tomorrow, ed. F. McKenzie. New York: Prentice Hall. Mitchell, W.C. 1937. The social sciences and national planning. In Planned society. Yesterday today tomorrow, ed. F. McKenzie. New York: Prentice Hall.
go back to reference Nemoto, J., and M. Goto. 1999. Dynamic data envelopment analysis: modeling intertemporal behavior of a firm in the presence of productive inefficiencies. Economics Letters 64: 51–56.CrossRef Nemoto, J., and M. Goto. 1999. Dynamic data envelopment analysis: modeling intertemporal behavior of a firm in the presence of productive inefficiencies. Economics Letters 64: 51–56.CrossRef
go back to reference Nemoto, J., and M. Goto. 2003. Measurement of dynamic efficiency in production: an application of data envelopment analysis to Japanese electric utilities. Journal of Productivity Analysis 19: 191–210.CrossRef Nemoto, J., and M. Goto. 2003. Measurement of dynamic efficiency in production: an application of data envelopment analysis to Japanese electric utilities. Journal of Productivity Analysis 19: 191–210.CrossRef
go back to reference O’Donnell, C.J., G. Battese, and P.D.S. Rao. 2008. Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios. Empirical Economics 34: 231–255.CrossRef O’Donnell, C.J., G. Battese, and P.D.S. Rao. 2008. Metafrontier frameworks for the study of firm-level efficiencies and technology ratios. Empirical Economics 34: 231–255.CrossRef
go back to reference Penrose, E. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. New York: Oxford University Press. Penrose, E. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Phelps, E.S. 1963. Substitution, fixed proportions, growth and distribution. International Economic Review 4: 265–288.CrossRef Phelps, E.S. 1963. Substitution, fixed proportions, growth and distribution. International Economic Review 4: 265–288.CrossRef
go back to reference Rothschild, M. 1971. On the cost of adjustment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 85(4): 605–622.CrossRef Rothschild, M. 1971. On the cost of adjustment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 85(4): 605–622.CrossRef
go back to reference Rubin, P.H. 1973. The expansion of firms. Journal of Political Economy 81(4): 936–949.CrossRef Rubin, P.H. 1973. The expansion of firms. Journal of Political Economy 81(4): 936–949.CrossRef
go back to reference Salter, W.E.G. 1960. Productivity and technical change. London: Cambridge University Press. Salter, W.E.G. 1960. Productivity and technical change. London: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Sengupta, J.K. 1995. Dynamics of data envelopment analysis. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publisher.CrossRef Sengupta, J.K. 1995. Dynamics of data envelopment analysis. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publisher.CrossRef
go back to reference Sengupta, J.K. 1996. Dynamic data envelopment analysis. International Journal of Systems Science 27(3): 277–284.CrossRef Sengupta, J.K. 1996. Dynamic data envelopment analysis. International Journal of Systems Science 27(3): 277–284.CrossRef
go back to reference Shen, T.Y. 1970. Economies of scale, Penrose effect, growth of plants, and their size distribution. The Journal of Political Economy 78(4): 702–716.CrossRef Shen, T.Y. 1970. Economies of scale, Penrose effect, growth of plants, and their size distribution. The Journal of Political Economy 78(4): 702–716.CrossRef
go back to reference Slater, M. 1980. The managerial limitations to the growth of firms. The Economic Journal 90(September): 520–528.CrossRef Slater, M. 1980. The managerial limitations to the growth of firms. The Economic Journal 90(September): 520–528.CrossRef
go back to reference Stigler, G.J. 1976. The Xistence of X-efficiency. American Economic Review 66(1): 213–216. Stigler, G.J. 1976. The Xistence of X-efficiency. American Economic Review 66(1): 213–216.
go back to reference Tan, D., and J.T. Mahoney. 2005. Examining the Penrose effect in an international business context: the dynamics of Japanese firm growth in US industries. Managerial and Decision Economics 26: 113–127.CrossRef Tan, D., and J.T. Mahoney. 2005. Examining the Penrose effect in an international business context: the dynamics of Japanese firm growth in US industries. Managerial and Decision Economics 26: 113–127.CrossRef
go back to reference Taylor, F.W. 1911. The principles of scientific management. Harper & Brothers. Taylor, F.W. 1911. The principles of scientific management. Harper & Brothers.
go back to reference Tran, N.-B., and V.K. Smith. 1983. The role of air and water residuals for steam electric power generation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 10: 35–49.CrossRef Tran, N.-B., and V.K. Smith. 1983. The role of air and water residuals for steam electric power generation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 10: 35–49.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Dynamic Efficiency Measurement
Author
Finn R. Førsund
Copyright Year
2015
Publisher
Springer India
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-81-322-2253-8_4